Thanks to visit codestin.com
Credit goes to www.scribd.com

0% found this document useful (0 votes)
23 views37 pages

Class13 2023 Fall HO

This document discusses various measures of liquidity and trading costs that can be observed in financial markets. It describes: 1) Quoted spreads, which measure the implicit cost of a hypothetical small-size round-trip trade based on the best bid and ask quotes. 2) Effective spreads, which measure the actual trading cost relative to the mid-quote by comparing the execution price of a market order to the mid-quote just before. 3) Realized spreads, which measure the trading cost relative to the mid-price some time after the transaction to allow the market to incorporate new information. Realized spreads typically estimate lower costs for liquidity providers than effective spreads.

Uploaded by

kokmunwai717
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
23 views37 pages

Class13 2023 Fall HO

This document discusses various measures of liquidity and trading costs that can be observed in financial markets. It describes: 1) Quoted spreads, which measure the implicit cost of a hypothetical small-size round-trip trade based on the best bid and ask quotes. 2) Effective spreads, which measure the actual trading cost relative to the mid-quote by comparing the execution price of a market order to the mid-quote just before. 3) Realized spreads, which measure the trading cost relative to the mid-price some time after the transaction to allow the market to incorporate new information. Realized spreads typically estimate lower costs for liquidity providers than effective spreads.

Uploaded by

kokmunwai717
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 37

FINA 4103

Class Note 13: Measuring Liquidity

Jun Aoyagi
HKUST

Fall 2023

0 / 36
Measure of Liquidity: What Theories Suggest?

I We learned canonical models that explain bid-ask spread


I information asymmetry (Glosten-Milgrom)
I order-processing cost (Stoll and Huang)
I inventory cost (Stoll)
I And the price impact of order flow
I again, information asymmetry matters (Kyle)
I As a trader, you are concerned about
I short-run cost (bid-ask spread)
I transient/long-run price impact

I In reality, what can we observe?

1 / 36
Actual Measure of Liquidity
I In general, information and utility-related variables are not
observable
I Who is informed/noise? How much informed?
I How risk averse dealers are?
I What we can observe is the trading cost
I Reverse engineer and estimate frictions

2 / 36
Measures of Trading Costs

I Some explicit costs are easy to observe


I Ex, dealer commissions, trading fees, etc
I Steadily decreasing since 2000s

I What about the implicit cost of trading?


I Implicit: costs arising from illiquidity
I Also declined ∼ 2007 but shot up afterwards

I Basic idea:

Illiquidity cost = Execution price - Benchmark

I benchmark is the price obtained in perfectly liquid market

3 / 36
Measures of Trading Costs

I Depending on “what if” situation, we have several measures of


spreads
1. Quoted spread
2. Effective spread
3. Realized spread
I Other trading cost measures
1. VWAP
2. Price impact measure
3. Amihud liquidity ratio
4. Roll’s measure

I Measure of information: PIN

4 / 36
Measures Based on Quotes Information

5 / 36
Quoted Spread

I From LOB data, we observe (N)BBO, i.e., A and B.


I The quoted bid-ask spread (“the” bid-ask spread):

S= A−B

I Sometimes use relative spread: normalized by the mid-quote

S S
s= = .
m ( A + B)/2

I Quoted spread measures the implicit cost for a small-size


round-trip trade

6 / 36
Determinant of Quoted Spread

I The GM model implies S is determined by


I µ: information-to-noise (signal-to-noise) ratio
I σ: value uncertainty
I δ, v̄: dealers’ belief

I Observing S, cannot separate these parameters (as well as other


factors)
I We may estimate how much information the order flow contains
I called PIN (probability of informed trading) measure
I will see later

7 / 36
Quoted Spread for a Large Order

I What if a trade has a larger size, |q| > 1?


I the order must walk up (down) the LOB, being executed at worse
prices

I Use average bid and ask prices to execute q

S̄ = Ā(q) − B̄(q)

I Ā(q) is the average ask price the order must pay

I In both cases, the quoted spread reflects the liquidity available at a


given point of time for hypothetical transactions

8 / 36
Data Issues in Quoted Spread

I For the quoted spread, need (N)BBO data at various points in time
I For the average quoted spread, need information about depth and
prices beyond (N)BBO
I this information is not always readily available

I Practitioners often measure the costs based on transaction price


data

9 / 36
Effective Spread

I The quoted spread is for a hypothetical round-trip trade at a


given point in time

I The actual execution price you pay/receive will be different from


BBO spread
I Effective spreads measure the actual trading cost
I A market buy trades at average price of $75.5, while the prevailing
mid-quote is $75.45
I What is the cost relative to the perfectly liquid market?

