Fed's New Monetary Policy Tools
Fed's New Monetary Policy Tools
Until the rules work for every American, theyre not working.
The Roosevelt Institute asks: What does a better society look like?
Armed with a bold vision for the future, we push the economic and social
debate forward. We believe that those at the top hold too much power
and wealth, and that our economy will be stronger when that changes.
Ultimately, we want our work to move the country toward a new
economic and political system: one built by many for the good of all.
It will take all of us to rewrite the rules. From emerging leaders to Nobel
laureate economists, weve built a network of thousands. At Roosevelt,
we make influencers more thoughtful and thinkers more influential.
We also celebrateand are inspired bythose whose work embodies
the values of both Franklin and Eleanor Roosevelt and carries their
vision forward today.
ABOUT THE AUTHORS ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Mike Konczal is a Fellow with the Roosevelt Institute, where We thank Josh Bivens, Gerald
he works on financial reform, unemployment, inequality, and Epstein, and Lenore Palladino
a progressive vision of the economy. He has written about for their comments and insight.
the economy for numerous publications, including The Nation, Roosevelt staff Nell Abernathy,
The Washington Post, and Vox. He received his M.S. in Kendra Bozarth, Katy Milani,
Finance and B.S. in Math and Computer Science both from Jennifer R Miller, Marshall
the University of Illinois. Prior to joining the Roosevelt Institute, Steinbaum, and Alex Tucciarone
he was a financial engineer at Moodys KMV working on all contributed to the project.
capital reserve models.
This report was made possible
J.W. Mason is a Fellow at the Roosevelt Institute, where he with generous support from the
works on the Financialization Project, and an assistant professor Open Philanthropy Project.
of economics at John Jay College, CUNY. His current research
focuses on the history and political economy of credit, including
the evolution of household debt and the changing role of
financial markets in business investment. He also works on
history of economic thought, particularly the development
of macroeconomics over the twentieth century.
Executive Summary
The Great Recession forced the Federal Reserve to think beyond conventional monetary
policy toolsprimarily adjusting the overnight federal funds rate targetto reverse the
economic downturn and steer the economy toward healthy demand. With rates close to
zero, the Fed turned to what was viewed as unconventional monetary policy, most notably
by purchasing longer-term assets, like treasuries and mortgage securities, a strategy known
as quantitative easing (QE). Even with these changes, there is strong evidenceincluding
low labor force participation and wage stagnationthat the Fed has not brought us back to
full employment or brought the economy back to its historical path of growth. Most of the
recovery has come not from a genuine increase in output, but from a reduced expectation of
the economys potential.
There are many reasons why monetary policy cant go back to the status quo. When the next
recession happens, its unlikely that reducing the short-term interest rate will be enough
to stabilize demand, simply because rates will almost certainly not be high enough for a big
enough rate reduction to give the economy the boost it will need. In addition, monetary
policy always has effects on the distribution of income and wealth and on the direction of
credit, as well as its volume. We should adopt a more expansive view of the central banks
role in providing appropriate credit conditions. This is less of a challenge, however, as we are
also remembering old tools. It was universally understood in the past that it was necessary
for the Fed to intervene across the entire distribution of interest ratessetting multiple
rates (both long- and short-term rates, for instance) and playing a more active role in
managing credit creation in order to maintain full employment.
Though changes to the Federal Reserves current target, to either a new one or a higher
inflation target, are worth investigating, we believe that this change is unlikely to work
outside a broader conceptual shift. There are institutional reasons why the Federal Reserve
hasnt been able to hit its target. In addition, the link between conventional monetary policy
and real economic activity is weakening. There is not a single interest rate, but many
interest rates, many asset markets, and many different kinds of institutions participating
in them. It has become increasingly clear that effective macroeconomic policy cannot be
conducted on the basis of a single unique target.
Following the example set by the Bank of Japan (BOJ), the Fed should target long-term
interest rates in addition to the overnight rate that is the current focus of monetary policy.
The Fed should be explicit about support for public borrowing, allowing the government to
employ countercyclical fiscal policy along with monetary policy. The Fed should purchase
state and local debt, thus combating the pro-cyclical pressure of state and local spending
This list is not meant to be exclusive, exhaustive, or definitive. But we hope that it can
begin a broader discussion of expanding the scope and scale of interventions by the Fed.
The Federal Reserve may be uncomfortable redefining its role in the macroeconomy. But
whether it likes it or not, the central bank is a central planner that can shape both the
character and the level of economic activity in the U.S. The Fed should embrace this role
and the democratic accountability that goes with itand exercise its power toward the
public good.
The Feds strategy was less new than it was generally believed to be at the time, as these
new tools had actually been part of the monetary policy toolkit for much of the 20th
century. However, as the Fed embarked on its QE strategy, this approach was considered
brand new and triggered considerable debate in the field of monetary economics. The ways
that the Federal Reserve can conduct policy at the zero lower boundwhen the short-
term federal funds interest rate is at or near zero percenthas inspired a research agenda
to expand and diversify the tools within the central banks disposal to reverse inevitable
downturns in our economy. For the first time in many years, the appropriate instruments
and targets for monetary policy are up for debate.
It is an open question today whether there has been a full recovery from the Great
Recession, and how much slack still remains in the economy. Labor force participation
still remains low. Meanwhile, wages remain slack. Most of the recovery has come not from
a genuine increase in output, but from a reduced expectation of the economys potential
(Mason 2017). By 2019, it is likely that our recovery over the past 12 years will have been
slower than the comparable period after 1929 (Leonhardt 2017). Nonetheless, central
bankers seem prepared to declare victory and go home. By ending the third and final round
of QE in September of 2014 and raising interest rates in December of 2015, the Federal
Reserve has moved away from its unconventional policy regime of QE. As Bernanke (2017)
observes, officials at the Fed and other central bankers believe they see the light at the end
of the tunnel and, for the most part, are no longer worried about their ability to achieve
their macroeconomic goals with the existing tools.
It is nearly certain that when the next recession comes, the Fed will again be forced to resort
to unconventional policy remedies. And even before then, there are substantial questions
about the extent to which demand managementi.e., the ways in which the Federal
Before the crisis, mainstream economists and policymakers had converged on a beautiful
construction for monetary policy. To caricature just a bit: we had convinced ourselves that
there was one target, inflation. There was one instrument, the policy rate. And that was
basically enough to get things done. If there is one lesson to be drawn from this crisis, it is
that this construction wasnt right, that beauty is unfortunately not always synonymous
with truth. The fact is that there are many targets and there are many instruments.
The goal of this paper is to begin to develop a new monetary policy toolkitone that will
broaden the set of countercyclical tools and flesh out some of the many instruments that
Blanchard thinks central banks should be exploring.
In Section One, we discuss why, in response to the Great Recession, it is essential that
the Federal Reserve develop a broader monetary policy toolkit. We then, in Section Two,
discuss some of the most widely discussed monetary policy reforms currently being
considered to stimulate post-recession growth. In particular, we review recent proposals
This list is not meant to be exhaustive or definitive, but we hope that it can begin a broader
discussion of expanding the scope and scale of interventions by the Fed. The economys
ability to weather recessions, and to meet human needs even in good times, depends on the
Fed getting out of the narrow box it trapped itself in before 2008 and is only just finding its
way out of today.
