Thanks to visit codestin.com
Credit goes to www.scribd.com

0% found this document useful (0 votes)
133 views33 pages

E Procurement EXAMPLES

The document discusses using designed electronic auctions to improve government procurement processes by addressing two key information problems. Firstly, auctions help discover which firms can supply goods and services at low cost. Secondly, contract incentives can ensure providers do not skimp on quality. Auction theory shows bilateral negotiations often disadvantage the uninformed party (government). The document recommends a systematic designed approach using electronic auctions to incorporate objectives like cost minimization, local content policies, and small business preferences. Well-designed auctions and incentives can improve alignment between government and suppliers while potentially saving 10-30% on procurement costs compared to traditional methods.

Uploaded by

Nathan Dsouza
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
133 views33 pages

E Procurement EXAMPLES

The document discusses using designed electronic auctions to improve government procurement processes by addressing two key information problems. Firstly, auctions help discover which firms can supply goods and services at low cost. Secondly, contract incentives can ensure providers do not skimp on quality. Auction theory shows bilateral negotiations often disadvantage the uninformed party (government). The document recommends a systematic designed approach using electronic auctions to incorporate objectives like cost minimization, local content policies, and small business preferences. Well-designed auctions and incentives can improve alignment between government and suppliers while potentially saving 10-30% on procurement costs compared to traditional methods.

Uploaded by

Nathan Dsouza
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 33

PROCUREMENT

DESIGNED, ELECTRONIC AUCTIONS FOR GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT


1. CONTENTS

1. INTRODUCTION ..................................................................................................................... 7

2. A DESIGNED PROCUREMENT PROCESS .................................................................................. 8

2.1 Selecting the “best” provider – the hidden information problem ................................................................. 8

2.2 Will the good or service be provided? – the hidden action problem ........................................................... 10

2.3 Procurement with Mixed adverse selection and moral hazard problems .................................................... 12

3. STEPS TO DESIGN AND IMPLEMENT PROCUREMENT AUCTIONS.......................................... 13

4. ELECTRONIC PROCUREMENT AUCTIONS .............................................................................. 14

4.1 Benefits from designed electronic procurement auctions ........................................................................... 15

5. IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGY ............................................................................................. 16

6. ATTACHMENT 1: A BRIEF DESCRIPTION OF AUCTION FORMATS .......................................... 20

7. ATTACHMENT 2: EXAMPLES OF DIFFERENT AUCTION FORMATS FOR PROCUREMENT ........ 24

8. ATTACHMENT 3: E-PROCUREMENT PLATFORMS ................................................................. 30

2
The Centre for market Design
The Centre for Market Design (CMD) is an innovative economic research centre hosted by the University of
Melbourne. The CMD was created specifically to build capabilities in research, training and engagement
needed to design and create efficient and effective public policy mechanisms. The CMD has established a
distinguished publication profile in the fields of mechanism design, auction theory, industrial organisation,
matching markets, experimental economics, and empirical economic analysis. We are also defined by our
success in applying economic/market design ideas to create innovative mechanisms needed to achieve public
policy objectives. The CMD has designed and implemented a range of public policy mechanisms including
environmental markets, procurement auctions, auctions of access rights etc. in sectors of the economy
including: extractive industries, the transport, human services, natural resources, the environment,
government procurement, renewable resources, biosecurity and waste sectors. We have deep expertise in
the application of empirical methods to evaluate competitiveness in the fuel and energy sectors, and to
evaluate the effectiveness of demand management programs in the water and electricity sectors. Our
research is extensively used by the ACCC and utilities. The CMD offers a unique engagement platform that
enables interactions and mutually beneficial cooperation between government, industry, and academic
economists. The CMD operates under the guidance of a Board consisting of high-level commonwealth and
state government representatives, business leaders, internationally recognised academics and public policy
experts. Further information about the CMD can be viewed on: https://fbe.unimelb.edu.au/cmd.

3
SUMMARY
The Victorian Government makes some of the goods and services needed to provide public services but
purchases around $5 billion from non-government suppliers. When governments procure goods and services,
they are faced with two important information problems: they must firstly discover which firm can supply
the goods and services needed at low cost; and they must also ensure that the provider of goods and services
does not skimp on inputs (leading to poor quality outcomes). These two problems occur widely in other
domains of the economy because information is decentralised and the incentives of the government (the
principal) differ from the incentives faced by private firms (the agent). Fortunately, there are ways to address,
or partially address, these problems through the application of auction theory and incentive theory that can
improve the efficiency and effectiveness of government procurement processes.

Auction theory provides an understanding of the problems of bargaining and negotiation under asymmetric
information. One of the most important lessons from this area of economic theory is that bilateral bargaining
between a well-informed supplier (firms and organisations they know their costs of production) and a poorly
informed buyer (government does not have information about these costs) is that the uninformed party will
come off second best in negotiated outcomes. In procurement, this translates to the government paying too
much for the goods and services it needs to supply public services. Government’s response to this should be
to firstly avoid bilateral procurement processes by designing procurement auctions in which the price of
goods and services is revealed through competition between suppliers. If well-designed, this strategy will
dissipate excess profit margins that could be earned by service providers. Each procurement auction
represents a unique economic design problem with different objectives (e.g., cost minimisation, efficiency);
different constraints imposed by government (e.g., local content); different characteristics (e.g., single, multi-
units) and a range of complexities (e.g., information, strategic and policy) that together influence the design
of the procurement auction. The use of sealed-bid tenders for all procurement activities is not supported by
auction theory. Procurement auctions need to be designed on a case-by-case basis. To accommodate these
factors, governments will benefit from access to a wide range of auction formats including: sealed-bid, first
price formats; a broad suite of open auction formats where there are common value information structures;
through to highly specialised auction formats capable of dealing with package problems. Furthermore, when
governments require procurement to reflect other government policy objectives, such as local content plans,
preference for small firms, spatial, quality outcomes etc. these objectives will need to be achieved in the
most cost-effective way. Under these circumstances, a systematic, designed approach to procurement will
be needed.

The second important influence on procurement is the incentive structures embodied in the contract for
goods or services required. The role of these incentives is to align the actions of the supplier with the
objectives of government (the buyer). Alignment can be improved by delegating some risk to the provider of
the good or service even though this may increase the price of risk bearing overall. In some procurement
situations, these two problems, referred to as adverse selection and moral hazard) occur simultaneously
creating additional design complexity.

4
Many of the auction formats that governments will want to use cannot be operationalized through paper-
based systems. Open auction formats, for example, rely on information and messaging between participants
in the auction, other auctions, such as combinatorial auctions used to procure packages of goods and
services, need to be supported by algorithms that process information required to facilitate competitive
bidding n the face of allocation complexities. These classes of auction will need to be hosted on web-based
electronic platforms that are accessed through the internet. Besides improved flexibility, with respect to
auction format, electronic auctions have other important benefits. These include:

• improved flexibility and functionality - electronic auctions provide the flexibility needed to host a
wider variety of designed procurement auction formats;
• improved participation - increased participation facilitated through the internet will promote the
achievement of government objectives with respect to procurement;
• mitigation of corrupt behaviour - electronic auctions provide a structural separation between
government representatives and market participants; and
• reduced red tape - electronic auctions can be reused or modified at low cost for repeat or similar
procurement activities and have been demonstrated to significantly reduce the procurement life
cycle.

