Investing For Long Term Value Creation
Investing For Long Term Value Creation
To cite this article: Dirk Schoenmaker & Willem Schramade (2019) Investing for long-
term value creation, Journal of Sustainable Finance & Investment, 9:4, 356-377, DOI:
10.1080/20430795.2019.1625012
a
Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University, Rotterdam, The Netherlands; bEquity Department,
CEPR, The Hague, The Netherlands; cEquity Department, NN Investment Partners, The Hague, The Netherlands
1. Introduction
The erosion of natural capital poses existential threats to national and global prosperity,
but political and economic systems are unprepared for responding to that risk (Cohen
et al. 2017). The sense of urgency is rising from a low base. The first climate bankruptcy
has already happened1 but governance, incentives and thinking are still misaligned. The
financial and corporate sectors could play an important role in turning the tide by truly
managing for long-term value creation. The concept of long-term value creation means
that a company aims to optimise its financial, social and environmental value in the
long term, making it prepared for the transition to a more sustainable economic model
(Dyllick and Muff 2016; Tirole 2017; Schoenmaker 2018). Unfortunately, current business
practices are still too narrowly focused on short-term financial returns, meaning that we
fail to achieve inclusive capitalism (e.g. Cort 2018). For decades, maximising profits has
been the leading objective in corporate finance. However, recent papers (Hart and
Zingales 2017) argue for a broader corporate objective than shareholder value in a
narrow sense.
CONTACT Willem Schramade [email protected] Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University, Postbus
1738, 3000 DR Rotterdam, The Netherlands
This article has been republished with minor changes. These changes do not impact the academic content of the article.
© 2019 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives License
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any
medium, provided the original work is properly cited, and is not altered, transformed, or built upon in any way.
JOURNAL OF SUSTAINABLE FINANCE & INVESTMENT 357
Hart and Zingales (2017) challenge the prevailing idea that externalities, like charity, can
be outsourced to the shareholders. They make a distinction between shareholder value,
which aims for maximisation of financial value only, and shareholder welfare, which incor-
porates social and environmental externalities. An important assumption in their model is
that these externalities are linked to a company’s operations. So, companies face a choice in
the degree of sustainability in their business model. The mechanism in Hart and Zingales
(2017) to guide that choice is voting by prosocial shareholders on corporate policy.
The internalisation of externalities is a dynamic process. That means that what is finan-
cially viable now can be loss making in the future (and vice versa). Some externalities are
already internalised through best business practices at companies, for example, energy and
material savings in the production process and cultivating an inspired work force. Further
externalities may be internalised in the future under pressure from government inter-
action, such as regulation and tax, societal pressure, and technological developments,
such as low cost solar and wind energy. Companies can anticipate and incorporate extern-
alities by connecting the relevant social and environmental dimensions to their business
model (Schramade 2016), making their business model transition prepared. That is in
line with the Hart-Zingales model, which assumes that the externalities are connected
to a company’s production process.
The materiality (or lack thereof) of the social and environmental dimensions is highly
context specific. It varies per industry, and also within industries, depending on the nature
of the industry, the specific company’s business model and local conditions. New evidence
indicates that there is a business case for full environmental, social and governance (ESG)
integration into investment. Companies that perform well on material ESG issues, also
show a superior financial performance (e.g. Clark, Feiner, and Viehs 2015; Khan, Serafeim,
and Yoon 2016). This is consistent with the idea that strong management of material ESG
issues brings a real competitive advantage.
Institutional investors are increasingly using ESG ratings to incorporate the social and
environmental dimensions in the investment process. But these external ratings rely on
scanty and sometimes conflicting data (Tirole 2017) and provide only limited information
on material ESG factors. Schramade (2016) argues that investing in sustainable companies
(defined as companies that optimise financial, social and environmental value in the long
term) requires doing fundamental analysis of the business model and the underlying value
drivers of investee companies. In that way, fundamental analysts can assess companies’
social and environmental value, next to their financial value. Unfortunately, very few
investors actually do this.
In this paper, we sketch the set of issues that make this problem so stubborn: the fact that
pricing, allocation and performance measurement are all versed in the language of efficient
markets; and that the other components of the current paradigm are skewed towards
optimisation within that same narrow financial risk-return framework. Long and compli-
cated investment chains -from the ultimate provider of capital to the ultimate user of
capital- mean that incentives are distorted, the horizon gets shorter with each extra party
in the chain and meaningful information is lost along the chain (Neal and Warren 2015).
