Trade and Aid
Trade and Aid
positive impact of growth, whereas the opposite is expected for the inflation rate and
conflict intensity.
For Sino-African trade flows, we use two different sets of variables. Firstly, we employ
total African exports to (and imports from) China and control for respective African trade
with the rest of the world (ROW). These variables are meant to capture the effects of
total
African trade with China, though we distinguish between imports and exports, which can
have different effects. Secondly, we differentiate between natural resource exports and
imports, and non-resource exports and imports. Due to the importance of natural
resources in Sino-African trade, we are interested in the effects of trade in different
commodities. Natural resource exports comprise, among others, fuel, various mineral
products, and non-ferrous metals.6 We normalised all trade variables by the GDP of the
respective African country.
For foreign investment, we again differentiate between Chinese FDI and FDI from the
ROW to African countries, both normalized by the host country’s GDP. Chinese outward
FDI data at the country-level is available from 1991. There are two sets of Chinese FDI
data: (1) Chinese Approved Overseas Investment data for 1991-2005, and (2) Chinese
Outward FDI data reported in IMF-OECD format since 2003.7 We combine the two sets
of data by using the first set for the years 1991-2002 and the second set for the years
2003-2011. Even though the data in the two datasets could differ at a country level, the
deviations are fairly small. This allows us to exploit a longer time series since 1991. To
include as many observations as possible, we fill missing values with zero assuming
that
there was no FDI in that case (and add one before taking the log).8 To control for FDI
from the ROW, we subtract Chinese FDI flows from total FDI flows to African countries.
Finally, we test for the effects of Chinese economic cooperation projects in African
countries, again, normalized by the respective country’s GDP. Data is taken from
various
issues of the China Statistical Yearbook published by China’s National Bureau of
Statistics. Following Biggeri and Sanfilippo (2009) and Sanfilippo (2010), we use data
on
economic cooperation as a proxy for Chinese aid due to the lack of other official data.
Although there have been Chinese economic cooperation projects in Africa for several
decades, country-level data on economic cooperation has only been published since
1998.
In order to keep the time frame of our analysis as long as possible, we computed data
at a
country level for 1991-1997. More specifically, we assume that the country breakdown
of
China’s total economic cooperation before 1998 is similar to that in the period 1998-
2001. As China’s economic cooperation projects started soaring after the Going Global
Policy in 2001, we find it reasonable to assume that in the years before 2002 the level of
economic cooperation in Africa as compared to the ROW was more or less constant.
Importantly, this procedure does not affect the main results reported below. If we
exclude
the years before 1998, the results do not change much in terms of the sign and
6 See Appendix A for an exact definition of natural resource trade and all other
variables as well as data
sources. Descriptive statistics are displayed in Appendix B.
7 For a discussion of China‘s FDI data, see Cheung et al. (2012).
8 We inserted a zero in 47 out of 151 observations. While excluding the zero
observations does not affect
the results reported below, it would reduce the sample significantly.
11
significance of the main variables of interest. Besides China’s economic cooperation,
we
control for foreign aid received by African countries from the ROW.
The period under consideration is restricted by the availability of Chinese investment
and
economic cooperation data, that is, we have data from 1991 to 2011. To control for
business cycle effects, we compute five-year averages for all variables, which results to
four observations for the period 1991 to 2010. For the lagged dependent variable, we
also
use information for the previous period 1986 to 1990. In further regressions, we use
four-year averages (five observations for 1991 to 2010) and three-year averages (seven
observations for 1991 to 2011). The sample consists of 43 sub-Saharan African
countries,
that is, all 48 countries in that region apart from Liberia, Sao Tome and Principe,
Seychelles, Somalia, and South Sudan. Whereas trade figures for Liberia are highly
distorted, the last four had to be excluded due to missing data for key variables such as
GDP per capita or investment, or simply did not exist as a country for the larger part of
the period under consideration. In extensions and robustness checks, we both enlarge
the
sample by including North African countries and reduce the sample by excluding sub-
Saharan African islands.9
In terms of the methodology, we use a standard OLS fixed-effects model. This approach
allows a robust estimation of the various linkages and ensures to control for unobserved
time-invariant country fixed-effects. In a dynamic fixed-effects model, it is well known
that the inclusion of the lagged dependent variable can lead to biased estimates
(Nickell,
1981). This bias mainly affects the lagged income per capita variable, which is not the
variable of principle interest in our paper. Still, the size of the impact of the various
trade,
FDI and aid variables of main interest could be affected, for example, by using the
lagged
dependent variable to calculate the long-run effects. More worryingly, there might be
another bias due to the endogeneity of some of the explanatory variables. Depending
on
the partner country or product type, trade, FDI and aid are likely to be endogenous with
respect to economic growth. To mitigate both concerns, we also use the system
Generalized Methods of Moments (GMM) estimator, introduced by Arellano and Bover
(1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998).
9 See Appendix C for the country sample.
12
4 MAIN RESULTS
We begin by reporting fixed-effects regressions using five-year averages in Table 1.
Column 1 presents our baseline specification including only the basic Solow model
variables. The results are predominantly in line with the theoretical model predictions
suggesting that the Solow model fits well for the employed African economies’ dataset.
The lagged dependent variable has a positive and highly significant coefficient of 0.868.
Our estimate is close to other findings of Solow growth regressions where African
countries are explicitly included, for example, Hoeffler (2002). 10 As expected, the
investment variable is positive and highly significant. Contrary to the theory, the
estimate
for population growth is positive, albeit, not significant and relatively small in size.
Finally, regarding the within R-squared (which is at 0.75), we find that the regressors
explain a high portion of the within country variation in GDP per capita growth –
meaning that the model fits relatively well.
10 In order to assess the effect of the lagged GDP per capita variable on GDP per
capita growth, we have
to correct the estimated coefficient by subtracting 1 and obtain -0.132. In a
corresponding fixed-effects
regression, Hoeffler (2002, p. 147) finds a coefficient which is equal to -0.230. The
difference in
magnitude is likely to be due to the fact that her study includes 85 developing countries
including also
a set of non-African countries.