These advantages have been argued to have improved cost effectiveness in countries that have introduced
web-based procurement auctions. Estimates of the cost savings from designed, auction-based procurement
processes range from 10% savings for commodities to 20-30% cost savings for more complex services.

The following recommendations are made:

1. Designed procurement – An auction design and incentive design phase should be included in all
procurement activities conducted by Victorian Government agencies. The objective of this step in
the procurement process is to identify the specific auction format, rules and processes that achieve
the objectives of Government with respect to procurement and to ensure that the goods and
services supplied by third parties are consistent with government objectives with respect to quality
and quantity. Bilateral negotiation processes should be avoided in favour of designed procurement
auctions that specifically enhance the bargaining position of government relative to the market.

2. Electronic auctions – All procurement activities should be transitioned from paper-based, sealed-
bid tenders to electronic procurement auctions. Electronic platforms allow for a wide range of
procurement auction formats to be run compared with paper-based processes that essentially limit
the auction format to sealed-bid tenders.

3. Internet hosting of all procurement auctions – All procurement auctions should be hosted on the
internet. Advantages include: cost savings from improved design and increased participation;
mitigation against collusion and corruption; and reduced internal red tape.

5
4. Designed incentive structures for procurement contracts- All procurement contracts should be
designed to address the moral hazard problem as well as being legally robust.

5. Staged transition – A staged approach is proposed to implement the reforms to procurement. The
first step will be to develop a general procurement auction platform that enables different auction
formats to be operated. Once this platform has been developed, a library of procurement auctions
can be accumulated. As with all new institutions, it is useful to start with simple problems first. The
fuel procurement auction scheduled for 2015 will represent an ideal pilot for the designed,
electronic procurement auction approach. The procurement auction required for fuel procurement
is relatively simple (sealed-bid, first-price auction format) and an electronic auction platform has
been developed by the CMD. This auction would be hosted on the internet. Following
implementation and evaluation, this auction format would be archived with instructions to
facilitate reuse when the fuel supply contract again matures or when the same auction format is
needed to procure other goods or services. A library of procurement auctions would be developed
over time by designing and creating procurement auctions that are fit-for-purpose to each new
procurement activity. For example, fuel procurement would be followed (May 2015) by
procurement of specialised expertise for medical panels (a Vickery Clarke Groves auction format),
followed by travel services procurement later in 2015 (an auction of incentive contracts has been
proposed), followed by electricity procurement (sealed bid format proposed) in November 2015.

6
1. INTRODUCTION
The public sector is a significant purchaser of goods and services. In the United States the federal government
alone (excluding individual states) procured goods and services valued at over $378 bn. ($1,300 per person).
In 2009, the European Union purchased over €420 billion (3.6 per cent of GDP) and the Australian
Government procured $48.9 billion in the 2013-14 financial year - around $2,100 per person.

Government “makes” some of the goods and services needed to fulfil public policy obligations but also buys
goods and services from the market. The make or buy decision hinges on transaction costs that apply to
vertical integration of functions verses outsourcing of functions. The incidence of incomplete contracting
problems that effectively raise the transaction costs associated with outsourcing effectively defines the
boundary between the public service and the market. Governments typically “make” services where there
are high transaction costs (e.g., producing the annual budget and policy advice) but routinely purchases a
wide range of goods and services from the market such as: electricity, fuel, stationary, travel and
accommodation services etc. Government typically engages with the market to purchase these goods and
services through procurement processes in which there is one buyer (government) and multiple potential
suppliers. More recently there has been interest in extending the role of the market in supplying a broader
range of goods and services through the creation of new institutions tasked with harnessing competition and
facilitating coordination needed to provide more complex goods and services such as freeways, prisons,
foreign aid etc. These initiatives are variously referred to as public private partnerships (PPP), franchising and
commissioning but they are all a form of procurement.

Procurement is typically framed as a principal agent problem in which the government (the principal) aims
to achieve a defined objective but engages a third party, with specialised expertise, to complete the task. The
third party is often (but not always) a private firm with incentives that are not aligned with those of
government. Government publicises its requirements and invites firms, capable of completing the tasks
identified, to register through expressions of interest. Each firm that registers have private information in
that it knows its costs, skills, and expertise but this information is not known to government. None of the
firms in contention has an incentive to truthfully reveal information about the real cost at which the good or
service can be provided because to do so would eat into potential profit margins. Furthermore, once the task
is assigned to a winning firm, it has an incentive to minimise inputs or skimp on quality to improve profits,
but which adversely affects the government service provided.

The standard practice is for government to call for bids from pre-qualified firms through a sealed-bid tender
process. Government then selects the lowest offer from the submitted tender and the winning firm is paid
the price specified in the tender. Most procurement, including complex weapons systems, highways and
government buildings are procured through a sealed-bid, pay as bid tender. In some cases, a tender process
is used to create a short list from which the winner is selected through bilateral negotiation. This is referred
to as a best and final offer process (BAFO).

Where agencies are looking to purchase goods and services that are generally available in the market place,
they may seek to leverage government purchasing power by entering into fixed term contracts with preferred

7
suppliers selected through a competitive tender process. There will also be instances where government is
the sole purchaser of a product or service, or one of only a small number of purchasers – for example, in the
procurement of rolling stock for publicly sponsored train and tram services. In such cases, best value for
money will most likely be achieved through a genuinely competitive procurement process. The concept of
competitive tendering is embedded in the Victorian Government Purchasing Board (VGPB) Procurement
Policies: “Consistent with government procurement policy, the procurement process should optimise effective
competitive tension to maximise value-for-money opportunities for government.” (VGPB 2009, p.49).

2. A DESIGNED PROCUREMENT PROCESS


There are two key problems that must be addressed if procurement is to meet the stated objectives of
government. These are referred to as: a) the hidden information problem (adverse selection), and b) the
hidden action (moral hazard) problem. Hidden information refers to the problem of discovering which firm
can provide the services needed at lowest cost – this information is known by the firm but is hidden from
government. Hidden action refers to the problem that the firm providing the goods and services has an
incentive to minimise costs but information about the actions of suppliers is hidden from government. These
information problems can occur sequentially in which case the hidden information problem needs to be
resolved before the hidden action problem arises. In other ceases these hidden information and hidden
action problems occur simultaneously (referred to as the mixed model) and need to be resolved in a
coordinated way (see Laffont and Martimort 20021). The following sections expand on how these information
problems apply to procurement and way they might be addressed.

2.1 SELECTING THE “BEST” PROVIDER – THE HIDDEN INFORMATION PROBLEM


In the procurement context, adverse selection refers to the problem of identifying and selecting the firm
(provider) that most closely matches the selection criteria that allows government (the purchaser) to meet
its objectives. This usually, but not always, means choosing the firm that can perform the task at lowest cost,
within set time constraints, to a given quality standard etc. Selecting the “best” supplier for the task is
confounded by the problem that government does not have information about the relevant attributes and
costs of private firms. Information (about costs, quality etc.) is confidential to private firms and is hidden
from government. Holt2 frames the procurement in a game theoretic context where the objective of the
buyer (e.g., government) is to define the rules and processes that causes pre-qualified firms to truthfully
reveal their costs of supplying the identified goods and services. This links procurement with the extensive
body of auction theory in which economists seek to design auctions that reveal the information needed to

1
Laffont, J. and Martimort, D (2002), The Theory of Incentives – The Principal-Agent Model, Princeton University Press.
2
Charles A. Holt, Jr. Competitive bidding for contracts under alternative auction procedures. Journal of Political Economy, 88:433–445,

1980.

