Thanks to visit codestin.com
Credit goes to www.scribd.com

0% found this document useful (0 votes)
104 views11 pages

Unit 2: Consumer Theory

This document provides an overview of consumer theory and demand analysis. It discusses: 1) The experienced utility function and how consumers maximize utility subject to a budget constraint to arrive at a demand function. 2) How to calculate consumer surplus graphically as the area between the marginal benefit and price curves. Consumer surplus captures the net benefit to consumers. 3) How to recover preferences and calculate consumer surplus using only observable demand data, without knowing the exact utility function. 4) How decision mistakes and addiction can lead to a divergence between optimal and actual consumption choices if decision utility differs from experienced utility.

Uploaded by

Manas Kotru
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
104 views11 pages

Unit 2: Consumer Theory

This document provides an overview of consumer theory and demand analysis. It discusses: 1) The experienced utility function and how consumers maximize utility subject to a budget constraint to arrive at a demand function. 2) How to calculate consumer surplus graphically as the area between the marginal benefit and price curves. Consumer surplus captures the net benefit to consumers. 3) How to recover preferences and calculate consumer surplus using only observable demand data, without knowing the exact utility function. 4) How decision mistakes and addiction can lead to a divergence between optimal and actual consumption choices if decision utility differs from experienced utility.

Uploaded by

Manas Kotru
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 11

Unit 2: Consumer Theory

Prof. Antonio Rangel December 12, 2013

1
1.1

Consumer demand
The experienced utility function
Suppose that the consumer only cares about two goods: x, good of interest, measured in units m, a measure of all other consumption in $. Think of it as amount of $ spent on all other goods except for x. Assume x 0, but can have m T 0. Experienced utility function: U (x, m) = level of experienced utility (= satisfaction or happiness) from consumption bundle x, m. Assume U is quasi-linear: U (x, m) = B (x) + m, B 0 > 0, B 00 < 0. Remarks: B (x) = willingness to pay for x units of good x B (0) need not be zero = 1, i.e. constant marginal utility; marginal utility since B 00 < 0.
U m U x

= B 0 (x), i.e. decreasing

U (x, m) measured in dollars

1.2

Utility maximization problem

Assume consumer is rational; i.e. chooses action to maximize experienced utility Consumers problem, given wealth W and a price p per unit of good x: max B (x) + W xp max B (x) xp
x 0 x 0 x0,m

max U (x, W xp) by QL assumption by dropping constant W

Familiar structure: benet minus cost Notation: x (p) = optimal choice = demand for x at p. It follows that m (p) = W px (p) Solution: Concavity conditions satised Case 1: Interior (x (p) > 0): when B 0 (0) > p and B 0 crosses p . Case 2: Corner solution at x (p) = 0: when B 0 (0) < p. Case 3: x = : when B 0 (x) > p for all x. Not very interesting, since crossing conditions usually satised via B 0 () = 0

Economic intuition: starting at zero, keep buying as long as MB > MC

1.3

The demand function

Demand curve for individual consumer Demand function: x (p), dened for all p > 0 In economics, we always graph price on the vertical axis, and quantity on the horizontal axis Key result: Demand function MB curve 2

With x as independent variable, graph B 0 Taking p as independent variable, same locus of points gives the demand function.

1.4

Example

U (x, m) = A ln x + m Observe that all solutions must be interior, since B 0 (0) = > p. Solving B 0 (x) = p yields x (p) =
A p

A is a taste parameter. As A increases the demand curve shifts right (i.e., the amound demanded increases at any p).

1.5

Example

U (x, m) = A ln x + m What is the demand function if there is a mandatory minimum purchase of at least 1 unit of x ? For p A, demand curve the same as in previous example, x bef (p) = xaf ter (p)
For p > A, demand curve now is x af ter (p) = 1 > xbef (p). In this case, since the consumers are forced to buy more than they want, they are made worse o by the policy.