We outline the contours of an alternative paradigm that is better able to pursue long
term value creation (summarised in Figure 1). It breaks away from efficient market think-
ing and assumes adaptive markets where the incorporation of sustainability information
into stock prices is an adaptive process, of which the success is dependent on the
358 D. SCHOENMAKER AND W. SCHRAMADE
Figure 1. Contours of an alternative paradigm. Note: EMH = Efficient Markets Hypothesis; AMH = Adap-
tive Markets Hypothesis; F = Financial; S = Social; E = Environmental.
cannot systematically beat the market. The market is supposed to be so efficient that it
immediately incorporates all relevant new information, making it impossible for investors
to benefit from superior insights or information. While there are differences in risk-return
profiles across assets, these assets are assumed to be priced accordingly. Arbitrage makes
sure that prices stay correct: abnormally high return assets immediately attract more fund
flows, which drive up prices and reset expected returns back to the market rate. As a result,
in the world of efficient markets, all information is incorporated in stock prices.
However, there is plenty of evidence that markets are not always efficient. Whereas the
efficient markets hypothesis assumes perfectly rational investors, a vast body of behav-
ioural finance literature has shown since the 1970s that people (including investors) are
far from rational (e.g. the early work by Tversky and Kahneman (1973), the review
article by Barberis and Thaler (2003)). The efficiency of markets has also been questioned
by strong evidence on the momentum factor, which shows that stocks that have done well
over the past few months tend to continue to do well over the next several months (Jega-
deesh and Titman 1993). Behavioural finance indicates that such lack of rationality has
important implications for financial markets, which can be seriously overvalued or under-
valued for extended periods of time. More recently, these behavioural anomalies have been
supplemented by sustainability anomalies (e.g. Khan, Serafeim, and Yoon 2016). This
indicates that pricing is a far from perfect signal, which should not be followed blindly.
Market benchmarks are indices, such as the MSCI World Index or the MSCI All Country
World Index, that consist of a basket of the largest companies by market capitalisation in a
certain market (i.e. the global stock market, a regional market like Developed Asia or a
sector like Real Estate). The underlying idea is that the index represents ‘the market’.
When assessing a fund manager’s performance, his or her performance will be measured
against such a benchmark (was it higher or lower over the past 5 years, 3 years, 1 year, 6
months, 1 month, and 1 day?), correcting for the amount of risk the fund manager took in
achieving that result.
Measures for such market risk-taking include beta, tracking error, information ratio
and Sharpe ratio (e.g. Elton et al. 2014). These performance measures relate a portfolio’s
return to the market return (or the risk free rate return), which is calculated in a financial
risk-return space. In this view, there is no need to analyse the companies in the portfolio
themselves; only the sensitivity of the portfolio’s return to the market. The social and
environmental dimensions are not included in these performance measures. And how
can markets maximise long term value if its major components are not measured?
information on their policies in the public domain; or they get misclassified and compared
with the wrong kind of firms.
Third, scores are ‘industry neutral’ and based mainly on operations, while hardly taking
into account the products of the companies in question. This can result in ratings that are
intuitively wrong, as the least bad companies in very unsustainable industries (say coal or
tobacco) still get very high scores and can be named sustainability leaders.
Finally, there are too many stocks (as many as 70) covered per analyst, which also
makes an in-depth assessment unlikely. While the ESG ratings agencies do aim to
address these design limitations, they seem trapped in their own frameworks, which
they are reluctant to change because they want to maintain consistency in their data.
Hence, it is not surprising to see a lack of correlation in scores between ratings agencies.
Across 1600 stocks in the MSCI World benchmark, Howard (2016) finds a correlation of
26% between the scores assigned by the two largest rating agencies. Based on survey data,
Mooij (2017a) concludes that ‘reporting fatigue, a lack of convergence and the (some-
times) poor quality and transparency have made the ESG rating industry more vice
than virtue in the adoption of responsible investment’.
In sum, ESG ratings need to get better. Investors should not accept them as the con-
clusion on a company’s sustainability quality, but rather as a starting point for analysis.