8
choose which firm is contracted to provide the goods and services required. Procurement is now seen as a
major application of auction theory.

The key message from auction theory is that auction design is not a “one size fits all” process (Klemperer 3).
The type of auction needed for procurement is determined by considering the objectives of procurement
(e.g., cost minimisation, economic efficiency, local content etc.); the characteristics of the goods and services
being procured, the characteristics of the firms; and the nature and severity of complexities (e.g., information
complexities, policy complexities, strategic complexities ….) 4 . At the simplest level, there are two broad
families of auction (open and closed). Open auctions allow bidders to revise their bids according to the
information revealed by other bidders. Closed auctions involve sealed-bid formats where each bidder makes
an offer that cannot be revised. Both open and closed formats can be operated as either ascending price or
descending price auctions (see Table 1). Auctions are further classified according to whether there are: single
unit; multi-unit homogeneous; and multi-unit heterogeneous items and whether the value structures are
independent or interdependent between items. Consideration of these and other complexities influence the
choice of the auction format and the fine-scale rules of a procurement auction. Klemperer provides a more
detailed discussion of the way auctions are designed and the factors that influence their design. Figure 1
illustrates the wide range of auction formats that have been used to allocate access to assets or procurement
contracts. Further details are included in Attachment 1. One important observation from auction theory is
that a first-price, sealed-bid auction (the standard tender) is the appropriate format only under a very specific
set of conditions. Other auction formats, the fine-scale rules within the auction, qualification and settlement
processes, reserve price strategies, activity rules etc., need to be designed according to the characteristics of
the good or service in question, the complexities associated with procurement and the objectives of
procurement. When auction theory has been applied to design procurement processes, a wide range of
different procurement auctions and contract incentives have been developed to accommodate the diversity
inherent in the different goods and services procured. Many organisations (including governments) use a
second-price auction (often referred to as a reverse auction - like eBay) as the standard procurement auction
format (UK, Brazil) with some private firms using very sophisticated combinatorial auctions to procure inputs
to production (Mars, Home Depot). Other procurement auctions include: mechanisms to deal with bid
preferences; bid schedules for different volumes of goods/services; novel incentive structures (e.g.,
encouraging optimal effort through auctions of incentive contrac5); incomplete contracts etc. Chandrashekar
reviews the uptake of designed procurement auctions by Compaq Computer Corp., General Dynamics, Dutch
Railway, General Electric, Sears Logistics, MARS, Home Depot etc.

3
Klemperer, P., What really matters in Auction Design, Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 16, Number 1—Winter 2002—Pages 169–189

4
See Plott for a comprehensive analysis of complexities that need to be taken into account in designing auctions.

5
R. Preston McAfee and John McMillan. Bidding for contracts: A principal-agent analysis. RAND Journal of Economics, 17:326–338, 1986.

9
Table 1: Broad auction classification
Format Open format Closed format

English auction (ascending price) Sealed bid auction (first price)

Auction type
Dutch auction (descending price) Sealed bid auction (second price)

2.2 WILL THE GOOD OR SERVICE BE PROVIDED? – THE HIDDEN ACTION PROBLEM
The second problem to be resolved in procurement arises because the actions of good/service providers is
hidden from the buyer – also referred to as moral hazard. Do they use quality components, pay enough
attention to the objectives of the purchaser, invest enough effort into the research required to provide
advice? It arises because the motives of the agent diverge from those of government, and this becomes a
problem because the government is not able to observe (or it is costly to observe) all of the actions of the
private firm to ensure that the agent supplies what is promised. Under these circumstances, the agent is
motivated to reduce costs, and this can lead to inferior service provision. Moral hazard is addressed by
carefully designing the incentive structures that are embedded in service supply contract.

Economic theory relevant to incentive design (principal-agent theory) essentially highlights the trade-offs
that are made in distributing risk between the principal and the agent. While government might be able to
wear risk at lower cost compared with a small service delivery firm it will often be advantageous to share the
burden of risk because of the incentive advantages of doing so. Although the service provider may need to
raise its supply cost (bid) to reflect the additional cost of risk bearing, to overall cost of supplying services can
be lowered if the devolution of some risk to the agent causes them to more closely align their actions with
the objectives of the government. The contract is the mechanism used to define risk sharing arrangements
between the government and the supplier. A contract that includes payments for inputs assigns all risk to the
government (principal) and a contract that specifies payments for outcomes shifts all risk to the supplier
(agent). Often a contract will specify a mix of input and outcome payments that reflects the “sweet spot”
between the costs of risk bearing and the benefits from alignment of incentives. An incentive contact is a
linear payment schedule where the buyer pays a fixed fee plus a proportion of the contracted cost. It can be
implemented to reduce the risk of moral hazard and correcting the principle-agent problem that creates
implications for the government due to poor behaviour from the supplier (See Weitzman). Table 2 identifies
a range of contract types.

10
Figure 1: Taxonomy of auction formats

Reverse
English
(Ascending)

Open

Clock
Dutch
(Descending)
Single Unit

Anglo-Dutch
First Price Auction
(FPA)
Closed

Second Price Auction


(SPA/Vickrey)

Uniform Price Dependent/Independent

Homogeneous Discriminatory Price Simultaneous/Sequential

Multi-Unit
Vickrey-Clarke-Groves
Combinatorial

Heterogeneous First Price Combinatorial

Combinatorial Clock

11
Table 2. Standard linear contractual structures
Type of Contract Contract Specifications Advantage Disadvantage

Cost-Plus Contract • Pay actual costs plus a • Elicit information on • No direct


(Cost-Plus Fixed fixed dollar fee bidder’s productivity alignment of
Fee) (determined as a levels incentives for cost
percentage of the cost reduction
estimate)

Fixed Price • Contractor agrees to • Every dollar saved • Buyer must


Contract (Firm fulfil the project for a becomes firm’s compensate with
Fixed Price) fixed dollar price profits (creating an a fee, decreasing
(regardless of cost incentive to average normal
overruns) minimize cost to profits
maximize profits)
Cost sharing • Contracted amount is
contract bid price plus (minus)
cost overruns
[production cost
minus bid price]