1.6

Properties of the demand function


dx dp

RESULT: Law of Demand: Outline of proof:

0, w/ inequality if x > 0.
dx dp

For prices in the range of corner solutions: x (p) = 0 =

=0

x (p) > 0 = interior solution = B 0 (x (p)) = p Taking derivatives of both sides w.r.t. p yields B 00 dx =1 dp dx 1 = dp = B 00 Therefore B 00 < 0 = dx <0 dp 3

RESULT: No income eects:

dx dW

=0

Why? With quasilinear preferences, the FOC that characterizes x does not depend on how much of the good m is consumed Both results approximately hold for goods which account for a small fraction of consumers overall spending Both can fail when U is non-quasilinear

2
2.1

Consumer surplus
Consumer Surplus: Basics
How do we measure well-being of consumer? Consumer surplus = NET benet of buying optimally at price p, measured in dollars Mathematically, it is dened as follows: CS (p) = U (x (p), W px (p)) U (0, W ) = B (x (p)) B (0) px (p) by quasilinearity x ( p ) x ( p ) = B 0 (x)dx p dx the Fundamental Theorem of Calculus 0 0 x ( p ) = (B 0 (x) p) dx by linearity of the integral
0

Denition in the rst line says CS (p) equals experienced utility of buying x (p) minus experienced utility of buying zero. Graphical description: CS = area between B 0 and p, from x = 0 to x = x Properties of CS: CS 0 CS > 0 i x (p) > 0 4

Can see both from the graphical description Can also see it from a revealed preference argument: (0, W ) is always feasible, i.e. the consumer can always buy nothing. Therefore CS cant be negative: if the consumer buys anything, it must make her better o.

2.2

Example
B0 =
A x A2 p2

Suppose U (x, m) = 2A x + m x ( p) =

Consider two dierent ways of computing CS (p). Direct method: CS (p) = U (x (p)) Uno trade h p i = 2A x (p) + W px (p) [0 + W ] 2A2 A2 2p p p 2 A = p =

Graphical/integral method: CS (p) =


x ( p ) 0

A p dx = x 0 2 A2 = 2A x px 0p A2 = p
A2 p2

(B 0 (x) p) dx

2.3

Eect of price changes on consumer surplus

Consider eect on CS of price decrease from p0 to p1 It is given by: CSp0 p1 = CS (p1 ) CS (p0 ) = Change in experienced utility following price change from p0 to p1 x 1 = x0 p + (B 0 p1 ) dx
x 0

where 4p = p0 p1 Fist term = value of buying the old x 0 units at lower price p1 Second term = value of buying additional units at price p1

2.4

More on consumer surplus

Lets extend the notion of consumer surplus to more general situations Let = complete description of consumers problem x () = optimal choice at situation Now, CS () = U (x ()) Uno trade Example: U (x, m) = A x + m : price = p, mandatory minimum purchase = 1 unit Now, we have x ( ) = and CS () = ( 1
A2 p2

if p A if p < A

2A p if p A A2 if p < A p

Important lesson from example: There are situations in which CS can be negative. They often involve situations in which consumers are forced to make purchases that they would not make volutarily. 6

3
3.1

Recovering preferences from data


What if we dont know the utility function?
In reality, we never know consumers experienced utility functions. However, we can infer changes in consumer surplus from behavior alone!

3.2

How to compute CS using only behavioral data

Given observations of several price/quantity pairs, can estimate the function x (p) using statistics Then, construct the inverse demand function p (x) = x1 (p) But we know that at an interior allocation, p (x) = B 0 (x), as long as the consumer makes decisions by maximizing her experienced utility function It follows that
x ( p )

CS (p) =

(p (x) p) dx

This gives CS as a function of x (p), p (), and p, all of which are observable Can use this to estimate the change in consumer surplus that would follow from an unobserved change in prices, the introduction of a new tax, etc.