13
Table 1: Baseline Regressions (Fixed Effects)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Lagged Dep. Var. 0.868***
(16.34)
0.747***
(9.495)
0.735***
(10.54)
0.756***
(11.09)
0.755***
(10.69)
0.785***
(11.51)
ln Investment 0.150***
(3.239)
0.170***
(3.235)
0.150**
(2.613)
0.135**
(2.473)
0.173***
(3.249)
0.159***
(3.243)
ln Population Growth 0.056
(0.842)
0.044
(0.477)
-0.052
(-0.619)
-0.101
(-1.158)
-0.051
(-0.622)
-0.074
(-0.847)
Terms-of-Trade Growth 0.205**
(2.361)
0.208**
(2.257)
0.176**
(2.322)
0.233**
(2.588)
0.295***
(2.935)
ln FDI China 0.0017
(0.428)
0.0016
(0.363)
0.0014
(0.285)
0.0010
(0.268)
0.0019
(0.541)
ln FDI ROW 0.0001
(0.00841)
-0.005
(-0.326)
-0.0103
(-0.554)
-0.0040
(-0.271)
0.0020
(0.131)
ln Aid China -0.0254
(-0.803)
-0.0329
(-1.179)
-0.0269
(-0.875)
-0.0278
(-1.141)
-0.0175
(-0.705)
ln Aid ROW -0.0689
(-1.574)
-0.0572
(-1.291)
-0.0703
(-1.243)
-0.0446
(-1.190)
-0.0437
(-1.127)
ln Total Exports to China 0.0170
(1.476)
0.0171
(1.483)
0.0115
(1.243)
ln Total Imports from
China
-0.0751**
(-2.376)
-0.0707**
(-2.186)
-0.0674**
(-2.311)
ln Total Exports to ROW 0.102***
(3.013)
0.0908**
(2.180)
0.0658*
(2.009)
ln Total Imports from
ROW
-0.0091
(-0.217)
-0.0116
(-0.260)
0.0081
(0.197)
ln Inflation -0.0018
(-0.0870)
-0.0077
(-0.341)
0.0034
(0.191)
0.0018
(0.0981)
ln Battle Deaths -0.0043
(-1.135)
-0.0037
(-0.828)
-0.00353
(-1.111)
-0.0027
(-0.845)
Terms-of-Trade Growth*
ln Total Exp. to China
0.0627***
(3.526)
ln Non-resource Exports
to China
0.0061
(0.785)
0.0072
(1.204)
ln Non-resource Imports
from China
-0.0612**
(-2.616)
-0.0547**
(-2.407)
ln Resource Exports to
China
0.0051
(0.658)
0.0025
(0.404)
ln Resource Imports
from China
0.00061
(0.0478)
-0.0091
(-0.723)
ln Non-resource Exports
to ROW
-0.0167
(-0.552)
-0.0192
(-0.652)
ln Non-resource Imports
from ROW
0.0498
(0.777)
0.0375
(0.718)
ln Resource Exports to
ROW
0.0082
(0.526)
0.0090
(0.537)
ln Resource Imports
from ROW
-0.0322
(-1.464)
-0.0166
(-0.761)
Terms-of-Trade Growth*
ln Res. Exp. to China
0.0557***
(3.000)
Observations 169 151 147 147 147 147
Countries 43 43 43 43 43 43
R-squared (within) 0.75 0.85 0.85 0.84 0.87 0.87
Notes: The dependent variable is always ln GDP per capita. All regressions include
period-specific dummies. t-values
obtained from robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at the 10% level; **
significant at the 5% level; ***
significant at the 1% level.
14
In the next step, we extend our model by including the variables of principle interest in
Column 2. Namely, the specification includes the terms-of-trade growth rate of African
countries, FDI flows from China and the ROW, the presence of Chinese economic
cooperation projects, aid flows from the ROW as well as total imports from and total
exports to China and the ROW, respectively. By including these additional variables, we
lose 18 observations due to missing data for these measures. Nevertheless, the data
loss is
marginal, the sign and significance levels of the main controls do not change much and
the model fit increases to 0.85 for the within R-squared.
Both estimates for FDI have a positive sign while those for foreign aid from the ROW
and
Chinese economic cooperation have a negative sign. Yet all four coefficients are
insignificant indicating that these factors do not play a big role in explaining the within
variation of African countries growth rates. Turning towards the trade measures, we find
effects that matter for economic growth. While the coefficient of Africa’s total exports to
China is positive but insignificant, total imports from China have a significant and
negative impact on growth rates. At the same time, we analyse the trade relations with
the
ROW. The effects are somehow contrary to those with China. Again, the exports’
estimate
has a positive sign and the imports’ coefficient has a negative sign, but the statistical
significance has changed. Total African exports to the ROW are significant whereas
total
imports from the ROW are insignificant indicating that exports to the ROW might foster
economic growth in Africa. For the moment, however, these results should be treated as
correlations rather than causations.
In Column 3 we include further variables to control for macroeconomic distortions as
well as for the occurrence and intensity of conflicts. The estimates of the two measures
enter with the expected negative sign in our specification, but they are statistically
insignificant. Most notably regarding this regression, the outcome for the other
estimates
– in particular those for our variables of principle interest – are not affected by including
the inflation rate and the number of battle deaths although we lose four further
observations.
Finding evidence for potential growth effects related to our trade measures, we next
differentiate between resource and non-resource trade (Column 4). We replace the four
total trade variables by eight disaggregated imports/exports variables for resource and
non-resource trade. Only one of the eight coefficients is statistically significant indicating
a correlation with economic growth, that is, non-resource imports from China which has
a negative sign. The negative correlation between total imports from China and
economic
growth across Africa, as shown in Columns 2 and 3, seems to arise from imports in non-
resource sectors. Given the dominance of non-resource goods in total imports from
China (97 percent in 2012), this result is hardly surprising. Still it points to potential
displacement effects of African firms by their Chinese competitors. Though the findings
in Columns 2 and 3 indicate a significant positive effect of total exports to the ROW, the
disaggregated results for resource and non-resource exports to the ROW are not
significant.