2.3 PROCUREMENT WITH MIXED ADVERSE SELECTION AND MORAL HAZARD PROBLEMS
In many procurement activities, the government starts by defining the incentive structure in the service
contract. It then offers this contract to the market and uses a designed auction to determine which firm can
provide the good or service at lowest cost. The winner of the auction then produces the good or service and
is rewarded according to the incentive structures in the contract (the moral hazard problem). In some cases,
however, adverse selection and moral hazard need to be resolved simultaneously. The best way to illustrate
this is through an example. To procure travel services the government requires both a transaction services
(i.e., booking airline tickets and accommodation) but may also want the travel agent to invest additional
effort to search for and then purchase lower priced airline tickets and accommodation. This proposal creates
the problem of how to induce the travel firm to invest the optimal level of effort needed to find and secure
lower prices for the Government. Additional effort required to search for savings is costly for the firm. Each
additional dollar invested in searching reduces the firm’s profit so that it has an incentive not to search for
better travel and accommodation deals. It is also difficult (and costly) for government to observe the effort
invested by the agent as the basis of remuneration. In this case adverse selection and moral hazard need to

12
be resolved simultaneously. This is a well-recognised class of problem in economic design literature initially
examined by Laffont and Tirole6 (Tirole is this year’s Noble Prize winner in economics) that can be addressed
by auctioning incentive contracts. The incentive contract component is a way of rewarding the firm for
investing extra effort to find cheaper airline tickets and accommodation for the government. To induce this
extra effort, the government must share the rewards achieved by the travel firm when it secures discounts.
If government does not reward the firm for this effort, the firm will just complete the transactions even if
lower cost options were available. The ideal is to encourage the optimal effort (i.e., where the marginal
benefits of additional effort are just rewarded by the additional returns) in discovering lower airline fares and
accommodation rates. This class of procurement problem is observed in the public sector e.g., where
government engages an agent to invest effort to: assist an unemployed person to find a job; provide legal
advice for citizens on low invome etc.

3. STEPS TO DESIGN AND IMPLEMENT PROCUREMENT AUCTIONS


There are essentially seven steps in designing procurement auction. These are summarised below.

Step Description

1. Clarify and Whilst most procurement processes aim to minimise the cost of inputs purchased from the
define the market, this is not universally the case. A range of other factors may be highlighted in the
objectives of government procurement and incorporated into the procurement process.
objectives
Governments may be interested in influencing market structure to preserve a competitive
and diverse range of suppliers in the market. If possible, these objectives, and weightings
for the different objectives should be stated before the procurement process is designed.
The objectives of a procurement process could include: fairness, efficiency, cost
minimisation, participation, strategic outcomes (i.e., diversity, sector composition).

2. Complexities Identify the complexities that apply to the goods or services required. Complexities arise
from: locational requirements for the goods or services to be provided, timing
requirements, synergies between items needed, where there are economies of scale. These
complexities can be designed into the procurement auction (to varying extents) so that the
procurement process is able to achieve a better outcome than buying from the market.
Different auction formats can be employed to accommodate these complexities.

3. Incentives Apply incentive theory to design the incentive structure in the procurement contract.

4. Auction design Apply auction design theory and experience to identify the auction format needed and the
rules and processes that will reveal the information needed Consider the objectives,

6
Laffont, J.J and Tirole, J (1987) “Auctioning incentive contracts”, The Journal of Political Economy pp. 921-937

13
complexities and incentive issues and design fit-for-purpose auction. The use of a tailored
auction design should remove opportunities for bilateral negotiations between parties and
induce competition.

5. Test-bed Build the auction and test its performance. This may include laboratory sessions.

6. Implementation A designed pre-qualification process is established, the auction is conducted, and contracts
and settlement are awarded to bidder’s dependent on awarding rules set in the auction design phase.

7. Feedback and Complete feedback and evaluation of goods and services supplied.
evaluation

4. ELECTRONIC PROCUREMENT AUCTIONS


Many fit-for-purpose (designed) procurement auctions are difficult, in some cases, impossible to run as
paper-based or open cry forms. Advances in information and communication technologies complement
developments in auction theory by allowing a wide array of fit-for-purpose auctions to be hosted, expanding
participation in auctions and reducing the cost of reusing auctions once they are developed. These
developments have transformed procurement processes for individuals, private firms and government. Sites
such as Alibaba, eBay and gumtree are examples of electronic, designed procurement auctions that allow a
wide range of goods and services to be procured by individuals and private firms through the internet. Where
private firms purchase large volumes of goods and services as part of a production process, it may be
advantageous to develop specialised procurement processes that accommodate the specific attributes of the
good or service in question and the complexities that impeded transactions and to reuse these procurement
auctions at low cost. The Mars Corporation and Home Depot 7 are examples of private firms that have
developed sophisticated electronic procurement auctions that allow these companies to rerun efficient
procurement auctions using electronically hosted auctions. These developments in the private sector also
apply to government procurement where specific goods and services are procured repeatedly and where
there are advantages to using fit-for-purpose procurement auctions that require electronic hosting.
ComprasNET developed by the government of Brazil is an example of an electronic procurement auction
system. It employs a relatively simple auction format for a wide range of goods and services but is reusable
at low cost. The World Bank 8 has an international program to assist developing countries migrate to
electronic platforms and the OECD actively uses designed procurement auctions.

7
Chandrashekar, T.S. Narahari, Y., Rosa, C., Kulkarni, D., Tew, J., Dayama, P. "Auction-based mechanisms for electronic procurement", IEEE Trans.
Autom. Sci. Eng., vol. 4, no. 3, pp.297 -321, 2007

14
4.1 BENEFITS FROM DESIGNED ELECTRONIC PROCUREMENT AUCTIONS
The benefits from a more systematic design and execution of procurement processes arise from four sources:

• Improved procurement auction design - harnessing competition, exploiting synergies etc.


• Improved incentive structures in the service contracts - improved quality of services provided.
• Internet bidding - increased participation, reduced scope for corruption.
• Electronic hosting of auctions - reduced reuse costs, more complex auction formats able to be used.

As a general observation, the potential for cost savings from designed electronic procurement auctions tends
to be lower where the buyer is procuring from an already competitive market (e.g., commodities) and where
collusion or other market power problems are minimal. Benefits will be higher where there are: thin markets,
market inefficiencies such as collusion; transaction complexities; and where there is corruption in
procurement processes. Table 4 provides a summary if the claimed gains from procurement reforms made
by various government agencies.

The cost savings from e-auctions observed in the UK are higher than anticipated given that many of the case
studies noted involve procurement of commodities such as computers, stationery, pharmaceuticals,
communication equipment etc. As noted earlier, we would not expect a procurement process to out-perform
an efficient market as is the assumption for most commodities. For these case studies, the gains are likely to
stem from greater participation through internet bidding and the use of a competitive auction compared
with the standard sealed-bid tender often with a negotiation phase. Nevertheless, the costs savings stated
are higher than expected. The gains identified by Brazil (20-30%) through ComprasNET are also at the high
end of the range of expected gains given that ComprasNET appears to be mostly used to procure standard
goods and services with a standard auction format. The cost reductions achieved are largely derived from
the impact of an electronic platform on collusive behaviour (see Santanna9). Electronic auction platforms
structurally separate the government officer from individual suppliers by embedding auction format, winning
rules and price discovery in computer code that affording a higher level of commitment by government,
independence and transparency than can be achieved through bilateral negotiation processes. Other
examples illustrate the gains from auction design alone. For example, an evaluation of the environmental
procurement auctions conducted by Victoria10 estimate the gains from improved auction design at 30%.