Its important to be clear on what we mean by conventional monetary policy. Lets define the
conventional view, which dominated finance in the decades before the Great Recession, as
follows: Monetary policy consisted of the manipulation of a single instrumentan overnight
interbank interest rate instrument. This instrument was meant to manage one or, at most,
two targets: a single inflation rate and perhaps also an unemployment rate. (In practice,
the Fed has treated full employment as simply meaning whatever level of unemployment
is consistent with its inflation target, so the notional two targets are really just one.) In
the consensus view, setting a single overnight interest rate at the appropriate level would
be sufficient to stabilize inflation, output, and unemployment at socially desirable levels,
and this would be consistent with stable trajectories for debt and asset prices, as well.
Macroeconomists believed that the economy was characterized by something close to the
divine coincidencethat full employment, maximum sustainable growth, and stable
inflation go together with no trade-offs between them (Blanchard 2016). In theory, if the
policy interest rate was set at the right level, the central bank would achieve all that could be
asked from it as far as the macroeconomy was concerned.
In the wake of the Great Recession, its clear that these promises were not fulfilled. It
is universally agreed that the single interest-rate instrument is insufficient to reliably
stabilize demandmost obviously because of the zero lower bound, but also because
changes in the policy interest rate are not reliably transmitted to the larger economy. It
is also increasingly recognized that the central banks macroeconomic goals cannot be
reduced to a single target. In part, this is because the divine coincidence may not hold
The unconventional monetary policy of the past decade largely consisted of the central
bank directly purchasing long-term debt and other securities from the market through
the QE program, guiding the financial markets on the future path of those purchases, and,
during the initial liquidity crisis, providing emergency loans to the financial sector so it
could weather the economic storm during the initial liquidity crisis.
Today, many inside and outside the Fed hope that it will be possible to fight the next
recession by relying on conventional policy, supplemented by the handful of unconventional
tools that were tried after 2007. We disagree. We believe new tools for monetary policy are
still urgently needed for the following reasons:
you only need to look back at monetary history to see the obvious: central banks
have engaged in extended periods of administrative guidance, of doing very active
directed lending in particular sectors, and especially of engaging in market operations
on financial assets other than government securities It is quite literally a prehistoric
argument to assert that central banks are engaged in experimental, unprecedented, or
somehow scandalous and dangerous policy maneuvers today.
Indeed, it was universally understood in the past that it was necessary for the Federal
Reserve to intervene across the entire distribution of interest ratessetting both long-
and short-term rates, for instanceand playing a more active role in managing credit
creation in order to maintain full employment. New research from the Federal Reserve
During World War II, the Fed directly set long-term interest rates. This was like QE,
but the Fed announced a target price for securities rather than a specific amount to be
purchased. Starting in 1942, the Fed successfully committed to a 2.5 percent ceiling on
long-term government bonds, which was maintained until 1947 (Hetzel 2001). In the
postwar decades, Fed staff promoted a broad range of credit-direction tools to developing
countries, establishing new central banks as part of monetary policy best practice (Epstein
2013). Given this, there is no reason to exclude a broader range of instruments for actively
directing credit from the Feds toolkit going forward, nor should we treat a more expansive
toolkit as some radical measure that should be considered only as a last resort.
12
10
Federal Funds Rate
6% drop in
1990 Recession
6
5.25% drop in
2001 Recession
4
During the summer of 2017, the federal fund rate was at 1.15 percent. In June of 2017, Fed
officials estimated that the federal funds rate will only be at 2.9 percent during 2019, with
a longer-run estimate of 3 percent. These estimates have generally been too optimistic
about the recovery, but even if they are true, it shows that there may be little space for
conventional interest rate setting policy to respond to any negative shock to demand. If the
next recession requires a fall in the federal funds rate of 5.5 percent, as it did in the 1990 and
2001 recessions, there simply wont be the room to carry it out with current estimates.
The larger problem here is twofold. First, there are widespread arguments that demand
is persistently weaker today than in the past. Whether this is because investment is
depressed by a lack of major new technologies or by corporate short-termism, or whether
consumption is depressed by higher inequality or other factors, the effect is the same: It
takes a lower interest rate to reach the economys potential even in normal times. Second,
At the same time, the range of outcomes that macroeconomic policy needs to address
has broadened to include financial stability and the distribution of income and wealth.
These outcomes have become increasingly prominent on central bank agendas over the
past decade. As Tinbergen (1952) pointed out long ago, a single macroeconomic policy
instrument cannot control more than one independent target. For the moment, central
banks seem to be trying to achieve adequate outcomes on all targets with the single
instrument of an overnight interest rate. But such an approach is likely to lead to, at
best, mediocre outcomesits a compromise rate, which is too low to rein in financial
exuberance while too high to generate full employment or fully utilize the economys
productive potential.
It is increasingly clear that even if the central banks objective is defined myopically as price
stability, the overnight interest rate is an inadequate interest rate to achieve even that.
Despite an overnight rate at zero, the Fed has undershot its inflation target almost every
month since 2008. During the recession and the immediate post-recession period, Fed
officials recognized the inadequacy of the short-term interest rate and worked to develop
a set of alternative toolsmainly QE and forward guidancethat could more effectively
boost desired spending by the private sector. The effectiveness of these tools is, at least,
questionable; though QE probably achieved more than forward guidance, neither were able
to stimulate private sector borrowing on a large scale (Friedman 2014).
The response to the crisis both demonstrated and reinforced the Feds deep involvement in
financial markets. While many of the special facilities to shift risk out of the banking system
have been wound down, some remain in place. Even today, the Fed is the final purchaser of
10-20 percent of new residential mortgages in the U.S., as it rolls over its existing stock of
mortgage-backed securities. Even if demand management and economic stabilization were
not the original goals of these asset purchases, they still have important effects on aggregate
demandin this case, by supporting mortgage lending. The crisis response also demonstrated
the range of actions available to the Fed in an emergency. Fed leadership should not be allowed
to plead helplessness in an emergency of mass unemployment or urgent, unmet social needs,
but should show the same creativity in addressing them they brought to the financial crisis.
Conversely, while the crisis was a lesson in the speed and flexibility with which the central
bank can act when it wishes to, it was also a lesson in the shortcomings of financial markets.
A narrow definition of monetary policy made sense when it seemed that, if the Fed simply
set the overall level of liquidity or credit creation in the economy, private markets would
allocate it to the most socially beneficial uses. The mortgage bubble and the ensuing collapse
of the securitized-mortgage market make that claim less defensible. If we cant count on
private finance to efficiently allocate credit, it is the responsibility of policymakers to take
a more active role in steering credit through the economy. Paul Krugman (2016) suggests
that this broader point about the efficiency of financial markets should be one of the main
lessons of the crisis. The experience of the past decade suggests:
Monetary policy choices also have important effects on the distribution of income
and wealth (Binder 2015). Expansionary policy can raise wages and improve income
distributionthere is evidence that in the absence of QE, inequality would have increased
in the post-recession period by even more than it did (Bivens 2015). Conversely, weak policy
responses can lead to less growth with slower wage gains, reduced productivity growth,
and lower labor force participation. Whether this decline in potential economic activity,
often referred to as hysteresis, is permanent or simply requires more aggressive effort to
combat is a current frontier of debate. Either way, however, it shows us that, contrary to
economic models, money is not neutral in the long run, because the state of monetary policy
determines how the economy grows towards the long-term.