The terms-of-trade growth’s estimate is positive and significant at the five percent level
(or better), indicating that African exporters of natural resources have benefited from
higher world market prices for their export products. This outcome is in line with the
results of Zafar (2007) who showed that demand from China has contributed
15
considerably to the increase in prices of raw materials, particularly for oil and metals
from
Africa, which then led to an increase in the terms-of-trade. This result is supported by
Farooki and Kaplinsky (2013), who also analysed the (positive) impact of China on
various
commodity prices. At the same time, the improvements in the terms-of-trade of African
countries could also arise from lower import prices, for example, from low-cost Chinese
manufactured goods, as imports of these goods increased significantly over the last 15
years. What matters is the positive correlation of changes in the terms-of-trade and
economic growth in African countries.11
To analyse the terms-of-trade effects in more detail, we computed interaction terms,
that
is, we multiply changes in the terms-of-trade with all respective trade variables, to
examine non-linear effects. While most interaction terms, whether at an aggregated or
disaggregated level are not significant, two exceptions stand out: the interaction terms
with total exports to China and resource exports to China, respectively, which are
positive
and highly significant at the one percent level (Columns 5 and 6). This outcome is
robust
to including all respective interaction terms at the same time (not reported) and
indicates
that exporting natural resources to China indeed is associated with higher growth rates.
But this result shows up either directly through changes in the terms-of-trade or
indirectly
through the interaction term.12
Next, we replicate all six specifications using system GMM regressions in order to
address
endogeneity concerns (and the bias due to the inclusion of the lagged dependent
variable). In these regressions we treat the lagged dependent variable, investment,
population growth, inflation, all four total import and export variables, all non-resource
import and export variables, as well as FDI and aid from the ROW as endogenous. To
reduce the number of endogenous variables (and thus the number of instruments used),
we set changes in the terms-of-trade, battle deaths, and all natural resource export
variables as exogenous. We assume that African countries are too small to have an
impact
on world market prices (that is, their terms-of-trade) and that conflicts mainly have an
impact on economic growth but not vice versa. Yet switching the status of both variables
from exogenous to endogenous hardly affects the results. Natural resource exports are
mainly driven by the fact whether a country has natural resource endowments or not.
Reverse causality is less of an issue in this case. Again, the main results are not
affected
by declaring all trade variables as endogenous.13 We also treat Chinese aid and FDI to
Africa as exogenous. As pointed out by Kolstad and Wiig (2011), Chinese FDI to Africa
is
not attracted by GDP as soon as South Africa is excluded from the sample.
Predominately, Chinese FDI (and aid) is concentrated in African countries with large
resource endowments, which is exogenous.
Using a large number of instruments may overfit endogenous variables and may
weaken
the Hansen J-test of the instruments’ joint validity. To keep the number of instruments at
a minimum, we use the collapse option in STATA in all regressions. This ensures that
11 A comprehensive analysis of the impact of Chinese demand for raw materials on
African terms-of-
trade is beyond the scope of this paper, as we focus on the growth effects.
12 Columns 5 and 6 are our preferred model specifications. As they include all controls,
the various
aggregated and disaggregated trade variables and the two interaction terms.
13 All non-reported results can be obtained from the authors upon request.
16
the number of instruments is always well below the number of countries. Overall, the
results, reported in Table 2, are broadly in line with the fixed-effects results. The lagged
dependent variable is always significant at the one percent level. Depending on the
model
specification, the estimated coefficient is slightly above or below one, implying no strong
evidence for convergence in sub-Saharan African countries. This finding is in line with
the results of McCoskey (2002), who also found no convergence for economic growth in
sub-Saharan Africa, although smaller “convergence clubs” do exist.
In five out of six model specifications, investment has a positive and significant impact
on
economic growth. In contrast to the fixed effects results, total African exports to the
ROW
are not significant. Importantly, total imports from China and non-resource imports from
China have – as before – a negative and significant impact on growth. This implies that
we do observe displacement effects of African products by Chinese imports, even if we
control for endogeneity. While changes in the terms-of-trade are no longer positively
associated with growth (apart from one model specification), both interaction terms with
terms-of-trade growth are positive and significant at the five or ten percent level. This
result underlines the importance of changes in the terms-of-trade with respect to
economic growth when looking at African exports of natural resources to China.
17
Table 2: System GMM
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Lagged Dep. Var. 1.060***
(18.22)
1.015***
(13.18)
0.964***
(12.01)
0.988***
(6.657)
0.960***
(11.27)
0.955***
(5.838)
ln Investment 0.313***
(3.048)
0.101
(0.841)
0.236**
(1.995)
0.230**
(2.412)
0.268***
(3.563)
0.217**
(2.440)
ln Population Growth 0.148
(0.876)
-0.129
(-1.070)
0.010
(0.0738)
0.022
(0.0915)
-0.032
(-0.256)
-0.095
(-0.534)
Terms-of-Trade Growth 0.089
(1.039)
0.050
(0.635)
0.018
(0.144)
0.151*
(1.691)
0.124
(1.064)
ln FDI China 0.0603
(1.172)
0.0347
(0.716)
0.0009
(0.0264)
0.0134
(0.425)
0.0144
(0.402)
ln FDI ROW -0.0508
(-0.783)
-0.0682
(-1.430)
-0.0872
(-0.957)
-0.0666
(-1.099)
-0.0636
(-0.618)
ln Aid China 0.0086
(0.904)
-0.0004
(-0.0250)
0.0020
(0.297)
0.0030
(0.289)
0.0037
(0.427)
ln Aid ROW 0.0361
(1.569)
0.0255
(1.614)
0.0330
(1.157)
0.0047
(0.301)
0.0222
(1.063)
ln Total Exports to China 0.0123
(0.719)
0.0069
(0.601)
-0.0005
(-0.0389)
ln Total Imports from
China
-0.162**
(-2.323)
-0.102*
(-1.745)
-0.0315
(-0.557)
ln Total Exports to ROW -0.0677
(-0.718)
0.0163
(0.209)
-0.0372
(-0.460)
ln Total Imports from
ROW
0.119
(1.553)
0.0467
(0.698)
-0.0087
(-0.158)
ln Inflation -0.0125
(-0.379)
-0.0243
(-0.700)
-0.0009
(-0.0280)
-0.0463
(-1.386)
ln Battle Deaths -0.0037
(-0.586)
0.0035
(0.252)
-0.0071
(-0.978)
-0.0015
(-0.0971)
Terms-of-Trade Growth*
ln Total Exp. to China
0.111**
(2.119)
ln Non-resource Exports
to China
0.0101
(0.285)
-0.0081
(-0.215)
ln Non-resource Imports
from China
-0.130**
(-2.019)
-0.0937*
(-1.723)
ln Resource Exports to
China
0.0020
(0.0964)
0.0074
(0.316)
ln Resource Imports
from China
0.0145
(0.620)
0.0066
(0.286)
ln Non-resource Exports
to ROW
-0.0120
(-0.195)
-0.0171
(-0.273)
ln Non-resource Imports
from ROW
0.173
(1.140)
0.147
(1.223)
ln Resource Exports to
ROW
0.0020
(0.0889)
-0.0083
(-0.302)
ln Resource Imports
from ROW
-0.0323
(-0.729)
-0.0293
(-0.595)
Terms-of-Trade Growth*
ln Res. Exp. to China
0.0383*
(1.814)
Observations 169 151 147 147 147 147
Countries 43 43 43 43 43 43
Instruments 8 21 24 24 26 24
AR (1), p-value 0.09 0.21 0.11 0.12 0.01 0.09
AR (2), p-value 0.29 0.41 0.40 0.41 0.40 0.41
Hansen J-test, p-value 0.21 0.68 0.39 0.58 0.39 0.68
Notes: The p-values reported for AR(1) and AR(2) refer to first- and second-order
autocorrelated disturbances in the
first differences equations. See Table 1 for further notes.