10 / 36
Effective Spread

Effective spread
Effective spread is the difference between the price at which a market
order is executed and the mid-quote on the market the instant before.

I Let d ∈ {+1, −1} be the direction of order


I If d is executed at price p and mid-quote is m

Se = d ( p − m )

I Relative effective spread: se = Se /m

I m: benchmark when market is perfectly liquid (i.e., no spread)


I For |q| > 1, use the average execution price p̄(q) − m

11 / 36
Effective Spread: Implications

I Se is also called a “slippage” measure


I your order triggers change in the price
I order’s impact on the price
I Based on the past information, capturing retrospective market
liquidity
I unlike the quoted spread, which is liquidity for incoming (future)
orders
I If average over many trades, Se measures market liquidity
I how each order impact the price and causes deviation of post-trade
price from the mid quote

12 / 36
Issues in Using Effective Spread

Split orders
Consider a large market order split into multiple small ones and
traded gradually. We want to compare the cost of split orders with that
of trading all at once.

I If you are a trader, easy to compute the effective spread for split
orders
I Compute average execution price; and
I m just before the first split order

I What if you are a researcher or policy maker?

13 / 36
Issues in Using Effective Spread (cont’d)

Misalignment in data
We see a transaction at price $98.88 at a moment when the best bid and
ask are $98.85 and $98.92.

I The trade might happen a few seconds earlier when b = 98.88 and
a = 98.92 (so its “sell” initiated)
I but opposite is also possible; data may not tell you the trading
direction
I Lee and Ready (1991): misalignment in data
I quote recording is generally faster than the trade recording
I delays up to five seconds are common

I They proposed the algorithm to classify (but not perfect)

14 / 36
Profits for Liquidity Providers (Market Makers)

I Quoted and effective spreads = cost for liquidity takers


I What about the cost (or profit) of liquidity providers?
I Naive prediction: taker’s cost = maker’s profit
I but need to incorporate timing

15 / 36
Profits for Liquidity Providers (Market Makers)

I A dealer buys at $100 from her customer when B = $100 and


A = $102
I To unwind this position, she may sell it at prevailing ask at
A = $102
I leading to $2 profits per share
I A − B would be a good measure
I But what if the prices change to B0 = $99 and A0 = $100?
I e.g., due to information updates

I If the price moves in the direction of liquidity-taking orders,


effective (and quoted) spreads overestimate maker’s profit

16 / 36
Realized Spread

Realized Spread
The realized (half) spread is the difference between (i) the execution
price and (ii) the mid-price at some time after the transaction.

I Let the market incorporate information into the quotes


I Estimate the spread by using mt+∆ as benchmark
I Choice of ∆ depends on
I data frequency and research objective
I market characteristics

17 / 36
Realized Spread

I Formally, it is defined as

Sr = d t ( p t − m t + ∆ )

I dt : trade direction
I pt : execution price
I mt : mid-point quote

I Trade at t and unwind at t + ∆ (in perfectly liquid market)

18 / 36
Realized Spread: Decomposition
I We can re-write it as
Se
z }| {
Sr = d t ( p t − m t ) − d t ( m t + ∆ − m t )

∴ E[Sr ] = E[Se ] − E[dt (mt+∆ − mt )]

I Sr (profit for dealers) is smaller than Se (cost for taker) if

E[dt (mt+∆ − mt )] > 0


I Change in the mid-price is positively correlated with order
direction
I “buy” leads to upward revision in belief (m
t+∆ > mt )

I What if E[Se ] is very small?

19 / 36
Quoted, Effective, and Realized Spreads

I In 2005, SEC rule 605 mandates reporting of monthly statistics by


exchanges
I called “Dash-5” reports

I Include average effective spreads, realized spreads, and spreads


for various order sizes.