9
Santanna, R. (200# ) Electronic Procurement Allow for Inspection By Society, Global Forum on Governance:

Modernising Government: strategies & tools for change, Rio de Janeiro - Brazil
10
Stoneham, G (2007), Creating markets for environmental goods and services, Land and Water Australia.

15
reduction in environmental procurement costs that are purely derived from auction design. from
procurement auctions that reveal relevant information. An additional advantage form electronic
procurement auctions arises because of savings in internal administration and approval processes. In Brazil,
for example, the procurement cycle has reduced from 117 days to 20 days because electronic auctions can
be reused quickly and at low cost.

5. IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGY
Government procurement practices can be improved by incorporating three capabilities in their
procurement processes:

• economic design - the use of designed, fit-for-purpose, procurement auctions and designed
incentive contracts;
• electronic auctions - creating electronic auctions that enable the use of a broader range of auction
formats and features not available in paper-based or open cry auctions; and
• internet bidding - internet bidding increases participation and can mitigate the possibility of
corruption.

Governments procure a wide range of goods and services from commodities to highly specific human services
for a wide range of clients at different locations. This suggests that a wide range of auction formats will be
needed in response to the characteristics of different goods and services and the information, spatial,
strategic, policy and timing complexities relevant to government. Figure 2 illustrates the sort of procurement
auctions that government might want to use for different circumstances. For example, sealed-bid auctions
might be needed to procure commodities or where collusion is anticipated by bidders; clock auctions might
be used where goods have a common value information structure i.e. a roadway where there is demand
forecasting risk); multi-unit auctions might be used in situations where bidders wish to offer lower prices to
reflect economies of scale with larger orders; multiple clock auctions might be used where several
interrelated goods/services will be needed an there are synergies between goods/services; similarly
combinatorial auctions would be considered where packages of goods/services are needed; and auctions of
incentive contracts might be used where suppliers can invest additional effort that benefits the procurer (e.g.
complex legal services). Although there is an investment required to design, build and test each of these
auction formats, once created, they can be reused at almost zero marginal cost. The procurement auction
capability illustrated in Figure 2 is best developed by building a library of fit-for-purpose procurement
auctions needed for each good or service procured by government. Because the features of each auction
reflect the specific characteristics of each good or service required, a strategy to sequentially develop the
library as existing procurement contracts mature and need renewing will be preferable to building a singly
auction platform for all goods and services.

The A staged approach, summarised in Table 5, is proposed to implement the procurement platform. The
first stage involves designing and building the web-based platform needed to host electronic auctions.
Fortunately, internet hosting of auctions is now commonplace (e.g. eBay, Tradeslot, Intelimarket, Power
Auctions etc.) and very little bespoke design and development is needed to create the platform. The internet
platform must be scalable, reliable and accessible. The Centre for Market Design will coordinate and fund

16
the creation of this platform. Once the internet platform has been developed, a library of procurement
auctions should be developed sequentially. As existing procurement arrangements mature, fit-for-purpose
auctions can be designed and created (stage 2). Once implemented and evaluated (Stage 3) each auction
would be archived with instructions developed to facilitate reuse when the supply contract matures (Stage
4) or adaptation to a new procurement activity.

Figure 2: Schematic representation of a procurement platform


First-price sealed bid , Clock auction Multi-unit auction with Multiple clock auction Second-price auction
single unit supply schedule (example)

Auction of incentive contracts Sequential auction Combinatorial auction Vickrey Clarke Groves auction Open
(example) auction

Web-based platform Internet bidding

Table 5. Stages in implementation

Stage Activity Description and strategy Resources Time

Stage 1 Develop internet Design the platform to be used to host and CMD to fund Jan 2015
auction platform save a library of auction formats needed to and
procure goods and services required by coordinate
government

Stage 2 Design and create fit- The library of procurement auctions will be CMD to
for-purpose developed sequentially as existing design
procurement auction procurement contracts mature. The following auctions
formats as new procurement arrangements are anticipated:
procurements arise
• Medical Panels March 2015
• Fuel (May 2015) May 2015
• Travel services ?
• Electricity Nov. 2015

Stage 3 Implement and Develop software for the fuel procurement CMD and Jan 2015
evaluate each auction Caltech
procurement auction

Stage 4 Archive auction Save and catalogue each new auction format CMD& As
formats and develop an instruction manual to guide Strategic procurement
reuse of the auction Sourcing auctions are
completed

17
Table 4: Summary of international experience with procurement reform

Jurisdiction (good/service) Gain Comments

Brazil (mostly goods and services) 20% to 30% cost reduction (Ref) ComprasNET does not have a strong auction design component but
internet hosting has increased participation and reduced corruption
Procurement life cycle reduced from
117 days to 20 days.

UK

• Merseyside Councils (office supplies) 42% (£3.5 m) e-Auctions plus aggregation across councils
• North Yorkshire Council (mobile phones) 29% e-Auctions
• Department of Constitutional Affairs (court 11.2% (£0.8/annum) Designed procurement auction
reporting services)
• Inland Revenue Department (furniture) Designed procurement auction
23% (£0.9/annum)
• Northampton County Council Designed auction + electronic
49%
(communications services)
• South East and Eastern region Police 50% (£0.48/annum) e-Auction
(stationery)
• Welsh Health Services (medical supplies) 10% (£0.6/3 years) e-Auction
• Portsmouth Hospital (pharmaceutical 12% (£0.64/annum) e-Auction
supplies)
• Coventry Council (office, stationery, 30% (stationery) e-Auction
computers) 18% (computers)

18
Victoria

• Department of Environment (environmental 30%/annum Designed procurement auction + designed contract incentives
service procurement from private
landholders)

US Federal Government

• aircraft ejection seat 28% Designed actions


• goods and services Not reported Designed auctions

US State Governments

• Massachusetts Not reported Increasing use of designed auctions


• Minnesota
• Pennsylvania
• Texas
• Wisconsin

19
6. ATTACHMENT 1: A BRIEF DESCRIPTION OF AUCTION FORMATS
Single unit auctions - Auction theory has commonly focused on single units of goods and services. Recently,
research has shifted this focus to the auctioning of multiple units or multi-unit auctions and adapted single
unit auctions to the multiple unit environment. Accordingly, knowledge of single unit auctions is fundamental
to the understanding of the more complex multi-unit environment. This discussion shall begin with
highlighting the auction mechanism that deal with single units before describing the more complex
auctioning of multiple items.

Auctions mainly differ across two characteristics – information and the final price paid. In particular,
knowledge of bids can be common or private and the winner may pay the highest or second highest price.
Open Auctions: Auctions are said to be open if bidding is common knowledge. An open auction refers to the
action of making an ‘open cry’ bid in which each bidders’ bid is announced and known to all
bidders. The two main types of open auctions are the English and Dutch auction.

English Auction: English Auctions follow an ascending price process such that bidders can only bid up the price.
The bidder who makes the highest and final bid wins the auction and pays the amount of
their bid. This format is commonly used in auctions for real estate.

Dutch Auction: The Dutch auction is a descending price auction where the auctioneer announces the highest
price which they are willing to sell the item for. The price then decreases set decrements until
a bidder announces a bid. At this point, the auction stops and the winner is the first to make
a bid and pays their bid.