18
The test statistics for the system GMM estimator (Hansen J-test) indicate that the
instruments used are valid. However, we do have econometric problems regarding
autocorrelation. The system GMM estimator requires high first-order but no second-
order
autocorrelation. While the p-values for the AR(2) indicate that, indeed, we do not have
second-order autocorrelation, the corresponding p-values for the AR(1) show that we
cannot reject the null hypothesis, in three out of six model specifications, though the p-
values are only slightly above 0.10 in two model specifications. These results thus have
to
be viewed with caution. Still, all test statistics for our preferred model specifications
(Columns 5 and 6) indicate that the estimations are valid.
By using the system GMM technique, we can calculate the size of the impact of our
variables of principal interest on economic growth. For example, an increase in the
volume of non-resource imports from China divided by total GDP (Table 2, Column 6)
by
one percent is associated with a decrease in GDP per capita growth of 0.1 percent over
a
period of five years across countries. The quantitative effect of importing more non-
resource goods from China on economic growth is thus modest but by no means
negligible.
Our results for a negative impact of non-resource imports from China are at odds with
those reported by Baliamoune-Lutz (2011) who found a positive impact of imports from
China on African growth. We believe that this can be partly explained by the fact that
Baliamoune-Lutz (2011) does not distinguish between resource and non-resource
goods.
At the same time we use a longer period of time (1991-2010 instead of 1995-2008) and
a
different methodology. On the other hand, our results for displacement effects are more
in line with those of Giovannetti and Sanfilippo (2009). Yet they concentrate on
displacement effects for African exports in third markets but do not investigate these
effects in African countries’ domestic markets.
For the growth effects of foreign investment, we cannot confirm the positive effects
found
by Whalley and Weisbrod (2012). Again, this can be explained by the different
methodologies employed. Since they use Solow growth accounting methods to analyse
the impact of Chinese FDI on African economic growth, they are more likely to
investigate (and find evidence for) the short-run growth impact of Chinese investment.
Also, their methodology allows them to account for the impact of even relatively small
changes in FDI and its impact on economic growth
https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/183560/1/wp-206.pdf
1. titute
2. Publications
3. Media Information
News
REGIONAL
ECONOMIC
OUTLOOK
ANALYTICAL NOTES
2023
OCT
Hany Abdel-Latif, Michele Fornino, Henry Rawlings, under the guidance of Wenjie Chen
(AFR).1
DISCLAIMER: The IMF Analytical Notes aim to quickly disseminate succinct IMF
analysis on critical economic
issues to member countries and the broader policy community. The views expressed in
IMF Analytical Notes are
those of the author(s), although they do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF,
or its Executive Board, or
its management.
Keywords: China, Trade, Debt, Foreign Direct Investment, Spillovers, Trade Integration
(REO) Analytical Notes were prepared by the African Department, Regional Studies
Division staff, under the
At risk is
Sub-Saharan Africa has forged broadly beneficial economic ties with China over the last
two decades.
China has become the region’s largest trading partner, a major credit provider, and a
significant source of
foreign direct investment (FDI). However, China’s support to Africa has also faced some
criticisms. Recently,
China has retrenched its financing activities in sub-Saharan Africa amid a growth
slowdown and reduced
risk appetite. The projected future deceleration in China’s growth is likely to affect
African trading partners
negatively over the medium term, mainly through reduced trade. Therefore, it is crucial
that countries in
the region strengthen their resilience and implement structural reforms to foster
economic diversification,
China has emerged as sub-Saharan Africa’s largest individual country trading partner in
the last 20 years. Today,
one-fifth of the region’s total goods exports go to China (Figure 1, panels 1 and 2).
Metals, mineral products,
and fuel represent about three fifths of the region’s exports to China. Meanwhile, China
has also emerged as the
single largest source of imports for African countries, supplying manufactured goods
and machinery. Following
its accession to the World Trade Organization in 2001, China’s rapid economic growth
and large appetite for
raw materials have spurred African exports of goods, which more than quadrupled in
nominal US dollar terms
between 2000 and 2022.1 Trade has raised the region’s incomes, mostly through higher
export revenues.
1 According to IMF, World Economic Outlook data, total goods exports increased by
about 60 percent in this period in volume terms.
The large difference stems not only from the cumulative inflation since 2000 but also
from the positive evolution of terms of trade for
2 For more details on China’s “go out” policy, see China Ministry of Foreign Affairs
(2021).
3 This figure includes sub-Saharan African countries’ general government debt owed
both domestically and to foreign actors
(external debt), as reported in the World Bank’s International Debt Statistics database,
accessed on August 10, 2023.
End of 2021
Domestic
60.9
China official
bilateral 5.8
Other
official
bilateral
2.1
Multilateral
13.7
Other commercial
16.4
China
commercial
1.1
Figure 2
Sources: IMF Direction of Trade Statistics database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: The chart depicts five-year averages of the share of exports from and imports to
sub-Saharan Africa for the top five destinations
and origins, with the remainder combined in a residual category. Regions are listed from
the largest (top) to the smallest (bottom).