What is more, they should reconsider some of their core assumptions to really embed
ESG in their investment process.
typically not fully aligned, neither across nor within organisations. These problems are
exacerbated when investing for the long term, where the payoff is distant and often
highly uncertain (Neal and Warren 2015). The human reflex is to battle such uncertainty
by focusing on short-term metrics that can be measured.
Problems arise from differences in investment horizons, a tendency to evaluate and
reward based on short-term results and a failure to commit. While an institutional inves-
tor might wish to pursue a long-term investment strategy for its beneficiaries, it might also
use a quarterly benchmark to evaluate its asset managers internally. Next, an institutional
investor might appoint internal and external gatekeepers to benchmark them against each
other. In such a setting, it is very difficult to avoid tactical investment decisions aimed at
short-term investment gains.
looking metrics, which gives incentives for taking shortcuts, without real accountability.
Still, those metrics are not entirely without merit. So what to do with them? A possible
solution lies in using those same metrics in a more flexible, slightly adapted way, while
being cognisant of their limitations (e.g. only measuring the financial dimension).
For example, instead of measuring performance against a single benchmark, one
could use:
An absolute return target is appealing as it is often more closely aligned with the goals
of the beneficiaries, which are typically in the realm of building capital over the long run
rather than beating indices. Jordà et al. (2017) find a long-term average return on equity of
about 7% in a cross-country study. An absolute return target could, for example, be 7%
over 5 year cycles. An absolute return target is not the holy grail of performance measure-
ment, but simply switching perspective and putting performance in a wider context is
valuable.
concern for metals and mining companies than for financial institutions. Pryshlakivsky
and Searcy (2017) provide a list of types of such contingencies. Third, the KPIs in question
may not measure all that should be measured. Fourth, it is not clear if performance on
certain KPIs means a sufficient contribution to achieving a more sustainable model. As
Pryshlakivsky and Searcy (2017) find, these indicators tend to be self-referential rather
than context-based. In fact, when investigating the sustainability reports issued by sustain-
ability leader companies in Canada, they found none of the 463 environmental indicators
identified to be context-based.
In sum, reporting on sustainability KPIs is still in its infancy. Too often, companies
produce sustainability reports with data on immaterial issues that happen to be measur-
able. A dramatic improvement in reporting is needed and this should be a focus point in
company engagement. Such improved reporting should be context-based and show to
what extent a company harms or helps global and local sustainability goals.
ready for a world with high sugar and salt prices (due to taxes on them to reduce intake).
But it might be experimenting with food that is tasty, affordable and healthy - thereby
creating the option to survive such a scenario, and turn out to be transition prepared
after all.
Figure 3. Financial impact of qualitative and quantitative ESG information. Note: The first step is iden-
tifying the company’s material ESG issues. The second step is assessing those issues in both qualitative
and quantitative ways to arrive at their financial impact (the final step). Source: NN Investment Partners.
368 D. SCHOENMAKER AND W. SCHRAMADE
preparedness, they require indicators that ‘work’ at the market level, i.e. are relevant across
companies and sectors. But so far, these indicators are rare because materiality is industry
or even company specific. Where quant ESG is successful, it is mostly at tracking short-
term ESG momentum (Kaiser 2017) often without a theoretical model or clear thought
behind it, let alone a view on transitions. However, it can be very useful in a complemen-
tary role to fundamental analysis.
markets hypothesis (Lo 2017), with pockets of poorly used (and poorly available) data as
inefficiencies and opportunities to be exploited.
ESG integration can be complemented by engagement with investee companies (see
Section 3.5 below) to reap the full benefits of ESG research. However, for that to
happen, we need a change of governance and incentives in the investment chain, which
is overly long and complicated.
investors with higher learning capacity (i.e. skilled investors) form more concentrated portfo-
lios. These results suggest, in contrast to traditional asset pricing theory and in support of
information advantage theory, that concentrated investment strategies can be optimal.