Finally, higher and lower interest rates redistribute income between debtors and creditors.
Indeed, the rise in the long-term household debt-income ratios after 1980 was due not
to higher borrowing by households, but by the effect of higher real interest rates on the
existing stock of household debt (Mason and Jayadev 2015). Monetary policy decisions must
take into account their effects on distribution and allocation of credit, as well as on the level
of demand. It is unlikely a single instrument will be sufficient to meet all these goals. Indeed,
there is an argument that policymakers should be much more concerned with the effects of
their choices on distribution than on long-term growth (Furman 2017).
For manyboth inside and outside the Fedthese kinds of large-scale asset purchases
represent undesirable distortions of financial markets. But, as Bernanke (2017) notes,
these criticisms are incoherent. The goal of all monetary policy is to set financial
conditions consistent with full employment and stable prices. So, it is always going to
produce a different pattern of asset prices and yields than it would have obtained otherwise.
Going into the Great Recession, it was understood that the Fed had a 2 percent inflation
target. This was made explicit in January 2012, when the Fed announced, [T]he Committee
judges that inflation at the rate of 2 percent, as measured by the annual change in the price
index for personal consumption expenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with
the Federal Reserves statutory mandate. This target or judgment behind it hasnt changed
since (Federal Reserve 2012). In fact, of course, the 2 percent inflation target had guided Fed
policy since at least the late 1990s and was embedded in widely used models of monetary
policymaking, such as the Taylor Rule.
Binder and Rodrigue (2016) give a good overview of many of these alternatives. An asset price target is most forcefully
1
advocated by Roger Farmer (2009). The hybrid inflation/price-level target was recently proposed by former Federal
Reserve Chair Ben Bernanke (Bernanke 2017).
3%
2.5% Core CPI, Quarterly Change from a Year Ago
As seen in Figure 2 above, the Fed has undershot this target consistently during the Great
Recession. This has lead to a significant debate about the role of targets in deep recessions.
Does communicating a target matter, independent of the central banks actions to reach it?
And doesor shouldmissing a target imply that the miss will later be made up for by
missing in the opposite direction?
There are several arguments why the Federal Reserve hasnt been able to hit its target.
The first is institutional. The Fed, by its nature, will be cautious and place too big a weight
on inflation versus full employment. Many have noted that Ben Bernanke as an academic
described Japan as being in a state of self-induced paralysis (Bernanke 2000). Bernanke
argued that certain actions, such as setting long-term interest rates, establishing a 3 to 4
percent inflation target, creating money-financed fiscal expansion, or executing currency
depreciation, mean that a central bank retains tools even at the zero lower bound. These
more aggressive actions do not characterize Bernankes own tenure, however. Some point
to his tenure on the Board of Governors as a period in which Bernanke moderated his more
aggressive earlier stances (Ball 2012).
The Fed tried to demonstrate that they did not see the 2 percent inflation target as a ceiling
during the Great Recession. In December 2012, the Federal Reserve announced a policy
modeled on the Evans Rulenamed for Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago President Charles
Evansthat stated rates would remain at zero even if inflation went above 2 percent, to
a rate of 2.5 percent inflation. It also announced QE purchases that were open-ended,
modeled on criticism of the Feds earlier forward guidance of future rate changes (Evans et
al. 2012; Woodford 2012).
However, throughout 2013, inflation fell to some of its lowest rates. Inflation expectations
were also falling during this time. It is not clear why this happened, but it appears a simple
commitment to a symmetric target with action behind it isnt sufficient to set inflation
expectations.
10%
8%
6%
4%
2%
0% Policy Rate Baa Corporate Bond 10-Year Treasury Bond 30-Year Mortgage
FIGURE 3 Changes in the Feds policy rate (black) do not always led to proportionate change in the longer interest rates
that matter most for the economy. For instance, when the Fed increased the federal funds rate by 4 points between 2004
and 2006, interest rates on corporate bonds, home mortgages and 10-year federal bonds all increased by less than one
point. Source: Moodys (Baa corporate bond), Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (other rates); retrieved
from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, October 30, 2017
The second explanation for why the Fed has consistently missed its inflation target is
economic. The standard interest rate instrument is paralyzed by the zero lower bound, QE
remains too weak to play more than a supporting role in macroeconomic stabilization, and
expectations of more expansionary policy in the future dont drive private sector decision-
making on investment and spending today. Even positive assessments of QEs impact are
underwhelming. Gagnon (2016) summarizes the results of 16 studies of QE. The median
estimate is that purchases of bonds equal to 10 percent of GDP would reduce long rates by
eight tenths of a pointnot trivial, but quite small relative to the programs size.
As shown in Figure 3, between July 2007 and December 2008, the target federal funds rate
was reduced from 5.25 percent to zero, where it remained until the end of 2015. Yet at the
Higher inflation would also reduce the burden of existing debt. Historically, the rise and fall in
inflation have played a larger role in the evolution of both public and private debt than is often
recognized. And in an environment in which inflation expectations are firmly anchored, there
may be a significant tradeoff between inflation and unemploymentperhaps not a permanent
or reliable tradeoff, but one significant enough that policy should take it into account
(Blanchard 2016). There is also an issue, relevant to the current debate, that announcing a
higher or different target would give the Federal Reserve latitude to allow the economy to
return to something closer to the pre-Recession trend linean opportunity that may be difficult
at just 2 percent. A higher inflation target would also eliminate the concern that 2 percent is
actually functioning as a ceiling. So, there are good reasons for the Fed to accept higher inflation
as a goal of policy, either directly or via an alternative target, like the price level or NGDP.
It is one thing to say that higher inflation (or some other target) describes a desirable
outcome. It is something else to say that adopting a different target would in and of itself do
anything to improve the poor economic performance of the past decade or strengthen the
Feds ability to deal with a future downturn. Despite the claims of some proponents, there
are good reasons to doubt that the choice alone of a target has any important effects on the
economy, or that the current inflation target is the main problem with monetary policy today.
Doubts about the effectiveness of announcing a new target are reinforced by evidence of
central bank experiments with forward guidance. A number of countriesincluding New
Zealand, Canada, Norway, Sweden, and Japan, as well as the United Stateshave seen
central banks experiment with explicit statements about policy actions years into the
future, as a way of influencing financial markets today. Empirical evidence to date suggests
that this had limited effects on financial markets, failing to consistently move interest rates
Discussions of forward guidance often distinguish between Delphic forward guidance, in which the central bank simply
3
communicates some belief about policy that is likely to be in the future, and Odyssean forward guidance, in which the
central bank somehow or another commits itself to specific future policy choices.