India
India
India
United States
World Bank International Debt Statistics. Five countries (Angola, Kenya, Zambia,
Cameroon, and Nigeria, mostly
resource intensive) account for 55 percent of official bilateral debt to China. There is a
correlation between
the prevalence of bilateral trade and lending disbursements between China and the
region’s countries, after
since 2017. At the 2021 China-Africa Cooperation Forum, China announced its first
cutback in financial support
to Africa, from $60 billion to $40 billion over three years. Half of this reduction was due
to a shift away from
4 Data on FDI are sourced from the United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development.
5 In contrast to the long-standing “go out” policy, the Chinese government announced
plans to reduce overseas capital outflows in 2021.
2000–21
(Billions of US dollars)
Figure 30200400600200005101520
United Kingdom
Africa, 2000–21
(Percent of GDP)
0.5
1.5
2001 03 05 07 09 11 13 15 17 19 21
Commitments
Disbursements
South Sudan.
China-Africa Economic and Trade Expo in June 2023, about $10 billion of projects were
signed (Africanews,
2023)—a 50 percent drop compared with 2019’s event, despite high-profile
attendance.6
Chinese lending to sub-Saharan Africa has drawn considerable attention and criticism
for imposing relatively
harsh terms on debtors and using natural resources as collateral (Bräutigam, Huang,
and Acker, 2020). Other
concerns include the lack of standardization and transparency in public debt because
Chinese lenders do not
In this context, China provides some official loans on concessional terms, accounting for
less than 10 percent of
total bilateral loans received by sub-Saharan Africa from China at the end of 2020,
based on the World Bank’s
International Debt Statistics data. The share of the region’s total external debt-service
cost attributable to
sub-Saharan African countries that are either in debt distress or at high risk of debt
distress account for about
40 percent of the total public debt stock to China at the end of 2020. China has been a
key player in recent
Initiative, during which Chinese lending to low-income countries was minimal). It also
contributed to the
just 30 percent of the claims (Bräutigam and others, 2023). But so far, however, debt
restructuring for some
countries (including under the Group of Twenty Common Framework) has been slow
and challenging because
of several factors, such as many different debt instruments and a more diverse creditor
base (including China),
which requires adaptation and coordination. The recent preliminary agreement between
Zambia and its official
creditors (notably including China) to restructure its external debt is a promising sign for
future resolutions in
other countries.
...and the region could face spillovers from China’s continued slowdown.
(Percent of GDP)-1.00-0.75-0.50-0.250.000.25
Other resource-intensive
countries
Non-resource-intensive
countries
Oil exporters
the median country effect as the thick horizontal line and the
Sub-Saharan Africa.
4
decline in China’s real GDP growth rate leads to about 0.25 percentage points decline
in sub-Saharan Africa’s
total GDP growth within a year. When considering the effect on oil-exporting countries,
the growth shortfall rises
to more than 0.5 percentage points. For non-oil-exporting countries, the growth loss
averages 0.2 percentage
points (Figure 5).7 Therefore, countries that export relatively more to China are more
likely to be affected
negatively by a slowdown in China. This model focuses mainly on the spillovers through
global commodity
prices, trade linkages, and financial conditions, but there are potentially more complex
feedback effects or
Economic Outlook: Sub-Saharan Africa and in the October 2023 World Economic
Outlook, Chapter 3. These
studies also highlight that strategic decoupling, in which countries in the region manage
to maintain trade ties
Sub-Saharan Africa has benefited from China’s growth takeoff, but the region needs to
adapt to China’s
growth slowdown and declining economic engagements. Navigating these new realities
in a context of
global uncertainty and amid increasing geoeconomic fragmentation will require building
resilience and
Building resilience will help cushion against the negative spillovers from China’s growth
decline.
nations and import sources. The African Continental Free Trade Area is particularly
promising, but its
trade environment, including reduction of non-tariff trade barriers. If all are realized, the
median goods
trade within Africa could increase by 53 percent and with the rest of the world by 15
percent. This has
the potential to raise the real per capita GDP of the median African country by more
than 10 percent
and lift an estimated 30–50 million people out of extreme poverty (El-Ganainy and
others, 2023).
and external reliance. This includes reviving efforts to boost domestic revenue
mobilization to reduce
To offset China’s declining economic engagement in the region, structural reforms are
necessary to foster
mitigate the repercussions from changing global trade patterns. Oil-exporting countries
need to gradually
manage the transition away from a heavy reliance on Chinese demand. Moreover, as
the world embraces
the green energy transition, the region can seize opportunities in the strong demand for
critical mineral
exports that support renewable energy development. Countries can strive to develop
more local processing
7 The regional or group average of the response of GDP growth to the shock to
Chinese GDP growth was calculated using the share
of each country’s cumulative GDP between 2018 and 2022 as weighting factor. See
Abdel-Latif and El-Gamal (forthcoming) for more
barriers) will help catalyze private sector growth and enhance the region’s
competitiveness. It is also
infrastructure (roads, railways, airports, and so on) and essential digital infrastructure—
will expand economic
References
Africa.”
Africanews. 2023. “The China-Africa Trade Biennale Bears Fruitful Results.” July 3,
2023.
https://www.africanews.com/2023/07/03/the-china-africa-trade-biennale-bears-fruitful-
results/.
Bräutigam, Deborah, and Yufan Huang. 2023. “Integrating China into Multilateral Debt
Relief: Progress and
Bräutigam, Deborah, Yufan Huang, and Kevin Acker. 2020. “Risky Business: New Data
on Chinese Loans and
China Ministry of Foreign Affairs. 2021. “China and Africa in the New Era: A Partnership
of Equals.”
November 26, 2021.
https://www.fmprc.gov.cn/mfa_eng/wjdt_665385/2649_665393/202111/
t20211126_10453904.html.
El-Ganainy, Asmaa, Shushanik Hakobyan, Fei Liu, Hans Weisfeld, Ali Abbas, Celine
Allard, Hippolyte Balima,
and others. 2023. “Trade Integration in Africa: Unleashing the Continent’s Potential in a
Changing World.”
Mandon, Pierre, and Martha Tesfaye Woldemichael. 2022. “Has Chinese Aid Benefited
Recipient Countries?