Statman (2004) shows that a well-diversified stock portfolio needs to include just 50–
100 stocks to eliminate idiosyncratic or unsystematic variance of stock returns. There are
smaller benefits of diversification beyond those 100 stocks, but they are exhausted when
the number of stocks surpasses 300 stocks (see Figure 5). Risk management should
monitor that the stocks are not overly correlated (reducing their diversification potential)
and are spread over sectors and countries. Moreover, diversification gains are mainly
driven by a well-balanced allocation over different asset classes, like equities, bonds and
alternative investments (i.e. real estate, private equity, hedge funds, commodities and
infrastructure) (see for example Jacobs, Müller, and Weber 2014). Thus, for diversification
it is more important to have a concentrated portfolio in each asset class than to have a very
diversified portfolio (beyond 100 securities) in a single asset class.
Moreover, diversification comes at a cost, which might cancel out the low fee costs of
passive investing. First, diversification reduces selectiveness, which disappears almost
completely in passive strategies. In passive investing, it is not yet possible to invest only
in the sub-set of companies that are able and willing to transform towards sustainable
business models. However, it is possible to build passive investments on ESG adjusted
indices that exclude the worst industries, such as coal and tobacco. This negative screening
is a rather crude measure, but does steer investment away from the worst companies. And
over time such indices should become more sophisticated.
Second, the larger the number of stocks owned, the harder it becomes to have sufficient
knowledge about, and really engage with, multiple companies in the portfolio. Third, on
an aggregated level, widely diversified portfolios result in inadequate monitoring of cor-
porate management teams. A free-rider problem arises as small percentage stakes mean
that few investors have sufficient incentives to monitor management.
3.5.2. Engagement
Another element of an active investment approach is effective engagement with investee
companies on the long-term, both behind the scenes by meeting with companies and in
the annual general meeting by voting (McCahery, Sautner, and Starks 2016). Investors and
companies can exchange not only funds, but also ideas on how best to put these funds to
work. Even the companies that are already on a journey to become more sustainable still
need help in developing the most useful and cost-effective disclosure practices. And while
lots of investors want companies to provide more and better disclosure of their ESG
exposures, they tend to shy away from giving explicit recommendations. So, investors
need to become more active in communicating their demands and preferences for infor-
mation (Higgins et al. 2017).
However, such engagement is costly. It requires human resources, expertise and time of
the asset managers, ideally delivered in cooperation between portfolio managers, invest-
ment analysts and sustainability specialists. This is only feasible in a concentrated and
actively managed portfolio: 100 stocks can be followed and engaged by a small team of
people who work closely together. Engagement needs to be actively managed to allow
the investment case knowledge of portfolio managers and investment analysts to be inte-
grated into the engagement.
In practice, this happens at very few financial firms. Rather, engagement is typically
done at the group level for a small percentage of the holdings and by a team of engagement
specialists that lack knowledge of the firms’ investment cases and hence miss important
points, resulting in engagement on matters that are often not material. As passive portfo-
lios typically have thousands of stocks, the best a passive asset owner can do in practice is
to vote for all those companies along the guidelines of a proxy advisor and do engagement
with a few dozen companies.
Large (passive) asset managers could have a strong impact on promoting sustainable
business practices by their size. However, US evidence on proxy voting (Bolton et al.
2019) indicates that mutual funds, including the large passive asset managers (Black-
Rock, Vanguard and State Street), are more narrowly ‘money conscious’ investors that
often vote with management, while pensions funds support a more social and environ-
ment-friendly orientation of the firm. Moreover, Bebchuk and Hirst (2019) show that
mutual funds have an incentive to under-invest in stewardship, as they bear the full
cost but only get a tiny part of the benefit.4 For Europe, Dimson, Karakaş, and Li
(2018) find that institutional investors, in particular pension funds, are active in coordi-
nated engagement to influence firms on environmental and social issues. The large US
mutual funds, which also have a large presence in Europe, are absent in these coordi-
nated engagements.
course, the answer does not need to be binary, as one could also invest in a mix of leaders
and improving laggards.
Investing in the laggards does raise additional questions. First, how to determine the
size and likelihood of the improvement? Second, will that improvement be good
enough to be consistent with global sustainability development goals or is it perhaps
better if the company perishes? Hence, where is the demarcation between laggards that
really want to (and will) improve significantly and the laggards that are beyond salvation?
3.6. Investment chains: from long & complex to short & simple
Building on our stylised investment chain in Figure 2, Figure 6 contrasts the ideal and the
current investment chain. The middle column illustrates the ideal investment chain from a
Figure 6. Ideal versus actual investment chains and their components. Note: IV = Integrated Value; FV
= Financial Value; SV = Social Value; EV = Environmental Value.