Anglo-Dutch Auction: Auctions can also be combined to include a number of designs. The Anglo-Dutch auction is
two-stage auction which combines the English and Dutch auctions. The first stage of the
auction takes the form of an English auction where the arbitrarily chosen group of highest
bidders are invited to participate in the second stage of the auction – the sealed-bid FPA (as
in the Dutch auction, a bidder’s dominant strategy is to bid below their true value in order to
receive a profit).

Clock Auction: Clock auctions are characterised by increasing or decreasing price movements along a
predetermined time schedule. Here, the buyer (seller) announces the highest (lowest) price
they are willing to buy (sell) the item for. This initial price becomes the starting price which
will then decrease(increase) in set decrements (increments). Sellers (buyers) remain an active
participant in the auction if they are willing to sell (buy) at the announced price. The winner
is the final active bidder who sells (buys) at the announced price.

Reverse Auction: The roles within an auction can be reversed such that the buyer becomes the auctioneer
rather than the seller and the auction implements a descending price process as sellers
compete to obtain business. The buyer announces prices to the sellers and those willing to
supply the item at the announced price remain active participants of the auction. The final
remaining seller is willing and able to sell the item to the buyer at the lowest price and pays
this announced price.

20
Closed Auctions: As mentioned above, bids can also be independent and private. This type of auction is known
as a sealed-bid auction and describes the situation where each bidder is restricted to the
knowledge of their own bid. Hence, competitors are uninformed of each other’s bids. Sealed-
bid auctions can be categorised by the price which the winning bidder pays for the item i.e.
the first price or second price.

First Price Auction The first price auction (FPA) can be used for both procuring and supplying items and allocates
the item to the highest or lowest bidder. The winner of this auction pays their bid so that
each bidders’ ‘profit’ from the auction is the difference between their own true value for the
item and the price that they pay for it. Hence, to maximise one’s profit, the dominant strategy
is to bid below the true valuation for the item.

Second Price Auction The second price auction (SPA) differs from the FPA in a significant way – the highest or
lowest bidder wins the auction but only pays the second highest or second lowest bid
submitted. Although it is similar to the FPA in that it can be used for both procuring and
supplying as well as allocating the item to the highest or lowest bidder, the difference in the
rule governing the price paid produces a significant difference in the respective bidding
strategies. In direct contrast to the FPA, bidding one’s true value in the SPA weakly dominates
any other strategy. This is due to the fact that the winning bidder never pays their bid. Hence,
if the winning bidder bids their true value, they will receive the item at the lower price of the
second highest value and gain a profit.

Multi-unit auctions - As with any well-designed process, the design of an auction must fit the type of good
or service which is to be procured or supplied. Traditionally, auctions have facilitated the sale of single units
of a good or service. Recent research has focused on the selling and buying of multiple units. While the
majority of auction theory pertaining to the single unit case can be adapted for the auctioning of more than
one unit, the characteristics in which these units can differ must be accounted for. In particular, the
auctioning of identical or homogeneous units will require a different auction design to the auctioning of
heterogeneous units which can differ across dimensions.
Homogeneous goods Homogeneous units are identical across characteristics. Whist units are identical the various
auctions that can be implemented vary over several dimensions such as the rules concerning
the final price paid and the bidding process. The final price paid by the winner of the auction
will not only depend on which institution is used i.e. English or Sealed-bid FPA, but also on
the pricing mechanism implemented.

Uniform Price Auction This mechanism is used when multiple units of homogeneous goods are auctioned in equivalent,
fixed quantities and allocated to each winning bidder until the allocation is exhausted. Each
winning bidder pays the same price, the market clearing price,
which is set equal to the lowest winning bid. This type of auction is commonly used in
auctions for treasury bills and initial public offerings.

Discriminatory Price Auction - Alternatively, winning bidders can be charged the price of their bid i.e. winning bidders
will pay-as-bid. Winning bidders are allocated the good and pay the amount that they bid
rather than a uniform price. This pricing rule is featured in the Dutch Flower auctions.

Simultaneous Auctions - When multiple units of homogeneous goods are auctioned simultaneously, bids and prices are
either dependent or independent of each other depending on the auction design.

21
Simultaneous-Dependent auctions share the same price rule as Uniform Price auctions and
each bidder makes a single action – submits their preferred allotment and price. Conversely,
Simultaneous-Independent auctions require bidders to submit bids in several simultaneous
auctions and the winners pay-as-bid as in the Discriminatory Price auction.

Sequential Auctions - Multiple units can also be auctioned sequentially i.e., each lot is auctioned one at a time. This
design has been utilised in procurement auctions such as Nitrous Oxide emissions permits by
the State of Virginia and export permits for timber in Siberia.

Heterogeneous goods: Both goods and services can differ in several ways and an individual’s demand for
each good or service will reflect these differences. Accordingly, it is imperative to design an auction to ensure
that a varying demand for heterogeneous goods is captured by the mechanism. Over the past 15 years both
theorists and practitioners have investigated and implemented combinatorial auctions to deal with this
important issue.
Combinatorial auctions - Rather than restricting bidders to bidding on a single unit, a combinatorial auction allows
bidders to bid on a combination or package of units. Bidding takes place in at least two
dimensions – bidding on individual units and bidding on a package of units. Goods are
allocated on the basis of which bid, individual or package, generates the greatest monetary
return. Hence, if a package bid is greater than the sum of the individual bids for each unit,
then the units are sold as a package. While this situation could be misinterpreted as a
motivation for volume discounts, the opposite may actually be true – as more units are
consumed, returns increase rather than diminish. Increasing returns arise from the synergies
or compliments that exist between a combination of units. Combining bids for individual
items allows bidders to reveal their preferences over complements. While combinatorial
auctions are commonly used for auctioning heterogeneous goods, this mechanism can also
be implemented to auction homogeneous goods which are capable of generating synergies.
A number of single unit auctions have been adapted for the combinatorial setting including
the FPA, SPA/Vickrey and Clock auctions.

First Price Combinatorial Auction (FPCA) - Many of the procurement auctions across the world have taken a sealed-bid
FPA form. As in the single unit case, the highest bid is the winning bid and the winner pays
their bid. It is common to include specific rules to ensure that the auction design not only
matches the goods’ characteristics but also the features which characterise its market. For
instance, the design may include a quota to prevent the formation of monopolies and
promote greater competition. The advantages of this design has led to an increase in auction
efficiency for both private and public procurement. Prominent examples include contracting
to supply Chilean schools with breakfast and lunch meals as well as the London Transport
Authority’s auctioning of London bus routes.

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves (VCG - An extension of the SPA to the multi-unit case, the VCG also requires winning bidders to
pay the opportunity cost of their bid i.e. the second highest bid. Under a simple set of
assumptions, bidders’ weakly dominant strategy is to bid their valuations. In a combinatorial
bidding environment, bidding one’s valuation reveals preferences over compliments.
Although the VCG’s dominant strategy is to bid one’s true valuation, the mechanism is rarely
used in the real world as it is highly susceptible to collusion.