Washington, DC.
file:///C:/Users/Stan/Downloads/china-note1.pdf
Home
Research
Long-Form
Occasional Papers
China in Africa: The Role of Trade,
Investments, and Loans Amidst Shifting
Geopolitical Ambitions
Peter Stein
Emil Uddhammar
Chinese influence in Africa is high on the global agenda, as China within just a few
decades has become a key political and economic power in the continent. Indeed, its
emergence as a dominant economic and political actor might be the most important
development in Africa since the end of the Cold War. This paper analyses China's
economic and political relations with Africa beginning in the 1990s. It argues that the
concern is not that China has expanded its economic and political presence in the African
continent; rather, that the other stakeholders have ignored it for long.
Attribution:
Peter Stein and Emil Uddhammar, “China in Africa: The Role of Trade, Investments, and Loans
Amidst Shifting Geopolitical Ambitions,” ORF Occasional Paper No. 327, August 2021,
Observer Research Foundation.
Introduction
China’s relations with the African continent[a] date back to the 15th century. In the Ming Imperial
Tomb in Beijing is a wall painting of a giraffe—it was the famous Chinese admiral and seafarer
Zheng He who brought it to the court in Nanjing during one of several expeditions to the Arab
world and the east coast of Africa between 1413 and 1419.
In modern times, official relations were established with South Africa after Sun Yat-sen was
elected Provisional President of the Young Republic of China in 1911. As the communist
leadership consolidated its hold on power in the early 1950s, China launched a more active
policy of establishing contacts in Africa. Under the shadow of the Cold War, 29 leaders from
political movements in Africa and Asia assembled in Bandung, Indonesia, in April 1955. They
discussed peace, economic development, and decolonisation, and agreed to increase cooperation
between the peoples of the “third world”, a term coined by China’s then leader Mao Zedong.
Although China at the time was relatively underdeveloped, it provided extensive assistance to
emerging African countries. A well-known example from the early 1970s is the Tanzam railway
project, which connected the copper belts in Zambia with the port of Dar Es Salaam. This
enabled Zambia to export copper without having to pass through South Africa or Rhodesia.
This analysis focuses on the period beginning in the 1990s, when China first pondered a “grander
strategy” for Africa. The paper makes an assessment of the implications of increased economic,
political and military exchanges between China and Africa.
To be sure, there is no dearth in literature on China’s activities in Africa. Some authors are
critical and use the term “neo-colonialism” to describe the relationship. Dan Blumenthal, a US-
based expert on China, for instance, has written: ”The Chinese Communist Party’s long-term
strategic objective is to displace the United States as the world’s most powerful country and
create a new world order favorable to China’s authoritarian brand of politics, or its “socialist
market economy.”[1] Others argue that loans and aid from China have an underlying agenda: to
make African states dependent on China and make them more compliant in international
contexts, where China is dependent on the voices of these states, such as within the UN, or in
issues such as Taiwan and Hong Kong. A third group sees China’s operations in Africa as rather
favourable, with infrastructure being expanded and modernised.
The rest of the paper attempts to answer the question of whether China-Africa relations have
further, strategic objectives, and in particular, if China views its economic relations with Africa
as a means for pursuing wider political purposes. The paper outlines the political and normative
differences between the West’s[b] and China’s relations with Africa, and gives an account of
China’s military and strategic initiatives on the continent. Finally, it asks: How should African
states and the wider international community respond to China’s increased presence in Africa?
China’s Economic Relations with Africa
Until the late 1970s the People’s Republic of China’s economic relations with Africa were driven
by ideological imperatives. Today, China’s political leadership view economic relations with the
continent as a means to achieve the country’s development goals. Within a few decades, China
has emerged as Africa’s biggest bilateral trading partner, Africa’s biggest bilateral lender, as well
as one of the biggest foreign investors in the continent.[c]
Chinese companies have entered almost all African markets. Today there are more than 1,000 of
them operating in Africa; some one million people of Chinese descent reside in the continent.
[2]
Many of these Chinese companies in Africa are privately owned, while others are wholly or
partly state-owned. Within this framework, Chinese companies have great degrees of freedom to
operate in Africa on market terms, in addition to being backed by Chinese investment capital on
favourable terms.
Trade in goods and services
China’s trade with Africa was limited in the 1990s and began increasing substantially around
2005 (see Figure 1). Chinese exports to Africa[3] amounted to USD 113 billion in 2019, while
imports from Africa[4] reached USD 78 billion; the volumes have been steadily increasing for the
past 16 years. To be sure, weak commodity prices in the period 2014-2017 had a massive impact
on the value of African exports to China, even while Chinese exports to Africa remained steady.
With a total trade of USD 200 billion in 2019, China is Africa’s biggest bilateral trade partner.
Figure 1. China’s trade in goods and services with Africa (1992-2019, in USD billion,
current prices)
Source: UN Comtrade and the SAIS China Africa Research Initiative (SAIS-CARI)[5]
In 2019, Chinese exports to North Africa (Algeria, Egypt, Libya, Morocco, and Tunisia)
amounted to USD 27 billion, or 23.8 percent of the total to the entire continent, while imports
from North Africa reached USD 7 billion. More than two-thirds of Chinese trade with Africa
thus takes place with the countries located in Sub-Saharan Africa.
China trades with almost all 53 countries in Africa. Table 1 shows, however, that China’s six
biggest export destinations absorb over half of its total exports to the continent. South Africa is
China’s principal export market, followed by Nigeria and Egypt.
Table 1. China’s largest export markets in Africa (2019)
However, the literature on China’s political activities in Africa often mention other goals, which
are considered to guide the Chinese government.[25] One such example is to diplomatically isolate
the democratic Republic of China (Taiwan) by persuading African countries to sever diplomatic
relations with this nation. Another is to influence attitudes towards Hong Kong. These are
examples of China’s underlying goals in cooperating with African countries, which would aim to
achieve compliance with China’s further geopolitical aspirations.
The question has been raised as to whether China, as part of its efforts to achieve these official
and unofficial goals, wants to export a specific Chinese model for development, which can be
replicated in other countries, in this case, those in Africa. Current research points in different
directions here, and many believe that this should be studied primarily in relation to the African
political elites who are regularly invited to China and courted by Chinese diplomats and
businesses.[26]
A well-known Chinese political scientist, Zhang Weiwei, has argued that the specific
developments that have taken place in China over the past 40 years are not transferable to other
countries. In the book The China Wave: Rise of a Civilizational State, published in 2011, Weiwei
highlights eight different factors that contribute to China being a unique civilisational state. The
first are the four “superfactors”: a super-large population; a super-large territory; a super-long
tradition; and a super-rich culture. Then follow the four “unique factors”: a unique language;
unique politics; a unique society; and a unique economy.