JOURNAL OF SUSTAINABLE FINANCE & INVESTMENT 373
sustainable finance perspective. The asset owner (e.g. a pension fund or a retail client) is a
long-term investor, who cares about financial, social and environmental returns. If it has
sufficient scale, the asset owner can do its asset management in house. If not, the asset
owner appoints an asset manager, who invests on his or her behalf. The asset owner
asks the asset manager to report on financial and ESG returns, including carbon-related
financial disclosures of the invested companies. The asset manager also actively engages
with the company to promote sustainable business practices.
The final party in the investment chain is the company, which ideally has a board that
has adopted a sustainable business model, and applies integrated reporting. Closing the
circle, the integrated report provides the necessary information on financial, social and
environmental values to the asset manager, who can report back to the asset owner. All
parts of the chain are expected to understand the important aspects of sustainable
finance and its nuances.
This ideal investment chain does not exist in practice, and the right column of Figure 6
is a more realistic representation of current investment chains. First, there are multiple
parties in the chain: both within each nexus of the chain and across multiple nexuses
(an asset manager may delegate the investment to another asset manager and so on).
An example of the latter is an asset manager for a pension fund, who invests in a hedge
fund or private equity. There may be so many delegates that monitoring becomes very
hard. Second, performance metrics tend to be narrow. For example, the performance of
the asset manager is often measured against a clearly articulated benchmark. Third, incen-
tives are shorter term than desirable given fiduciary duty and investment goals.
Alecta’s total management costs are 0.09% of assets under management, of which
investment management costs are 0.02%. Alecta can keep its operating costs very low,
because it has cut out external asset managers and consultants. While a large pension
fund like Alecta has sufficient scale to do this, it might be more challenging for smaller
pension funds to do this. Such smaller players as well as retail investors will have to
rely on asset managers.
3.8. Role for asset management: truly performing the social function of finance
A new paradigm has serious implications for the role of asset management. The industry
can add a lot of value and build trust by offering active management aimed at long term
value creation, truly performing the social function of finance. However, for that potential
to be met, the industry needs to step up its efforts in terms of the depth and breadth of
transition preparedness analysis, its engagement, and the concentration of its portfolios.
Ideally, this feeds into passive products as well, making the two types of investment
mutually reinforcing.
In addition, asset managers will have to make products available to the public that not
only do the above, but also do it in a way that is credible and verifiable, which is quite a
challenge indeed as even professionals are confused by the current state of the field. This
task is not merely hypothetical since client demand for sustainable and impact investing
products is strongly on the rise. The younger members of wealth families seem particularly
eager to invest their capital in ways that make the world a better place.
4. Conclusions
The financial system is instrumental in achieving the transition to a sustainable
economy. To fulfil that societal role, investors have to move from a focus on short-
term financials, towards long term value creation. This requires doing fundamental
research into the investee companies. While several financial institutions aim to
move to investing for long-term value creation, traditional investment approaches
are still built and run on the concepts of efficient markets and portfolio theory. More-
over, long and complicated investment chains exacerbate the reliance on market
metrics.
This article identifies the contours of an alternative investment paradigm, aimed at
investing for long-term value creation. Its ingredients are adaptive markets thinking,
short investment chains, and active management in concentrated portfolios, with deep
engagement aimed at assessing transition preparedness.
These alternative ways are available, but not yet widely used. Some are showing the way,
but the asset management industry has yet to deliver its added value. Achieving paradigm
change requires a change of mindsets. For this, integrated sustainable finance education
and incentives from governance and regulation are needed. Finance education at univer-
sities is not much different from what it was two decades ago. That needs to change. We
need students that are trained in assessing transition preparedness; who are able to look
beyond both the numbers and the fuss. That requires examples, training and sharing of
best practices. And we need an evolution in governance, incentives and regulation that
stimulates long-term value creation.
JOURNAL OF SUSTAINABLE FINANCE & INVESTMENT 375
Notes
1. Chunka Mui, ‘PG&E is just the first of many climate change bankruptcies’, Forbes, January 2019.
2. Indeed, Shrivastava and Addas (2014) find that strong governance can engender high per-
formance on E and S.
