Thanks to visit codestin.com
Credit goes to www.scribd.com

0% found this document useful (0 votes)
86 views32 pages

Firm Valuation With Taxes

The document discusses firm valuation when corporate taxes are considered. It makes several key assumptions, then examines how firm value, debt, and equity are related. It presents the Modigliani-Miller theorem, which states firm value depends only on expected returns and is independent of capital structure. Hamada's equation combines MM with CAPM to relate levered and unlevered betas. The weighted average cost of capital is also discussed as the appropriate discount rate. Finally, it briefly discusses using option pricing models like Black-Scholes to value equity as a call option on firm assets.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
86 views32 pages

Firm Valuation With Taxes

The document discusses firm valuation when corporate taxes are considered. It makes several key assumptions, then examines how firm value, debt, and equity are related. It presents the Modigliani-Miller theorem, which states firm value depends only on expected returns and is independent of capital structure. Hamada's equation combines MM with CAPM to relate levered and unlevered betas. The weighted average cost of capital is also discussed as the appropriate discount rate. Finally, it briefly discusses using option pricing models like Black-Scholes to value equity as a call option on firm assets.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 32

FIRM VALUATION

WITH TAXES
Firm Valuation with
Corporate Taxes
Assumptions:
 Only corporate taxes - individual tax rate is
zero

 Capital markets are frictionless


 Individuals can borrow and lend at the risk-free
rate
 There are no costs to bankruptcy
 Firms issue only two types of claims: risk-
free debt & (risky) equity
 All firms are in the same risk class

CFi CFj

 No other taxes than corporate taxes


 All cash flow streams are perpetuities
 Everybody has the same information
 No agency costs
The P/L statement
Let
NOI = Net Operating Income
t = tax rate
D = outstanding debt
r = interest rate
P = net profit
= return requirement on equity

Assume first that D=0. Then P = NOI-t*NOI= NOI*(1-t)

The value of the firm’s equity - under the going concern


assumption - is equal to the value of the firm:
E U = V U =P/ NOI*(1-t) /
The P/L statement
Assume next that D>0.

Then P = NOI-rD-t*(NOI-rD)= (NOI-rD)*(1-t)

The firm now has to yield profits to cover both return on


equity and interest on loans. The value of the firm’s equity
- under the going concern assumption – is
E L = NOI*(1-t)/ rD(1-t)/r = E U - D(1-t), from which
E U = V U = E L +D(1-t) = E L + D – Dt.
But V L = E L + D by definition. Thus,
V U = V L – Dt. Notice that if t=0, then
V U = V L (the famous Modigliani-Miller theorem)
The Modigliani-Miller theorem implies that
“The market value of any firm is independent
of its capital structure and is given by
capitalizing its expected return at the rate
appropriate to its risk class”

(Modigliani-Miller, American Economic Review, 1958 june)


Hamada’s equation
The beta of a firm i – obtained from ordinary least squares
regression – is: βi cov(r i ,rM )/var(r M ) (1)

From the discussion above, we know that the return on


equity for a firm without debt – an unlevered firm – is
rU = NOI*(1-t)/EU (2)
and for a firm having debt – a levered firm – is
rL = (NOI-rD)*(1-t)/EL. (3)

Inserting (2) and (3) in (1) gives the betas of the


unlevered and levered firms:
Hamada’s equation

cov(NOI(1 - t)/E U ,rM ) cov(NOI(1 - t), rM )


βU E Uβ U
var(r M ) var(r M )
and
cov((NOI - rD)(1 - t)/E U ,rM )
βL
var(r M )
cov(NOI(1 - t), rM ) cov(rD(1 - t), rM )
EL βL
var(r M ) var(r M )
Hamada’s equation
By elementary covariance rules, cov(x+y,z) =
cov(xz)+cov(yz), giving the expression for L.
Furthermore, since the interest rate is assumed to be
nonstochastic, the latter term in the expression for L is
zero. Therefore,

cov(NOI(1 - t), rM )
ELβL E Uβ U
var(r M )
E Uβ U
βL
EL
Hamada’s equation
We showed above that E U = E L + D – Dt.

Inserting this in the expression for beta of the levered firm


gives the well-known Hamada’s equation [1972], combining
the Modigliani-Miller theorem with the Capital Asset Pricing
Model (CAPM):

E Uβ U (E L D - Dt)βU D
βL (1 (1 t ))βU
EL EL EL
 Assume that the firm’s debt (D) equals
the market value of the debt (B).
 When the firm makes an
investment I, its value will change
according to (C-W, p. 445)
L
V (1 t c ) E ( NOI ) B
tc
I I I
 The above investment will affect the
value of the levered firm:
L 0 n 0 n
V S S B B
0 n
Note that Equity = old + S + S
 Because the project has the same risk
as those already outstanding, the value
of the outstanding debt stays the same
( B 0 0) .
 Because the new project is financed with
new debt, equity or both
n n
I S B
 Inserting I into the above formula,
L 0 n n
V S S B
I I I
L 0
V S
1
I I
 This means that the project has to
increase the shareholders’ wealth, so
that