This interpretation of China’s uniqueness undoubtedly displays a level of pride and self-
confidence in relation to one’s own culture. It is not unlike imperialist Europe during the latter
part of the 19th century, with its self-image of being the most developed part of the world and
carrying the responsibility to civilise the rest.
About the Communist Party, Weiwei says:
The Chinese Communist Party (CPC) is not a party as the term “party” is understood in the
West. At its core, the CPC continues a long tradition of a unifying Confucian ruling entity, which
represents or seeks to represent the interests of the whole of society, rather than a Western
political party that openly represents certain group interests. [27]
To the extent that this view is shared among the leading political classes in China, it could
explain why the country today, unlike the Soviet Union during the Cold War, does not actively
incite revolutionary movements that aim to install Marxism-Leninism in “third world” countries.
Such activism would also not be in line with Chinese business interests, as these operate
predominantly within the Western capitalist logic and the framework of the World Trade
Organization (WTO). It would also run counter to China’s official policy of non-interference in
the affairs of other countries.
On the other hand, China seems to have a clear will to influence political leaders in Africa and
other developing countries, regardless of whether or not it involves copying its own development
model. The authoritarian interpretation of the CPC has also gained ground, since Xi Jinping in
2018 received a de facto indefinite mandate as president.
China’s principle of non-interference in the domestic affairs of other countries has met with
some criticism, as it can be argued that it risks weakening the principle of “Responsibility to
Protect” or R2P adopted by the United Nations (UN) in 2005—with the support of China. The
purpose of R2P was to give the international community a greater opportunity to intervene to
protect civilian populations from genocide, ethnic cleansing, war crimes, and other crimes
against humanity. This principle is seen as a tool to prevent these abuses from being committed,
and also to provide a basis for a mandate to intervene, if the preventive work fails.
Arthur Waldron, professor of International Relations at the University of Pennsylvania, believes
that the notion of a Chinese policy in Africa based on non-interference in the affairs of other
countries needs to be dissected and argues that the Chinese have had few qualms about
interfering if judged to be in their own interest.[28] According to Waldron, China’s interpretation
of the non-interference policy is that foreign policy should not be enslaved by abstract principles
but rather guided by pragmatic considerations.
Such policy seems to have the support of Africa’s elites. From the West’s viewpoint, it has been
argued that this gives China an advantage in business relations with African countries, as the
political elites there prefer loans, aid and business agreements from a great power that does not
demand certain liberal rights, corruption-free governance, sustainability, transparency, nor
democracy. Others argue that these trends are exaggerated, mainly because there is no single
model for development that China seeks to promote.[29] Still others claim that engagement with
China tends to lead countries in a less democratic direction.[30] At the same time, the West has in
several occasions favoured non-democratic regimes as long as they have worked for other
normative goals that were in line with the West’s development agenda—such as poverty
reduction, and improved healthcare and education.[31] Moreover, it has been done when the West
saw a need for access to crucial raw materials, or a “buffer” vis-à-vis political enemies or
possible military bases.
Normative similarities and differences
The political scientist Stein Ringen has characterised China as a “sophisticated dictatorship”, one
that stands between the authoritarian model and the totalitarian one—or a “controlocracy”.
[32]
There are mock trials and sudden disappearances, of which the entrepreneur Jack Ma is one of
the latest high-profile people to have been affected, just like in Stalin’s Soviet Union or Hitler’s
Germany.
Ringen discusses what motivates the dictatorial power of the Chinese Communist Party, or
its raison d´être. He considers the constant rise in the material standard of living and the
eradication of poverty as the main legitimising factor after Deng Xiaoping’s takeover. At the end
of 2020, China declared that it had completely eradicated extreme poverty in the country over an
eight-year period.[33] President Xi Jinping emphasised at an official ceremony in Beijing in
February 2021 that this “miracle is a complete victory that will go down in history.”[34]
At the same time, this shows that China has achieved goals 1 and 2 of the UN Agenda 2030—
i.e., no poverty or hunger—for a massive one-fifth of the world’s population. This, together with
the continued and accelerating economic exchange between the West and China, means that in
terms of material goals such as prosperity and poverty reduction, standards between West and
China are running in parallel. Furthermore, these material objectives are in line with officially
stated development and poverty reduction policies in most African countries.
There may be another factor that motivates the power of the Communist Party. China experts
point out that there are “three ghosts” chasing China’s political leadership: the century of
humiliation of 1842 – 1949, when foreign powers ruled the “Middle Kingdom”; the destructive
excesses of violence during the Mao Zedong era; and the fall of the Soviet Union. Another way
of expressing this is the fear of weakening or undermining the peace-making Leviathan, the
central power. Unfortunately, this also tends to favour authoritarian leadership and the incumbent
regime. At the same time, peace and stability remain fundamental values.
As discussed briefly earlier, China in Africa often acts bilaterally. Although there is a common
forum for contacts with Africa through the FOCAC and other arenas, agreements are mostly
bilateral. When China acts in African countries, it often does so outside the various platforms for
development established by other donors, where common normative requirements for issues like
procurement and sustainability are monitored. China often abstains from such cooperation.
In the tourism sector, for example, there are Chinese entrepreneurs that act outside the
organisations that exist for ecotourism and for sustainability requirements—this despite China’s
high-profile assurances at world summits as being “protectors” of climate agreements and
sustainability goals. Thus, in terms of common demands for sustainable development, anti-
corruption and common social rights requirements within donor organisations, there is no
normative agreement between the West and China in Africa.
Meritocracy is a traditionally strong value in China.[35] The administrative apparatus has
historically been built on a Confucian basis. From the 17th century it included a rigorous
countrywide system for screening prospective civil servants every three years, which remained in
various forms until 1962.[36] After the chaos of the Cultural Revolution and Deng Xiaoping’s
return to power, one of the first steps he took was to reintroduce national examinations as a basis
for admission to higher education.