3. The lost time injury frequency rate measures the number of lost time injuries occurring in a
workplace per 1 million hours worked. An LTIFR of 7, for example, shows that 7 lost time
injuries occur on a jobsite every 1 million work hours.
4. While an asset owner receives a proportional increase in value of a company due to engage-
ment, the asset manager (which charges a small fee on assets under management) only
receives a tiny amount (the fee times the proportional increase in company value).
Acknowledgement
The authors are grateful to Magnus Billing, Mathijs van Dijk, Han van der Hoorn, Rob Lake and
Marno Verbeek, two anonymous reviewers and seminar participants at the University of Zurich
and Vienna University for very useful comments.
Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.
ORCID
Willem Schramade http://orcid.org/0000-0003-2004-4409
References
Ambachtsheer, K. 2016. The Future of Pension Management. New York: Wiley.
Andersson, M., P. Bolton, and F. Samama. 2016. “Hedging Climate Risk.” Financial Analysts
Journal 72 (3): 13–32.
Barberis, N., and R. Thaler. 2003. “A Survey of Behavioral Finance.” In Handbook of the Economics
of Finance. Vol. 1, edited by G. Constantinides, M. Harris, and R. Stulz, 1053–1128. Amsterdam:
Elsevier.
Bebchuk, L., and S. Hirst. 2019. “Index Funds and the Future of Corporate Governance: Theory,
Evidence, and Policy.” Columbia Law Review 119: forthcoming.
Bloomberg. 2013. Bloomberg Carbon Risk Valuation Tool. New York: Bloomberg.
Bloomberg. 2015. Water Risk Valuation Tool: Integrating Natural Capital Limits into Financial
Analysis of Mining Stocks. New York: Bloomberg.
Bolton, P., T. Li, E. Ravina, and H. Rosenthal. 2019. “Investor Ideology.” CEPR Discussion Paper,
DP12633.
Cappucci, M. 2017. "The ESG Integration Paradox." Working Paper. Boston, MA: Harvard
Management Company.
Choi, N., M. Fedenia, H. Skiba, and T. Sokolyk. 2017. “Portfolio Concentration and Performance of
Institutional Investors Worldwide.” Journal of Financial Economics 123 (1): 189–208.
Clark, G., A. Feiner, and M. Viehs. 2015. “From the Stockholder to the Stakeholder: How
Sustainability Can Drive Financial Outperformance.” Working Paper, Smith School of
Enterprise and the Environment, University of Oxford. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2508281.
Cohen, F., K. Hamilton, C. Hepburn, F. Sperling, and A. Teytelboym. 2017. “The Wealth of Nature:
Increasing National Wealth and Reducing Risk by Measuring and Managing Natural Capital.”
Working Paper, Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET) at the Oxford Martin School
and Smith School of Enterprise and the Environment.
376 D. SCHOENMAKER AND W. SCHRAMADE
Cort, T. 2018. “Incentivizing the Direction of Multi-Capital Toward Inclusive Capitalism.” Journal
of Sustainable Finance & Investment 8 (3): 203–212.
Cremers, M., and A. Pareek. 2016. “Patient Capital Outperformance: The Investment Skill of
High Active Share Managers Who Trade Infrequently.” Journal of Financial Economics 122
(2): 288–306.
Dimson, E., O. Karakaş, and X. Li. 2018. “Coordinated Engagements.” Working Paper. https://ssrn.
com/abstract=3209072.
Dyllick, T., and K. Muff. 2016. “Clarifying the Meaning of Sustainable Business.” Organization and
Environment 29 (2): 156–174.
ECCE (European Centre for Corporate Engagement). 2016. The Materiality of ESG Factors for
Equity Investment Decisions: Academic Evidence. Maastricht: Maastricht University.
Elton, E., M. Gruber, S. Brown, and W. Goetzmann. 2014. Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment
Analysis. 9th ed. New Jersey: Wiley.
Fama, E. 1970. “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work.” The Journal of
Finance 25 (2): 383–417.
Friedman, M. 1970. “The Social Responsibility of Business is to Increase its Profits.” The New York
Times Magazine, September 13.
Future-Fit. 2018. Methodology Guide. https://futurefitbusiness.org/resources/.