20 / 36
Dash-5 Reporting of Microsoft in 2005

21 / 36
Other Measures of Trading Costs

22 / 36
VWAP

I Let’s say we don’t have quote data


I cannot compute and use the mid-point quote as benchmark

I Use the average transaction prices over a day


I Volume-weighted average price (VWAP)

$ volume of trading
VWAP = = ∑ wt p t
# of shares traded t∈ T

with
|qt |
wt =
∑t∈ T | qt |

I qt and pt : size and price of tth trade

23 / 36
VWAP

I Evaluate your trade at your trading price P and VWAP


I involves comparison with effective and realized spreads
I Obvious problem arises when your order has a significant share
I say, your order is the only order in the day

I Also, when brokers are evaluated relative to VWAP, they have


incentive to game with VWAP

24 / 36
Price Impact Measure

I Use data on mid-prices and order imbalances


I The price impact estimation:

mt+∆ − mt = λqt + ut (1)

I ∆: appropriate lag
I qt : order imbalance (buy - sell volume)
I ut : estimation error
I λ̂ measures how order pressures affect the mid-quotes
I c.f., Kyle (1985) model

25 / 36
Price Impact Measure: Estimation Result

I Stoll (2000, JF): estimation in NYSE/AMSE and Nasdaq


I λ > 0 for 95% of stocks (5% significance)
I λ = 0.75% for small-cap stocks
I λ = 0.5% for large-cap stocks
I Hasbrouck (2007): modified the estimation using trading volume
I when trading direction is not observable

26 / 36
Amihud Liquidity Measure

I Amihud (2002) introduced the “illiquidity” ratio

|r t |
It =
Volt
I The absolute return |rt | relative to volume Volt over a given period
I Measuring changes in return when additional volume is traded
I Implication is similar to the price impact regression in (1)
I m
t+∆ − mt is replaced by return rt
I qt is replaced by volume Volt
I Can compute without using quote/order direction data

27 / 36
Some Other Measures

I No-trading: Lesmond, Ogden, and Trzcinka (1999)


I fraction of no-trade days (or time with no price changes) as a
measure of illiquidity
I Implementation shortfall: Perold (1988)
I brokers sometimes delay customer’s order excessively
I derive measure incorporating the delays

28 / 36
Measuring Information Frictions

I Glosten and Milgrom (1985) and Kyle (1985) are based on


information asymmetry
I informed-to-noise ratio matters
I caveat: we cannot directly observe informed/noise

I But order flow is observable


I Can we reverse estimate it from order flow?
I Easley, Hvidkjaer, and O’Hara (2002)

29 / 36
Information Measure: Event Uncertainty

I Each period has two possibilities:


I α: asset fundamentals change (v → v ± σ)
I 1 − α: nothing happens to v
I In both cases, noise traders trade
I buy and sell u quantities in expectation
I Only if innovations happen to v, informed traders trade
I trade with intensity µ
I always in the right trading direction

I This setting incorporates event (or model) uncertainty

30 / 36
Information Measure: Event Uncertainty

31 / 36
Information Measure: Event Uncertainty

I Assuming Poisson arrival,1 we can write the joint probability of


having buy (b) and sell (s) as function of parameters

Pr(b, s) = f (α, µ, u)

I think of is as the number of b and s in a day

I Using order flow data, estimate α, µ, and u by maximum


likelihood
I Use estimated values to evaluate information frictions (and
spread)

1 Beyond the scope of the class. Refer to Ch 6.2 of Hasbrouck (2007)


32 / 36
Information Measure: PIN

I The expected total order arrival intensity is

2u + αµ

I Probability of informed trading (PIN):


αµ
PI N =
2u + αµ

I Prob that a randomly chosen trader on a randomly chosen day is


informed

I Ex., applying to the simplified GM model, the spread for the first
trade should be
A−B
S= = PI N × σ
2

33 / 36
PIN Analyses
I Easley, et al., (2002): estimated PIN for all NYSE common stocks

34 / 36
PIN Analyses

I Easley, et al., (2002): estimated PIN for all NYSE common stocks
I median PIN = 19%
I difference across stocks is not large

I PIN is negatively correlated with firm size (ρ = −0.58)


I PIN is positively correlated in cross-section with
1. stock return volatility (ρ = 0.24)
2. bid-ask spread (ρ = 0.35)

I PIN is not correlated with volume

35 / 36
PIN Analyses (cont’d)

I Some other observations of PIN:


I PIN is higher in electronic trading markets than in non-anonymous
venues (like floor trading)
I Experiment with German Stock Exchange
I PIN is higher for stocks with less analyst coverage
I well known that spread widens when analysts stop following a stock

I Due to DeFi and blockchain, a new identification method appears;


how will it change?

36 / 36

You might also like