More generally, there are several good reasons to doubt the effectiveness of announcing
future policy actions as a tool for influencing the economy today. First, economic behavior
is not as forward-looking as this approach requires. For the past generation, most academic
macroeconomics has been based on models of intertemporal optimization by rational
agents. That is to say, actors in the economy are imagined to make decisions by weighing
outcomes over all future time. Meanwhile, the central bank is assumed to pick a rule once
and for all and to stick with it forever. This means that policy a year or ten years from
today factors into economic behavior just as much as policy today. But one clear lesson of
the past decade is that old Keynesian ideas about financial constraints and conventional
expectations are more realistic descriptions of economic behavior than the intertemporal
optimization of newer models. Real households and businesses cannot spend future income
as easily as current incomethat is, they face financial constraints. And their expectations
of the future are more likely to be extrapolations from recent trends or shared beliefs with
no solid foundation, rather than true reflections of the probabilities of future events. So,
even if central banks could make binding commitments about policy several years from
now, economic actors today would not necessarily respond to them.
Second, central banks cannot in fact make binding commitments to actions several years
from now. Regardless of what todays Federal Open Markets Committee (FMOC) says
about the Feds actions in 2025, actions will in fact be taken by the FOMC in place in that
year, as appointed by elected officials between now and then, and on the basis of economic
data available at that time. No statement by todays FOMC will constrain them. Economic
models that feature permanent policy rules are not useful guides for monetary policy in the
real world.4 It is not possible, legally or practically, for a central bank to set a rule that will be
followed for all time, or even to make a binding commitment for policy actions a year from
now. And it is clear that markets recognize this. As Benjamin Friedman (2014) puts it, the idea
As Bernanke (2017) notes, central banks are not typically unitary actors, but may include participants of diverse views
4
trying to reach compromise in an uncertain environment. This kind of institutional realismrooted, in this case, in first-
hand experienceis unfortunately missing from too many discussions of monetary policy rules.
There are many concerns that might be raised about the radical step of eliminating cash
and the impact of negative rates more broadlyon the balance sheets of insurance and
pension funds, for example. But the real problem with proposals for negative rates is that
they are not radical enough. They remain within the orthodox framework in which there
is a single, economy-wide interest rate, which is tightly linked to the rate set by the central
The problem with looking toward negative rates as the solution to monetary policys
weakness is that there is not a single interest rate, but many interest rates, many asset
markets, and many different kinds of institutions participating in them. A variety of
financial frictions and other institutional features of real-world finance prevent easy
arbitrage between these different markets, so different interest rates, prices of different
assets, and access to credit of different borrowers may move independently. In a 2012
speech, the fundamental issue was described very clearly by Posen:
Differentiation of financial assets matters. One of the most foolish mistakes of the
last 15 years was that we actively assumed this fact away One key lesson is that there
simply is not one real interest rate for the economy. Households are facing one set of
highly differentiated interest rates, small and medium enterprises are facing another set
of far from smoothly distributed interest rates, as is the construction sector, and so on
If the persistence of financial fragility and of weak recovery are in large part due to the
preferred habitats of asset holders with imperfectly substitutable assets, these problems
are not easily addressable by moving the price of one financial asset or the level of one
interest rate.
As we have seen, it is quite possible for the policy interest rate to be extremely low
while credit remains tight for many non-financial firms and households. Rather than
looking for ways to push its old policy instrument farther, the Fed should be looking for
new instruments that operate closer to the sectors of the economy that actually face
credit or liquidity constraints. There is no assurance that liquidity injected in one place
(e.g., through purchases of Treasury bonds) will flow to where it is needed (e.g., small
businesses or underwater homeowners). For policy to be effective, it has to first answer
Absent another major crisis, the Fed is unlikely to give up its framework based on an
aggregate target and a short-term interest rate as the main instrument of policy. So
it is important to think about better rules within that framework for sustaining full
employment. But, given the weak track record of meeting its targets in the Great Recession
and aftermath, and the economic and institutional barriers to rely on the short-run policy
rate in future downturns, we also need to look beyond that framework. The remainder of
this paper lays out some directions to explore.
As the start of what we hope will be a larger conversation, we propose the following six
changes in central bank practices. Some of these describe choices that the Fed can already
make under its existing authority. Others may require action by a broader set of policymakers.
Currently, quantitative easing works by setting the quantity of purchases of long-term debt.
Starting in December 2012, for instance, the Fed started buying $45 billion a month of long-
term treasuries in an open-ended commitment. This was the third, and most aggressive,
version of purchases, generally referred to as QE3. This method was chosen as a way to
push down longer interest rates and boost the economy. But what if, instead of targeting an
amount, QE worked by targeting a price?
The BOJ introduced this strategy in September 2016, under the name yield curve control.
This is an intervention where the BOJ will control short-term and long-term interest
rates. They stated that the initial target was to intervene so that 10-year [Japanese
government bond (JGB)] yields will remain more or less at the current level (around zero
percent) (Bank of Japan 2016). There are already several positive signs that show its
superiority over targeting the quantity.
Since the price and yield of a bond vary inversely, fixing the price of, say, 10-year Treasury bonds, is the same as fixing
5
Period of
BOJ Rate
Period of QE3 Control
1
0
-1
1/1/2010
4/1/2010
7/1/2010
10/1/2010
1/1/2011
4/1/2011
7/1/2011
10/1/2011
1/1/2012
4/1/2012
7/1/2012
10/1/2012
1/1/2013
4/1/2013
7/1/2013
10/1/2013
1/1/2014
4/1/2014
7/1/2014
10/1/2014
1/1/2015
4/1/2015
7/1/2015
10/1/2015
1/1/2016
4/1/2016
7/1/2016
10/1/2016
1/1/2017
4/1/2017
7/1/2017
1/1/2007
4/1/2007
7/1/2007
10/1/2007
1/1/2008
4/1/2008
7/1/2008
10/1/2008
1/1/2009
4/1/2009
7/1/2009
10/1/2009
As the figure shows, the JGB remains flat during this time period. Treasuries, however,
fluctuate widely. Future Roosevelt Institute work will quantify these changes further. But
to start, the volatility of both monthly JGB values and returns drop by half from the year
before the announcement to the year after. For 10-year Treasuries, the volatility actually
increased in the year after QE3 was announced, compared to the year before.
A second benefit of the price target was that the BOJ has had to purchase fewer assets to achieve
the same rate reduction. In the second quarter of 2017, the BOJ purchased 13.5 trillion yen of
bonds, compared to 22.3 trillion yen during the same time in 2016. As can be seen from Figure
5, the price target allowed the BOJ to purchase fewer assets while keeping markets more stable.
This is an important advantage over traditional QE, where both the public and policymakers
hesitate over the necessary increases in the size of the central banks balance sheet.
300k
250k
200k
150k
100k
50k
-50k 9/1/2016
11/1/2016
9/1/2013
11/1/2013
1/1/2014
3/1/2014
5/1/2014
7/1/2014
9/1/2014
11/1/2014
1/1/2015
3/1/2015
5/1/2015
7/1/2015
9/1/2015
11/1/2015
1/1/2016
3/1/2016
5/1/2016
7/1/2016
1/1/2017
3/1/2017
5/1/2017
7/1/2017
7/1/2010
9/1/2010
11/1/2010
1/1/2011
3/1/2011
5/1/2011
7/1/2011
9/1/2011
11/1/2011
1/1/2012
3/1/2012
5/1/2012
7/1/2012
9/1/2012
11/1/2012
1/1/2013
3/1/2013
5/1/2013
7/1/2013
The smaller required purchases are a direct result of the announcement of a target for
the long rate. When rates began to rise towards 0.10 percent, the BOJ took action to
communicate that it would buy an unlimited amount to keep rates from going above that.