Haldane, A. 2014. “The Age of Asset Management.” Speech at the London Business School,
London, April 4.
Hart, O., and L. Zingales. 2017. “Companies Should Maximize Shareholder Welfare Not Market
Value.” Journal of Law, Finance, and Accounting 2 (2): 247–275.
Higgins, K., J. White, A. Beller, and M. Schapiro. 2017. “The SEC and Improving Sustainability
Reporting.” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 29 (2): 22–31.
High Level Expert Group on Sustainable Finance. 2018. Financing a Sustainable European
Economy. Final Report. Brussels: European Union.
Hong, H., F. Li, and J. Xu. 2016. “Climate Risks and Market Efficiency.” NBER WP Nr. 22890.
Howard, J. 2016. “Painting by Numbers - The Difficulties of Measuring Sustainability.” Market
Insights, Schroders, London.
Jacobs, H., S. Müller, and M. Weber. 2014. “How Should Individual Investors Diversify? An
Empirical Evaluation of Alternative Asset Allocation Policies.” Journal of Financial Markets
19 (1): 62–85.
Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman. 1993. “Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications
for Stock Market Efficiency.” The Journal of Finance 48 (1): 65–91.
Jordà, O., K. Knoll, D. Kuvshinov, M. Schularick, and A. Taylor. 2017. “The Rate of Return on
Everything, 1870–2015.” CEPR Discussion Paper 12509.
Kaiser, L. 2017. “Style, Momentum and ESG Investing.” Working Paper. https://ssrn.com/abstract=
2993843.
Khan, M., G. Serafeim, and A. Yoon. 2016. “Corporate Sustainability: First Evidence on
Materiality.” The Accounting Review 91 (6): 1697–1724.
Lo, A. 2017. Adaptive Markets: Financial Evolution at the Speed of Thought. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Markowitz, H. 1952. “Portfolio Selection.” Journal of Finance 7 (1): 77–91.
McCahery, J., Z. Sautner, and L. Starks. 2016. “Behind the Scenes: The Corporate Governance
Preferences of Institutional Investors.” The Journal of Finance 71 (6): 2905–2932.
Mooij, S. 2017a. “The ESG Initiative Industry; Vice or Virtue in the Adoption of Responsible
Investment?” Journal of Environmental Investing 8 (1): 331–367.
Mooij, S. 2017b. “Asset Owners and the Diffusion of Responsible Investment. What Explains the
Low Rate of Adoption?” Working Paper, Oxford University.
Neal, D., and G. Warren. 2015. “Long-term Investing as an Agency Problem.” CIFR Paper No. 063/
2015, Centre for International Finance and Regulation, Sydney.
Pryshlakivsky, J., and C. Searcy. 2017. “A Heuristic Model for Establishing Trade-Offs in Corporate
Sustainability Performance Measurement Systems.” Journal of Business Ethics 144 (2): 323–342.
Reporting 3.0. 2018. Blueprint 5: Transformation Journey. https://reporting3.org/publications/.
JOURNAL OF SUSTAINABLE FINANCE & INVESTMENT 377
Schoenmaker, D. 2018. “A Framework for Sustainable Finance.” CEPR Discussion Paper, DP12603.
Schoenmaker, D., and W. Schramade. 2019. Principles of Sustainable Finance. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Schramade, W. 2016. “Bridging Sustainability and Finance: The Value Driver Adjustment
Approach.” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 28 (2): 17–28.
Schramade, W. 2019. “A Sustainable Finance Case Study: Air France-KLM.” Working Paper,
Erasmus Platform for Sustainable Value Creation, Erasmus University Rotterdam.
Shrivastava, P., and A. Addas. 2014. “The Impact of Corporate Governance on Sustainability
Performance.” Journal of Sustainable Finance & Investment 4 (1): 21–37.
Simon, M. 2017. Real Impact: The New Economics of Social Change. New York: Nation Books.
Statman, M. 2004. “The Diversification Puzzle.” Financial Analysts Journal 60 (4): 44–53.
Tirole, J. 2017. Economics for the Common Good. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman. 1973. “Availability: A Heuristic for Judging Frequency and
Probability.” Cognitive Psychology 5 (2): 207–232.
WRI (World Resources Institute). 2015. Greenhouse Gas Protocol. Washington, DC: World
Resources Institute.