3.3

Recovering the utility function from observed behavior

Suppose x () observed. We recover U using the following steps: Assume U is quasi-linear, i.e. U (x, m) = B (x) + m Then p (x) = B 0 (x) x So B (x) = B (0) + 0 p (u)du 7

U (x, m) =

x
0

p (u)du + m + constant

So we can recover U (x.m) up to a constant, which is equal to B (0). Constant typically unimportant in most applications. What if U is not quasilinear? OK if U quasi-linear, even if not exactly so Method generalizes (taught in advanced courses, requires substantially more math)

3.4

Example
10 p

Consider an example of how to recover U (x, m) from x (p) Suppose we observe that x (p) = Then p =
10 x+1

So B (x) = 10 ln(x + 1), and U (x, m) = 10 ln(x + 1) + m + constant

3.5

Example
9 p

0 = initial situation at which consumer buys freely at price p At initial situation observe x (p) = 1. 1 = new situation at which individuals buy freely, but also get 2 free units (regardless of how much they buy) Question: Predict whatt is CS (1 )? Solve in three steps. Step 1: Recover U (x, m) from the initial observed demand. Get U (x, m) = 9 + ln(x + 1) + m (similar to previous example) Step 2: Predict x 1 (p) by maximizing the recovered prefences 8

Important: x 1 (p) denotes the amount bought, not the amoung consumed which is equal to x 1 (p) + 2. Get x 1 ( p) = Step 3: Predict CS (1 ) Get CS (1 ) = ( 9ln3 if p 3 9 9ln p + 9 3p if p < 3 ( 0
9 p

if p 3 3 if p < 3

3.6

Application: Valuing new products

Hypothetical example: compute the value of introducing household robots for a typical US consumer Data: 2020 2025 p 9000 1000 x 1 9

Graph the data, and t a line through them (trivial in this example, since only two points) Get x (p) = max{0, 10
p } 1000

Value of introducing robots = CS (p) CS (p = ) = CS (p) . Using graphical method: - CS2020 = 1 1 1000 = $500 2 - CS2025 = 1 9 9000 = $40, 500 2 Lesson: Value of a new product depends strongly on the price at which its sold.

4
4.1

Consumer mistakes
Decision mistakes
A simple model of decision mistakes: 1. Decision Utility vs. Experienced Utility - Experienced utility: describes well-being/hedonics - Decision utility: describes objective that is maximized at decision time 2. x () = maxx U DU (x) s.t. feasibility constraints in xopt () = maxx U EU (x) s.t. feasibility constraints in 3. Rational behavior: U DU = U EU = x = xopt 4. Mistakes: U DU 6= U EU = x 6= xopt Example: U EU = 2A x + m U DU = 4A x + m
A So xopt (p) = A , x (p) = 4p 2 . Note the gap between the consumer p2 choice and the optimal choice.
2 2

Remarks: 1. B DU (x) 6= B EU (x) + constant = mistakes arise 2. If mistakes, then: Utility function recovered from behavior 6= U EU CS calculted with the recovered utility function is incorrect 3. Thus, critical to know if mistakes likely in a given context Example (continued): The CS estimated under the assumption that the consumer is 2 rational is CS est (p) = 4A . p But the true CS, given the consumers true EU function, is CS true (p) = 0. 10

4.2

Application: Addiction

Here is a simple model to think about the consumption of addictive substances: U EU (x, m) = B (x) + m U DU (x, m) = B (x) + m, 1 Can have CS true (p) < 0, in which case prohibition can be welfare improving!

Final remarks
Key ideas: 1. Modeling behavior: x () given by maxx0 U DU (x) s.t. constraints in 2. Measuring well-being: Consumer surplus, CS () = U EU (x ()) EU Uno trade 3. Given rationality, can recover B (x) from x (p) and measure CS from p (x) Tips on problem solving: Must specicy maximization problem correctly Consumer behavior (x ()) follows from maximizing U DU given the constraints in situation Optimal level of consumption (xopt ()) follows from maximizing U EU given the constraints in situation Dont mix up demand x (p) and inverse demand p (x) Careful when computing CS using the notion of area under the curve

11

You might also like