As Grant Lewis, head of research at Daiwa Capital Markets Europe, told The Wall Street
Journal, the BOJ stood up and said yields will be held at these levels. Try and beat me, Ive
got infinite resources. Thats actually allowed them to start purchasing less (Bird 2017).
Announcements of future policy can have a powerful effect when a central bank announces
a target price in a market in which it is currently active, and in which it has the demonstrable
power to move prices. If the Fed announces that it will buy, lets say, 10-year Treasuries until
their price rises to a certain level, the significance of this statement doesnt depend on either
counterfactual assumptions about the Feds ability to move macroeconomic aggregates or
the behavior of future bank authorities. And, given the credibility of the promise in this case,
it would be irrational for market participants to sell the bonds at any price below the Feds
target. As this example shows, announcing the goal of the intervention greatly reduces
perhaps almost to zerothe amount that the Fed actually has to buy or sell. As Bernanke
(2017) puts it, A yield target may be enforceable with reduced quantities of purchases by
the central bank [compared with QE], because deviations from the target will be arbitraged
away by market participants. This is why yield curve control, such as adopted in Japan, may
allow the central bank to produce large changes in market interest rates with only small
volumes of transactions.
While the Japanese experiment is still in its early days, there are good reasons to believe
that the arbitrage described by Bernanke is effective. In the decades before 2007, the Fed
and other central banks set overnight interest rateslinked to an immense volume of
lending between financial institutionswith a comparatively tiny volume of transactions in
the federal funds market. This was effective because once the Fed announced a target rate,
private institutions had every incentive to quickly adopt that rate in their own transactions.
Its worth noting that before the mid-1980s, open-market operations were conducted
similar to how QE is today, with the Fed simply buying or selling a certain quantity of
securities. The practice of announcing a target rate was adopted precisely because it
While the merits of this policy have been extensively debated, the extent to which current U.S.
policy already looks like this is much less widely recognized. Between 2010 and 2016, the Fed
increased its holdings of Treasury debt by nearly $2 trillion. This represents approximately
30 percent of total federal borrowing during this period. In other words, while economists
debate the theoretical merits of helicopter money, it has already been in substantial use.
The reason that this extraordinary shift toward monetary finance of public spending
has received so little attention is that the policy has never been described as such. What
quantitative easing actually consists of, is large central bank purchases of public debt, or
in other words, central bank loans to the federal government. It follows that, if the federal
government faces any kind of financial constraints, QE must have gone a long way to
removing them. (There is no need to worry about how much federal debt the bond markets
will buy if the Fed is actually buying it.)
This has never been described as the goal of the policy. Rather, its described as a roundabout
way of influencing the willingness of the financial system to hold private liabilities. Whats
We propose that the Fed should be explicit about support for public borrowing, encouraging
the government to employ countercyclical fiscal policy along with monetary policy. In
other words, quantitative easing should be frankly described as what it is: monetary finance
of public spending. Such a change in language would have major benefits, even if the
substantive policy did not change. By clarifying that its policy is, in fact, one of supporting
the market for government debt, the Fed would assuage any doubts about the sustainability
of public finances. This alone would have a stabilizing effect on bond markets and might well
lead to lower long ratesthe ultimate goal of the policy. Perhaps, more importantly, it would
reassure policymakers in the elected branches and clarify discussions of budget questions.
One simple step in this direction would be to exclude federal debt held by the Fed from
headline measures of government debt.
From a social standpoint, public investment is less costly during a downturn, when a larger
fraction of labor and other resources are unemployed. So it is perverse that borrowing
constraints cause many governments to cut back investment spending in recessions.
FALLING STATE AND LOCAL SPENDING HAS CONTRIBUTED TO THE WEAK RECOVERY
15.5
Total Spending
Percent of GDP
15.0
2002-2007 Average
14.5
14.0
2.4
Percent of GDP
2002-2007 Average
2.2
Investment Spending
2.0
1.8
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
FIGURE 6 Both total spending and investment spending by state and local governments declined steeply between 2007
and 2017. This procyclical behavior of state and local government budgets may be due in part to the cost and availability of
credit for these governments. BEA; retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, October 30, 2017
As we see from Figure 6, this decline in state and local spending imparted a substantial
contractionary impulse to the economy during a period in which a great majority of
economists and policymakers believed more expansionary policy was needed, and is one
factor in the unusually weak recovery. By purchasing state and local debt, the Fed can
relax these credit constraints, ensuring both that vital services and public investment are
provided by financially constrained governments and that the overall balance of state and
local spending behaves countercyclically rather than pro-cyclically as it does today.
Given the two goals of supporting state and local spending during cyclical downturns
and providing relief for particular governments facing financial distress, the Fed should
develop facilities for purchasing state and local debt. This could involve a standing offer
to purchase state and local debt, up to some amount based on a formula involving average
revenue over recent years, resident population, or similar metrics. Both the interest rate
and quantity of this lending could be varied based on macroeconomic conditions. The
Fed might also make clear that it is ready to make emergency loans above this amount to
particular governments facing acute financial pressure. In order to avoid undermining
democratic government, however, it is important that there be no policy conditionality
attached to such emergency loans.
One obstacle to a program of lending to state and local governments is that the Fed is
currently authorized to buy their debt with a maturity of six months or less. This law should
be changed. But it doesnt represent a major obstacle to a program of Fed purchases of state
and local debt. By committing to roll over the debt for a certain number of years at a fixed
rate, the Fed can effectively lend to state and local governments at the longer maturities
more suited to their needs. Central banks have credibility. Here is a case where that hard-
won credibility can be put to practical use. A Fed announcement that it will roll over short-
term borrowings a fixed number of times at the same interest rate (say, 20 times, to create
the equivalent of a 10-year loan) will be meaningful in a way that an equivalent promise
from a private lender would not be. If such a facility is established, its benefits could greatly
exceed the actual volume of loans made. A public commitment to stabilize the finances of
state and local governments will make them safer borrowers, making it easier for them to
issue conventional bonds in private markets.
Its important to note that increased lending to state and local governments is not always
the right answer to the problem of financial constraints on public spending. In some cases,
outright debt forgiveness may be more appropriate. Puerto Rico may be in that situation
today. In other cases, the answer may be increased federal aid, or even in the long run,
shifting the burden of some kinds of public services from the state or local level to the
federal. In the near term, however, the Fed has a great deal of power to alleviate the acute
financial distress faced by some subnational governments and the pro-cyclical fiscal
behavior of the sector as a whole. This power should not be dismissed.
The maturity level of Treasury debt probably has little macroeconomic effect in normal
times, and conventional monetary policy can usually offset whatever effect Treasury
borrowing choices may have on financial conditions. The Treasury influences the supply of
Treasury debt of different maturities, affecting their different interest rates. But the actions
of the Federal Reserve should be able to move the whole complex of interest rates together.