22
Combinatorial Clock (CC) - The CC auction extends the single unit Clock auction to allow for package bidding. In a
descending price auction environment, the buyer or procurer announces the highest price
that they are willing to purchase the item. Suppliers who are willing and able to supply the
item at the announced price remain active while unwilling suppliers drop out. The price
decreases in set decrements allowing suppliers a moment to decide whether to remain active
at the announced price. The final active bidder wins the auction and pays the announced
price. The CC auction may be preferred to the single round sealed-bid FPCA depending on
the characteristics of the item and the market which the auctioneer faces. For instance, in
cases when common knowledge is lacking, the CC auction may be preferred due to its ability
to generate of information feedback. Under this mechanism, bidders reveal their preferences
to competitors allowing for greater competition and efficiency from the auction. The amount
of information that is common knowledge can be adjusted to suit the characteristics of the
market. The CC auction has been implemented successfully by a number of private sector
including the auctioning of transport contracts by Sears Logistic Services. The public sector
has also utilised the CC auction in selling digital spectrum licences in Australia and abroad.

23
7. ATTACHMENT 2: EXAMPLES OF DIFFERENT AUCTION FORMATS FOR
PROCUREMENT
A limited survey of procurement auctions reveals that a wide range of auction formats have been used to
procure goods and services (see Tables below). Different auction formats are used to reflect the information
characteristics of the good or services (i.e., independent private values or common values), single- verses
multi-unit objects, concerns about collusion, objective etc. The simplest form of auction design, the “open
first price sealed-bid” has the effect for mitigating potential collusive behaviour between participants in the
auction (see environmental services example in Table A.2.2), by limiting their access of information on bids
submitted by competing bidders. Despite its simplicity, the “open first price sealed-bid” can cause
implications such as a winner’s curse through its “competitive mechanism”. Bidders are unable to observe
the “true” market and other competitors’ bids and are likely to overestimate the value of the good/service
contract being auctioned (see Kagel and Levin). This suggests there is no “one-size fits all” auction format in
designing procurement auctions.

Depending on the complexities, issues and the number of objectives of the government, varying and unique
auction formats should be used - for example, when there is a locational issue in procuring goods and
services. Procurement transactions delivering goods and services cross regions and states within a country
puts less prominent suppliers in disadvantage under a first price sealed-bid approach. Less prominent
supplies are disadvantaged (less market power) relative to suppliers with greater market share who are more
able to reduce transportation costs through economies of scope. The use of combinatorial auctions can
reduce procurement costs by increasing the margins of competition and take advantage of cost synergies
between elements of the set of goods and services needed. This type of auction was used in Chile to procure
meals for school children (see Chilean meals services example in Table A.2.2). Additionally, the use of
combinatorial auctions can improve the economies of scope for suppliers (by reducing transportation costs)
through increasing equipment utilisation and improving efficiency (see Home Depot example in Table 3),
resulting in lower overall costs for the government. Ultimately, combinatorial auctions bring scope for
bidders to express their synergistic values. Again, despite the ability of combinatorial auction format in
addressing complex procurement auctions, it can carry implications. Combinatorial auctions create the
“winner determination problem” and if inappropriately addressed, causes allocative inefficiency problems
(see Rothkopf). Other auction types, such as Vickery Clarke Groves, are being used to procure multiple
heterogeneous units of services in a second price, open auction process. Table also records the use of
innovations in auction design such as the use of bid schedules that allow suppliers to indicate cost discounts
for increased volumes of goods or services procured. Some procurements have employed multi stage
procurement processes to deal with specific complexities and clock auctions as a form of open, second price
auction.

These examples illustrate have been selected to illustrate the important point that auction design should not
involve a “one-size-fits-all” approach (see Klemperer). Instead, a wide range of procurement auctions will be
needed to procure different goods and services.

24
Table A.2.1 Examples of single item single attribute procurement auction
Good/service Auction format Description/Purpose
procured

Pharmaceutical Sealed-bid, first-price


inputs • Ability to leverage demand and supply of inputs

• Create a competitive environment amongst suppliers

• Electronic platforms created an accountable and transparent procurement process

S. Beall, C. Carter, and et. al., “The role of reverse auctions in strategic sourcing: Case Study Glaxo Smith Kline,” Center
for Advanced Purchasing Studies, Temple, AZ, USA, Tech. Rep., 2003.

25
Table A.2.2 Examples of multi-item procurement auctions
Good/service Auction format Description
procured

Environmental Sealed-bid, first-price, • Auction format to reduce collusion and lower the number of bids
services single round • Single round because bidders all have private values (not common values) and multiple rounds would
facilitate information aggregation
• Price minimization
• No reserve price set (no need if there is a budget constraint)
Stoneham et al (2003) Auctions for conservation contracts: an empirical examination of Victoria’s BushTender trial,
The Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 47:4, pp. 477–500

Brazil Descending auctions • Bidders are all pre-qualified (qualifications criteria change overtime and can change from auction to auction
Government • Pre-bidding: Procured goods are grouped in lots (batches), then a reservation price is set (calculated from the
average of three quotes from market research) and an advertisement for tender (with product description) is
(ComprasNET) sent out 8 working days before bidding occurs. All information is free to download anonymously at the time.
• Bidding: All interested bidders submit opening bids (no minimum bids), when auction starts – the lowest bid
is announced and bidders engage in a descending auction. All new bids are strictly lower than their previous
bid. All bids are anonymous. Bids close at random with a 30-minute warning.
• Post Bidding: The best bid is checked whether it is below the reserve price, if it is, documents a submitted to
adjudicate the lot. Otherwise, the second-best bid is checked, etc. It is rare but possible to have a winning bid
higher than the reserve price.
• Increase in speed of transactions
• Improved transparency in government procurement
• Reduced collusive behavior among market participants and the government
Motor car parts Online • Purpose to improve purchase productivity, not cost reduction
supply auctions/negotiations • Reduce complexity in process
• Improve market transparency
• Ability to act on worldwide basis
S. Beall, C. Carter, and et. al., “The role of reverse auctions in strategic sourcing: Case Study Volkswagen,” Center
for Advanced Purchasing Studies, Temple, AZ, USA, Tech. Rep., 2003.

26
Medical expertise Sealed-bid, Vickrey- Medical experts bid to supply expert advice on medical panels for Medical Panels Victoria. A VCG auction is used to
Clarke-Groves, second- lead to truthful revelation of wage rates for individual doctors.
price auction

Home depot Multi-item • Provide flexibility in transportation bidding;


combinatorial auction • Provide information to bidders about the demand for various transportation lanes
• Economies of scope for transporters
• Pre-screening of bidders for quality filtering
• Allow bidders to bid for lanes in groups
W. Elmaghraby and P. Keskinocak, “Technology for transportation bidding at the home depot,” Teaching Case,
School of Industrial and Systems Engineering Georgia Institute of Technology, Tech. Rep., 2003

Transport • This is more of a summary paper of a number of Combinatorial auctions and does not provide great detail of
services each auction – Colgate-Palmolive, Compaq, Ford, Home Depot
Y. Sheffi, “Combinatorial auctions in the procurement of transportation services,” Interfaces, vol. 34, pp. 245–252,
2004.