0 L
S V
1 0
I I

L 0
V and
S
1 0
I I
The Weighted Average Cost of Capital
(Copeland-Weston, 1988, p. 444)
• IAS 36.55: the discount rate should be the pre-tax
rate that reflects current market assessments of the
time value of money and the risks specific to the
asset
• IAS 36.57: If market-determined discount rates are
unavailable, one should recognize the entity’s:
• weighted average cost of capital
• the incremental borrowing rate
• other market borrowing rates
The Weighted Average Cost of Capital
(Copeland-Weston, 1988, p. 444)

 Recall the formula


L n
V (1 t c ) E(NOI) B
tc 1
I I I
as shown it should be greater than 1, so
(1 t c ) E(NOI) B
(1 t c )
I I
 This results in what is called “the Weighted
Average Cost of Capital”, WACC,(C-W, p.446).

B
WACC 1 tc
I
 If there are no taxes the cost of capital is
independent of capital structure.
B
What does mean ?
I
B*
 “IfV* denotes the firm’s long run target
debt ratio ... then the firm can assume,
that for any particular investment
dB B * “
dI V * (C-W, p. 446).
An alternative definition of the
weighted average cost of capital
 Definition by Haley and Shall [1973]
 Target leverage ratio

B
WACC 1 tc
V
Reproduction
value
Reproduction value = PV of the stream of goods
and services expected from the project.
How to calculate the cost of the two
components in WACC (debt & equity)
 Assumptions:
 The cost of debt = k b
 The cost of equity capital is the return on
0 n
S S
NI
0 n
S S
This can be written as (C-W, p. 449):
NI B
0 n
(1 t c )( kb )
S S S0 Sn

Since the total change in equity is


0 n
S S S
NI
, the cost of equity ks
S
can be written as
B
ks (1 t c )( kb )
S
 If the firm has no debt in its capital
structure, then k s
It can be shown that (C-W, p. 451) WACC
can be written as:
B S
WACC (1 t c )k b ks
B S B S

tax shield Percentage Percentage


cost of debt in cost of equity in
of debt the capital of equity the capital
structure structure
 This formula is the same as the
Modigliani-Miller definition

B
WACC 1 tc
B S

The M-M and the traditional definition


are identical !
Combining cost of equity equations :
B
Rf [E (Rm ) Rf ] L ( kb )(1 c)
S

Cost of equity (CAPM) Cost of equity (MM)

Then substituting the CAPM definition of


unlevered , rearranging and canceling terms...
B
[E (Rm ) Rf ] L [E (Rm ) Rf ] 1 (1 c) U
S
 If we can observe L by using observed
rates of return on equity in the stock
market, then we can also estimate U of
the firms operating cash flows.

 In absence of bankruptcy costs, it


doesn’t matter if the debt is risky or not,
L L U
V
the is still the same (V V t c B) .

C-W, 1988, p. 457.


Valuing the Equity of a Firm with the
B & S Option Pricing Model (OPM)
 The equity of a firm can be seen as a call
option.
It is possible to apply the Black &
Scholes OPM on the valuation problem.
rf T
S VN( d1 ) e DN( d2 )
ln( V / B) rf T 1
d1 T d2 d1 T
T 2
C-W, p. 467.
,where
S = The market value of equity
V = The market value of the firm’s assets
rf = The risk-free rate
T = The time to maturity
B = The face value of debt (book value)
N(.) = The cumulative normal probability of
the unit normal variate, d1
= The standard deviation of the returns
on the firm’s assets
Measuring risk (beta) with the OPM
S= Systematic risk of equity
V = Systematic risk of the firm’s assets
V = Market value of the firm’s assets
S = Market value of equity
(according to Black & Scholes)
V
S N(d1 ) V
S
 By substituting the above formula for S,
we get

VN ( d1 )
s = rf T v
VN ( d1 ) Be N( d2 )
1
= rf T v
1 ( B / V )e [ N ( d 2 ) / N ( d1 )]
The impact of parameters on S

 on equity increases monotonically


with leverage.
Increasing
parameter S

Market value (V) 


Debt (B) 
Risk-free rate (rf ) 
Variance of the firm’s 
assets’ value (
Maturity of debt (T)  C-W, p. 467.
The cost of debt funding (C-W, p. 469).

 According to the OPM k B is


V
kB rf ( rf ) N( d1 )
B

Risk premium

 The OPM, CAPM & M-M are all consistent,


when there exist no bankruptcy costs!
C-W, p. 471.
Literature
 Copeland T.E, Weston I.F (1988): Financial Theory
and Corporate Policy. Addison-Wesley. New York.
Goetzmann, William (2000): An introduction to
investment theory. Available on
http://viking.som.yale.edu/will/web_pages/will/finman5
40/classnotes/notes.html
 Hamada, R.S. (1972) “The Effect of the Firm's Capital
Structure on the Systematic Risk of Common Stocks,”
The Journal of Finance, 27(2):435-452.
 Keeping all options open (1999). The economist
08/17/99
 Johnson, Richard A & Wichern, Dean W (1997).
Business Statistics: decision making with data. Wiley.

You might also like