In theory, if the short-term rate rises, it should move longer-term interest rates up with it,
and if the short-term interest rate falls, it should pull longer-term rates down. In practice,
as discussed above, the links between shorter- and longer-term rates are not as tight as
orthodox theory suggests. But even if they are linked, this is not helpful when short-term
rates themselves are stuck at zero. In this case, further expansion must focus on the longer
end, where Treasury choices about the maturity structure of debt are likely to matter more.
Since the 1980s, theres been little or no coordination between Treasury and Federal
Reserve officials. The U.S. Treasury has handled decisions about the maturity of the
debt, thinking through stability, market needs, and uncertainty surrounding economic
policymaking. They do not take under consideration macroeconomic effects. That
responsibility has fallen to the Federal Reserve, which sets the interest rates with an eye
towards full employment and inflation.
Instead of coordinating during the Great Recession, Treasury and Federal Reserve officials
pulled in opposite directions. As can be seen from Figure 7, the Treasury lengthened the
average maturity above the historical range at exactly the moment in which the Federal
Reserve was trying to reduce term premiums and long-term interest rates.
65
60
55
50
45
40
1/1/00
6/1/00
11/1/00
4/1/01
9/1/01
2/1/02
7/1/02
12/1/02
5/1/03
10/1/03
3/1/04
8/1/04
1/1/05
6/1/05
11/1/05
4/1/06
9/1/06
2/1/07
7/1/07
12/1/07
5/1/08
10/1/08
3/1/09
8/1/09
1/1/10
6/1/10
11/1/10
4/1/11
9/1/11
2/1/12
7/1/12
12/1/12
5/1/13
10/1/13
3/1/14
8/1/14
1/1/15
6/1/15
11/1/15
4/1/16
9/1/16
2/1/17
7/1/17
FIGURE 7 U.S. Department of the Treasury, Most Recent Quarterly Refunding Documents: https://www.treasury.gov/
resource-center/data-chart-center/quarterly-refunding/Pages/Latest.aspx
There are numerous options for coordination. A simple one, suggested by Greenwood and
others, is for both the Treasury and the Fed to release joint statements on their plans for
the maturity structure of Treasury debt. This would make the decision-making explicit
and force both sides to consider each others objectives. The Federal Reserve would have to
understand the fiscal risks that the Treasury understands itself to face, and the Treasury, in
turn, would understand the macroeconomic conditions that the Federal Reserve works to
navigate. As a baseline, this would align both sides with having to create a determined plan.
But given that the Treasury department will be setting maturity, it is impossible for them
not to be providing support or a headwind to zero lower bound policy.
This is not a new policy. During the 1960s, Treasury and Federal Reserve officials
coordinated in Operation Twist, an effort to lower long-term rates while leaving short-
term rates unchanged. Due to the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate system, policymakers
were worried about international gold flows that might result from changes in short-term
interest rates. Recent research has found that Operation Twist was successful in reducing
long-term Treasury yields by about 0.15 points (Alon 2011).
Purchasing a broader range of private liabilities may also be necessary simply to make the
transmission of routine monetary policy more reliable. While simple economic models refer to
the interest rate, in fact there are many interest rates in the economy. Monetary policy that
During the crisis, the Fed acquired very large holdings of mortgage-backed securities
(MBSs). The Fed has followed a policy of maintaining these holdings since the crisis,
purchasing an equal volume of new ones as its existing mortgage-backed securities mature.
In recent years, these purchases have amounted to about $30 billion a month, or about
15 percent of total new mortgages issued in the country. (This is down from $60 billion a
month in 2013-2014, the majority of new mortgage backed securities issued during that
period.) These purchases were originally undertaken not to support the mortgage market
but to revive interbank lending by removing toxic assetsMBSs of uncertain valuefrom
bank balance sheets. But the ongoing purchases have also provided support for the market
for MBSs, making issuing of new mortgages more attractive to banks. This has made an
important contribution to the revival of housing lending since the crisis.
At present, the Fed is more limited than most central banks in the types of assets it can
purchase. Direct lending to non-financial businesses or households might require new
legislation. On the other hand, when the Fed has felt forced to act in a crisis, the legal
restrictions on its activities have often turned out to be quite elastic. In any case, it is
important to have leadership at the Fed that is willing to push its existing authority as far as
possible to channel credit toward socially useful activities. Future Fed appointees should be
encouraged to adopt an expansive view of their ability to supportdirectly or indirectlya
broad range of private and public debt markets.
VA Mortgages 462
TABLE 1 Source: Office of Management and Budget, Budget of the U.S. Government, Fiscal Year 2018.
These major credit programs are centered around both student loans and mortgages
through the Federal Housing Administration (FHA), each representing more than a trillion
dollars of loans. Other notable programs reflect transportation infrastructure financing,
disaster assistance, small business loans, and the Export-Import Bank.
As private credit collapsed during the financial crisis and early Great Recession, particularly
in the mortgage market, these programs increased in size. We see the importance of these
policies most clearly in the mortgage market. In the immediate aftermath of the Great
Recession, the federal government took over most of the housing mortgage market. The
government-sponsored enterprises of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were taken directly
on the government books. FHA, in particular, took on a countercyclical role in the Great
Empirical and theoretical work from the Great Recession emphasized the contractionary
results of so much negative equity. Facing binding leverage constraints resulting from the
collapse in home value, consumers began deleveraging by rapidly paying down debts. Pre-
2007 consensus would expect this behavior to result in lower interest rates to maintain full
employment, yet the zero lower bound was already binding. The theoretical work shows that
this can drive down aggregate demand and keep an economy away from full employment
(Eggertsson 2010). The empirical results found that areas with higher negative equity
suffered significantly worse unemployment. This unemployment couldnt be explained
simply by a mismatch of skills or by a negative shock to wealth (Dynan 2012; IMF 2012;
Mian 2012 and Mian 2013).
Refinancing at lower interest rates is one way to address this. However, underwater and near-
negative equity homes usually cant refinance in traditional ways. During the financial crisis,
policymakers addressed this through coordination between the Treasury and the Federal
Housing Finance Agency (FHFA), which oversees mortgages owned or guaranteed by Fannie
Mae and Freddie Mac in a program called the Home Affordable Refinance Program (HARP).
Taken together, the overall credit portfolio played a large role in countercyclical policy
during the Great Recession. One estimate found that the stimulative effect of federal
credit programs was close to $400 billion in 2010 (Lucas 2016). If future recessions occur
alongside failures in financial markets that make it difficult to translate macroeconomic
policy into credit growth, the federal government will have to play a similar role.
Credit policy has historically been widely usedfrom Asian central banks directing lending
to strategic export and capital-goods industries; to efforts by the Bank of England and others
to assist in postwar reconstruction after World War II; to the longstanding U.S. policy of
supporting owner-occupied housing (Epstein 2013). Indeed, the creation of the Fed was
arguably motivated by a desire to channel credit to certain industries, specifically to support
U.S. banks in their effort to compete with British banks in provision of trade finance (Broz
1997). In recent years, the idea of credit policy has gone out of fashion in the U.S. and most
other countries, replaced by the idea that the central bank can set borrowing terms for the
economy as a whole without considering the credit demand or supply facing particular
sectors. But todays circumstances call for a return to a more active credit policyindeed,
the pendulum is already swinging back under the pressure of recent events.