Sears Logistics Multi-round sealed-bid • Contract carriers to supply transport services to a number of lanes
Services (SLS) - FPCA • Firms submit sealed-bids and lowest bid becomes benchmark for following round and is subsequently bid
transport down
services • Firms bid on multiple lanes and the minimum amount they require to service these lanes
• SLS saved US$25m or 13% in costs
• Original Combinatorial Auction for transportation services

J. Ledyard, M. Olson, D. Porter, J. Swanson, D Torma, ‘The First Use of a Combined-Value Auction for Transportation
Services’ Interfaces, vol. 32, no. 5, pp. 4–12, 2002.

Chile Single-round first-price • Meal services are standardised such that firms only compete in prices
Government – sealed-bid • Firms are allowed to submit multiple bids
combinatorial auction • Meal services standardised but packaged according to territorial units/areas in Chile

27
• Two types of discounts: 1) package discounts (depending on size of package), 2) density discounts (for
packaging nearby units)

Meals for schools • By conducting packaged bidding, allowed firms to express their cost synergies
(Olivares, 2012) R. Epstein, L. Henriquez, J. Catalan, G. Weintraub, and C. Martinez, “A combinatorial auction improves school meals
in Chile,” Interfaces, vol. 32, no. 6, pp. 1–14, 2002

MARS Auction with volume • Increase the number of potential participants (bidders) and stimulating competition
discount – bidding • Allow bidders to learn from information (bids from others) to ‘correct’ their bids
through a supply • Elicit bids incrementally so bidders do not need to specify all is preferences
schedule • Provide discounts on certain ‘bundles’ of supplies
G. Hohner, J. Rich, E. Ng, G. Reid, A. J. Davenport, J. R. Kalagnanam, S. H. Lee, and C. An, “Combinatorial and quantity
discount pro curement auctions provide benefits to Mars, Incorporated and to its suppliers,” Interfaces, vol. 33, no.
1, pp. 23–35, 2003.

London Regional First-price • Pre-auction design: Defining ‘low frequency’ routes and distinguishing between night and day routes
Transport (The combinatorial auction • Packaging and sequencing decisions: to share fixed costs and coordinate efficiencies
London Bus • Pre-qualification: Screens for financial stability and operational capacity of potential operators
Route) • Each bid is a firm but non-exclusive commitment of resources, where two bids on different routes implicitly
define a bid for the package of these routes
• Contracts are awarded to bids with the highest economic value (lowest bid and operator quality)
E. Cantillon, & M. Pesendorfer, “Combination Bidding in Multi-Unit Auctions," CEPR Discussion Papers 6083, C.E.P.R.
Discussion Papers, 2007.

Brazil Hybrid mechanism with • Stage One: Initiated at high price then and decrease until supply is met to discover a price ceiling. Suppliers
(Renewable two stages: 1) who are willing to offer goods at this price continues to Stage Two
Energy – Wind descending price clock • Stage Two: All remaining bidders remaining places a sealed bid for the supply of the goods to meet demand,
Technology) auction; 2) pay-as-bid and the bid must be less than or equal to the price ceiling set in Stage One
sealed bid auction • Deposit bid-bond of 1 per cent of project cost declared by the investor and regulator (guarantee is returned if
contract is won and signed)
• Auction winners must deposit a project completion guarantee of 5 per cent of investment costs
• Requirement of 60% local content in each contract
E. Rego and V. Parente, ‘Brazilian experience in electricity auctions: Comparing outcomes from new and old energy
auctions as well as the application of the hybrid Anglo-Dutch design,’ Energy Policy, vol. 55, pp 511-520, 2013

28
29
8. ATTACHMENT 3: E-PROCUREMENT PLATFORMS
e-procurement is now a well-developed tool which has been implemented across the world in both the
private and public sector. As such, there are a number of e-procurement software providers and a great deal
of differentiation in the type of auction that each firm specialises in. This follows from the aforementioned
importance placed on fit-for-purpose auctions and ensuring that each auction is specifically tailored to meet
the characteristics of its market. While supply chain software developers have collaborated with logistic
service firms to develop combinatorial auctions other software developers have focused on improving the
user experience within a simpler reverse auction environment. Broadly speaking, e-procurement systems
generally include the following components:

• Definition of the good or service needed


• Approval of funds
• Contract
• Tender
• Bidding and negotiation
• Settlement
• Supply
• Evaluation
• Control

When selecting the most suitable e-procurement platform the potential suppliers experience with this
software should play a role in the decision-making process. In the case of complex auction design like the
combinatorial auction, firms and government can limit learning costs by using a recognised and reliable
software platform. Additionally, increasing the ease of which firms are able to access the auction should be
of concern. For instance, if suppliers are able to access the auction through their web browser rather than
download and install an additional software package will facilitate a more streamlined approach. A list of
providers and a short description of their capabilities is listed in Table below.

30
Table A.3.1 E-procurement platforms.
Name of e-procurement platform E-procurement Platform

EPIQ • Provider of procurement solutions for enterprise and mid-sized customers


• Epiq offers auction software that allows businesses to create their own auction events.
• Dutch auctions, English auctions, second price auctions
• http://www.epiqtech.com/auction_software.htm

Sensible Development • Combinatorial auctions, multi-unit auctions


http://www.sensibledevelopment.com/product-range/auction-features/advanced-auction-system-
features/

Auction Flex • Catalogued live auctions, non-catalogued live auctions, internet-only (timed) auctions, live auctions with
webcast, and multi-parcel live auctions
http://www.auctionflex.com/live_auction_software.htm

Purchasing auctions • Reverse auctions


http://purchasingauctions.com/

Procureport • Reverse auctions, forward auctions, Dutch auctions, sealed-bid auctions


• Develop custom auction software
http://www.procureport.com/reverse-auctions.html

Buynamics • Reverse auctions


http://en.buynamics.eu/e-auction/

JDA Software • Combinatorial auctions


• Supply Chain e-auctions

31
• Acquired i2 Tech (Home Depot) and Manugestics Inc.
http://www.jda.com/view/scm-brochure/jda-logistics-procurement/

Manhattan Associates • Transportation procurement solutions


• Possibly acquired Logistics.com (Walmart, Compaq, Staples)
http://www.manh.com/solutions/transportation-management/transportation-procurement

Other possible platforms:ariba - http://www.ariba.com/solutions/buy/procurement-solutions,


perfect commerce - http://www.perfect.com/services/bpo/,
AT Kearney - http://www.atkearneypas.com/,
Moai Technologies - http://www.moai.com/solutions/solutions_overview.asp,
orbis online - http://www.orbisonline.com/solutions.asp,
NSW Procure point - https://www.procurepoint.nsw.gov.au/,
WebBidder by DotEcon - http://www.dotecon.com/expertise/auction-software/,
CRAB - https://swing.fit.cvut.cz/vranyj1/software/crab?_s=AFYI2Ar74MPfWawR&_k=IqyFFxDedY0K3Jfy&_n&10,
eFractal - http://www.e-fractal.cz/en/Page/SpectrumAuctions.aspx,
tradeslot - http://www.tradeslot.com/combinatorial-auctions/,
Power Auctions - https://www.powerauctions.com/

32
Repo

Centre for Market Design

The University of Melbourne

Level 4, 111 Barry Street

Carlton Victoria 3010

You might also like