Fed officials may be uncomfortable redefining their macroeconomic role in terms of credit
policy. They are more comfortable thinking of themselves as simply setting one overall interest
rate. But it is clear that the existing approach does not yield either macroeconomic stability
or reliable financing for productive investment. It is time that the Fed owns its role as an
immense island of central planning in the middle of the market economy (DeLong 2008).
These questions, and other similar choices about our collective productive activities, will
determine whether our grandchildren continue enjoying rising living standards and social
stability, or whether they face a new age of conflict and scarcity. As the ultimate arbiter of
credit and finance, the Fed has a central role to play here. Like it or not, the central bank is
a central planner, shaping both the character and the level of economic activity. It should
embrace this roleand the democratic accountability that goes with itand exercise its
power toward the public good.
Ball, Laurence. 2016. Ben Bernanke and the Zero Bound. NBER Working Paper No. 17836. Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber.org/papers/w17836.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Bank of Japan. 2016. New Framework for Strengthening Monetary Easing: Quantitative and Qualitative
Monetary Easing with Yield Curve Control. Tokyo, Japan: https://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/
release_2016/k160921a.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Bernanke, Ben. 2000. Japanese Monetary Policy: A Case of Self-Induced Paralysis? Presented at ASSA
Meeting, Boston, MA: January 9. http://www.princeton.edu/~pkrugman/bernanke_paralysis.pdf
(Accessed October 26, 2017).
Bernanke, Ben. 2012. Speech: Monetary Policy since the Onset of the Crisis. Presented at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY: August 31. https://www.
federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20120831a.htm (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Bernanke, Ben. 2017. Monetary Policy in a New Era. Prepared for the Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy
conference, Washington, D.C.: Peterson Institute. https://piie.com/system/files/documents/
bernanke20171012paper.pdf (Accessed November 3, 2017).
Bernanke, Ben and Mark Gertler. 1995. Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy
Transmission. NBER Working Paper No. 5146. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
http://www.nber.org/papers/w5146 (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Binder, Carola. 2015. Rewriting the Rules of the Fed: Testimony on the Full Employment Federal Reserve Act
of 2015. New York, NY: Roosevelt Institute. http://rooseveltinstitute.org/carola-binder-fed-testimony/
(Accessed October 26, 2017).
Binder, Carola and Alex Rodrigue. 2016. Monetary Rules and Targets: Finding the Best Path to Full
Employment. Washington, D.C.: Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. https://www.cbpp.org/sites/
default/files/atoms/files/9-1-16fullemployment.pdf (October 26, 2017).
Bird, Mike. 2017. Japan Shows Europe How to Dial Back Stimulus Without Spooking Investors. July 6,
The Wall Street Journal. https://www.wsj.com/articles/bank-of-japan-dials-back-stimulus-without-spooking-
investors-1499346641?mod=e2fb (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Bivens, Josh. 2015. Gauging the Impact of the Fed on Inequality During the Great Recession. Washington,
D.C.: Hutchins Center for Fiscal Monetary Policy, Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/
wp-content/uploads/2016/06/Josh_Bivens_Inequality_FINAL.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Blanchard, Olivier. 2011. Monetary Policy in the Wake of the Crisis. Prepared for the IMF Macro Conference.
Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund. http://www.imf.org/external/np/seminars/eng/2011/res/pdf/
ob2presentation.pdf (Accessed November 3, 2017).
Blanchard, Olivier. 2016. The U.S. Phillips Curve, Back to the 60s? Washington, D.C.: Peterson Institute for
International Economics. https://piie.com/publications/pb/pb16-1.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Borio, Claudio and Piti Disyatat. 2010. Unconventional monetary policies: an appraisal. The Manchester
School 78(s1): 53-89. http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1467-9957.2010.02199.x/full (Accessed
November 9, 2017).
Broz, Jeff L. 1997. The International Origins of the Federal Reserve System. Cornell University Press.
Brunnermeier, Markus K. and Yuliy Sannikov. 2013. Reviving Money and Banking. In Is Inflation Targeting Dead?
Central Banking After the Crisis, Centre for Economic Policy Research. London, UK: 95-103. http://voxeu.org/
sites/default/files/file/P248%20inflation%20targeting%207%20may.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Campbell, Bill. 2012. CoreLogic Reports Negative Equity Increase in Q4 2011. Santa Ana, CA: CoreLogic.
http://www.corelogic.com/about-us/news/corelogic-reports-negative-equity-increase-in-q4-2011.aspx
(Accessed October 26, 2017).
Carlson, Mark and Burcu Duygan-Bump. 2016. The Tools and Transmission of Federal Reserve Monetary
Policy in the 1920s, FEDS Notes. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, November 22.
Washington, D.C.: https://www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/notes/feds-notes/2016/tools-and-
transmission-of-federal-reserve-monetary-policy-in-the-1920s-20161122.html (Accessed November 9, 2017).
Dynan, Karen. 2012. Is a Household Debt Overhang Holding Back Consumption? Washington, D.C.:
Brookings Institute. https://muse.jhu.edu/article/486373/summary (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Eggertsson, Gauti B. and Paul Krugman. 2010. Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-
Koo Approach. Working Paper, Princeton University. Princeton, NJ: http://www.princeton.edu/~pkrugman/
debt_deleveraging_ge_pk.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Eichengreen, Berry and Garber, Peter M., 1991. Before the Accord: U.S. Monetary-Financial Policy, 1945-51. In
Financial Markets and Financial Crises (pp. 175-206). University of Chicago Press. http://www.nber.org/
chapters/c11485.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Epstein, Gerald, 2006. Central Banks As Agents of Economic Development. UNU-WIDER, United Nations
University (UNU). Research Paper No. 2006/54. https://www.econstor.eu/
bitstream/10419/63574/1/513074155.pdf (Accessed November 9, 2017).
Epstein, Gerald. 2013. Developmental Central Banking: Winning the Future by Updating a Page from the Past.
Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 1 No. 3 (Autumn): 273287. http://inctpped.ie.ufrj.br/spiderweb/
dymsk_4/4-12S%20Epstein_Developmental%20central%20banking.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Evans, Charles L., Jonas D.M. Fisher, Alejandro Justiniano, and Jeffrey R. Campbell. 2012. Macroeconomic
Effects of FOMC Forward Guidance. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/
bpea-articles/macroeconomic-effects-of-fomc-forward-guidance/ (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Farmer, Roger. 2009. What Keynes Should Have Said. London, UK: VoxEU CEPRs Policy Portal. http://voxeu.
org/article/government-should-target-stock-market (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Friedman, Benjamin M. 2014. Has the Financial Crisis Permanently Changed the Practice of Monetary Policy?
Has It Changed the Theory of Monetary Policy? NBER Working Paper No. 20128. Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber.org/papers/w20128 (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Gagnon, Joseph. 2016. Quantitative Easing: An Underappreciated Success, Washington, D.C.: Peterson
Institute for International Economics. https://piie.com/publications/policy-briefs/quantitative-easing-
underappreciated-success (Accessed November 3, 2017).
Greenwood, Robin, Samuel G. Hanson, Joshua S. Rudolph, and Lawrence H. Summers. 2014. Government
Debt Management at the Zero Lower Bound. Washington, D.C.: Hutchins Center on Fiscal & Monetary
Policy at Brookings https://search.proquest.com/openview/3d3548c5c46c3bd2e30a2fb2d550d0e2/1?
pq-origsite=gscholar&cbl=2041179 (Accessed November 3, 2017).
Griffith, John. 2012. The Federal Housing Administration Saved the Housing Market. Washington, D.C.: Center
for American Progress. https://www.americanprogress.org/issues/economy/reports/2012/10/11/40824/
the-federal-housing-administration-saved-the-housing-market/ (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Haldane, Andrew. 1999. Pursuing Price Stability: Evidence from the United Kingdom and Other Inflation-
Targeters, Workshop on inflation targeting at the Czech Republic National Bank. Prague, Czech Republic:
September 14-15. https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/1d7b/6b95a3cbe87b56ce09233d506263704ad9b4.
pdf?_ga=2.26967997.1899835311.1509044025-1674595353.1509044025 (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Hetzel, Robert L. and Ralph F. Leach. 2001. The Treasury-Fed Accord: A New Narrative Account. Economic
Quarterly. Richmond, VA: Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. https://www.richmondfed.org/-/media/
richmondfedorg/publications/research/economic_quarterly/2001/winter/pdf/hetzel.pdf (Accessed
October 26, 2017).
Jonas, Jiri and Frederic S. Mishkin. 2003. Inflation Targeting In Transition Countries: Experience And
Prospects. NBER Working Paper No. 9667. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
http://www.nber.org/papers/w9667.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Kool, Clemens J.M. and Daniel L. Thornton. 2015. How Effective Is Central Bank Forward Guidance? St. Louis,
MO: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Research. https://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/
review/2015/12/07/how-effective-is-central-bank-forward-guidance/ (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Krugman, Paul. 1998. Japans Trap. Working Paper, Princeton University. Princeton, NJ: http://www.princeton.
edu/~pkrugman/japans_trap.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Krugman, Paul. 2016. What Have We Learnt from the Crisis? Presented at the Graduate Institute of
International and Development Studies, Geneva: September 20. https://webspace.princeton.edu/users/
pkrugman/krugman_geneva.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Leamer, E.E. 2007. Housing is the Business Cycle. NBER Working Paper No. 13428. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber.org/papers/w13428 (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Leigh, Daniel, Deniz Igan, John Simon, and Petia Topalova. 2012. Dealing with Household Debt. Washington,
D.C.: International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/pdf/c3.pdf (Accessed
October 26, 2017).
Leonhardt, David. 2017. Were About to Fall Behind the Great Depression, October 12. The New York Times.
https://www.nytimes.com/2017/10/12/opinion/great-depression-recession.html (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Mason, J.W. 2017. What Recovery: The Case for Continued Expansionary Policy at the Fed. New York, NY:
Roosevelt Institute. http://rooseveltinstitute.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/09/Wired_Roosevelt-Institute.pdf
(Accessed October 26, 2017).
Mason, J.W. and Arjun Jayadev. 2015. Loose Money, High Rates: Interest Rate Spreads in Historical
Perspective. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Vol. 38, No. 1: 93-130 http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/
abs/10.1080/01603477.2015.1065671 (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Mason, J.W. and Arjun Jayadev. 2015. The post-1980 Debt Disinflation: An Exercise in Historical Accounting.
Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 3 No. 3 (Autumn): 314-335. http://jwmason.org/wp-content/
uploads/2015/05/Mason-and-Jayadev-The-post-1980-debt-disinflation-published-version.pdf
(Accessed October 26, 2017).
Mason, J. W., Arjun Jayadev and Amanda Page-Hoongrajok. 2017. Working Paper Series: The Evolution of
State-Local Balance Sheets in the U.S., 1953-2013. Washington, D.C.: Washington Center for Equitable
Growth. http://cdn.equitablegrowth.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/07/10010227/07112017-WP-evolution-of-
state-local-balance-sheets.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Mehrling, Perry. 2010. The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970.
(Vol. 162): Harvard University Press.
Mian, Atif R. and Amir Sufi. 2012. What Explains High Unemployment? The Aggregate Demand Channel.
NBER Working Paper No. 17830. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.
nber.org/papers/w17830 (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Mian, Atif R., Kamalesh Rao and Amir Sufi. 2013. Household Balance Sheets, Consumption, and the Economic
Slump. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(4): 1687-1726. https://pdfs.semanticscholar.
org/75a5/00894c5ffa5f9203a7e223e3a61f9eb7aa29.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Palley, Thomas. 2016. Why Negative Interest Rate Policy (NIRP) Is Ineffective and Dangerous. Real-World
Economics Review. Issue No. 76: 5. http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue76/Palley76.pdf (Accessed
October 26, 2017).
Posen, Adam. 2012. Discussion of Methods of Policy Accommodation at the Interest-Rate Lower Bound.
Presented at FRBKC Economic Policy Symposium on the Changing Policy Landscape, Jackson Hole, WY:
August 31. https://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/2012/posen.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Posen, Adam. 2013. Cheap Talk Is No Alternative to Inflation Targeting. In Is Inflation Targeting Dead?
Central Banking After the Crisis, Centre for Economic Policy Research. London, UK: 59-65. http://voxeu.
org/sites/default/files/file/P248%20inflation%20targeting%207%20may.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Price, David A. 2012. When the Fed Conducts Credit Policy. Federal Reserve Region Focus (First Quarter).
https://www.richmondfed.org/~/media/richmondfedorg/publications/research/region_focus/2012/q1/pdf/
federal_reserve.pdf (Accessed November 9, 2017).
Rogoff, Kenneth. 1985. The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target. Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 100: 1169-90. https://scholar.harvard.edu/files/rogoff/files/51_qje85.pdf (Accessed
October 26, 2017).
Woodford, Michael. 2012. Methods of Policy Accommodation at the Interest-Rate Lower Bound. Presented at
Jackson Hole Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming: August 20. https://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/
sympos/2012/mw.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2014. Treasury Presentation to TBAC. Washington, D.C.: https://www.treasury.
gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/quarterly-refunding/Documents/August%202014%20Quarterly%20
Refunding%20Combined%20Charges%20for%20Archives%20FINAL.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
U.S. Office of Management and Budget. 2017. Analytical Perspectives: Budget of the U. S. Government, Fiscal
Year 2018. Washington, D.C.: https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/whitehouse.gov/files/omb/budget/fy2018/
spec.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
U.S. Federal Housing Finance Agency. 2013. Home Affordable Refinance Program: A Mid-Program Assessment.
Washington, D.C.: https://www.fhfaoig.gov/Content/Files/EVL-2013-006.pdf (Accessed October 26, 2017).
Yellen, Janet. 2011. Unconventional Monetary Policy and Central Bank Communications. Presented at the
University of Chicago Booth School of Business U.S. Monetary Policy Forum, New York, New York:
February 25. https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20110225a.htm (Accessed
October 26, 2017).