Meritocracy in this sense is largely in line with norms in the West, but not insofar as it provides a
basis for recruitment to political leadership within the Communist Party. It is hardly possible to
claim that recruitment to the political classes in the West or in Africa today takes place on
strictly meritocratic grounds. Nevertheless, the lack of transparency in China’s political system
creates opportunities for corruption, which undermines the meritocratic norm.
In China, land cannot be owned by private individuals. However, there are possession rights that
can be valid for up to 70 years. Since 2015, registers for possession rights have been established
in municipalities.[37] In addition, individuals can own real estate, but not the land they stand upon.
In Africa, Western countries and NGOs have initiated formalisation of property rights in several
countries. In this there is no normative agreement with China.
In recent years, the Communist Party has further tightened its grip on the educational sector by
forcing private schools to hand over ownership to the state without compensation.[38] Together
with other recent moves, this puts China’s governance system closer to the totalitarian model,
based upon a Leninist power structure and with the Communist Party and the president as the
main players. Thus there is, using Ringen’s framework, a strong tendency towards
“controlocracy”. It is not likely that this will result in the promotion of liberal democracy,
division of powers, and the rule of law as governance models when engaging with African
countries.
China’s Diplomatic Offensive
The FOCAC has been active for many years and provides political and diplomatic backing for
Chinese companies and investments in the continent.
A 2020 analysis of China’s active diplomacy to influence African leaders, military, and senior
officials observes: [39]
Beijing’s investment in professional training for senior cadres from African countries means that
three synergistic goals can be achieved: (1) the dissemination of a Chinese model for
development and governance (2) the development of a professional network involving Chinese
senior officials, politicians and specialists counterparts in various African countries and other
developing countries within the BRIC, as well as (3) a socialization of African senior officials
and politicians into China’s views on Chinese culture, Chinese diplomacy and interpretations of
history.
Another aspect of China’s “charm offensive” is the so-called Covid vaccine diplomacy.
Donations of relatively modest doses of Chinese vaccine make headlines in African newspapers,
while the West is perceived to be prioritising its own citizens.
An example of Chinese diplomacy in Africa is an official visit by Chinese Foreign Minister
Wang Yi to the Seychelles that took place on 31 January 2021. He underlined that China’s
diplomacy has always been based on equality between small and large countries. China
advocates multilateralism, he said, and opposes power politics; it supports “democracy in
international relations” and supports the UN in its legitimate role in international relations. Large
countries should be the first to follow the basic norms that govern international relations, Wang
Yi emphasised, adding that they should also be the first to “follow the principle of non-
interference in other countries’ internal relations.” They should also be the first to shoulder their
international commitments on climate change and sustainable development.[40]
One aspect of the “propaganda war” is China’s growing media presence. From ownership of
local radio stations to the establishment of a China Central Television station in Nairobi, Kenya,
China is becoming a major influence in the daily discourses in these countries.[41] According
to Afrobarometer survey data in 36 African countries, 23 percent believe that China is the most
influential foreign power in their country, close behind “the former colonial power” (28 percent)
and slightly ahead of the US (22 percent).[42]
Cultural factors and attitudes
A report from the Afrobarometer research project in 2016 states that the US development model
is preferred by most Africans, while a majority view the Chinese presence in Africa favourably.
[43]
A drawback is that Chinese business people have been accused of being condescending towards
Black Africans. In part, this can be attributed to the idea of cultural superiority, as suggested by
the notion of what Weiwei referred to as the four Chinese “superfactors” and the four “unique”
Chinese factors, discussed in an earlier section of this paper.
In Kenya, a Chinese restaurant owner was arrested in 2015 after denying Black Africans entry.
[44]
Sometime in the same year, a Chinese businessman was expelled after calling a Kenyan
employee and the country’s president “baboons”. The 26-year-old employee said he had not
encountered outright racism until the incident.[45] The Chinese embassy apologised, saying that
this did not represent the attitude of the Chinese people.
Zambia has had several incidents of unfair labour practice, some involving violence. During a
2010 strike over working conditions in a Chinese-owned coal mine in the south of the country,
two Chinese managers opened fire and 11 workers were seriously injured. The two were brought
to justice, but the indictment was later dropped.[46] In 2012, a Chinese foreman was murdered at
the same mine.[47]
In 2020, three Chinese supervisors at a textile department store in Lusaka in Zambia were
murdered and their corpses burned, after they were accused of keeping Black workers locked in a
container to avoid being infected by Covid-19, while Chinese customers were allowed to move
freely within the premises. The press said that “the waves of racial antagonism went high.” [48] A
few weeks earlier, a restaurant and a hair salon that had barred Zambians were ordered closed by
authorities.[49]
Such tensions have been exploited by the country’s political leaders. In 2007, the then opposition
leader Michael Sata issued a statement saying, “We want the Chinese to leave the continent and
the former colonial powers to return. Of course, they also exploited our raw materials, but at
least they took care of us.”[50] Sata won the 2011 presidential election in a high-profile anti-China
campaign. Conversely, the government of Edward Lungu (president, 2015-2021) leaned heavily
towards China, which also is the country’s single largest lender.
The Western response
Signs are emerging that the West and its allies, such as Japan and India, are aiming to counter the
economic and diplomatic initiatives from China. One example is the EllaLink, a transatlantic
optic data cable launched with funding from the European Investment Bank and others. The aim
is to be an alternative to the BRI, and to boost high-quality projects in middle- and low-income
countries, including Africa.[51] In 2021 the EU and India launched a global infrastructure
partnership, although both sides are careful not to brand it as any sort of anti-Beijing alliance.
[52]
The India Africa Trade Council, inaugurated in January 2021, is yet another example: it aims
to open 13 trade offices in each of India’s major cities, assisting businesses that could be
interested in conducting trade with African countries.
China’s Strategic and Military Interests in Africa
Economic globalisation has meant that Chinese business interests also benefit from long-term
economic rules and the prevention of conflicts and wars. Thus, in 2008, Chinese warships
arrived on the coast of Africa in the Indian Ocean, to take part in international operations against
piracy, as those activities have also affected Chinese ships. It was the first time China’s navy
operated in these waters since the 15th century.
Soon it was clear, however, that the Chinese presence was not aimed at only fighting pirate
attacks. When piracy subsided around 2012, the Chinese warships remained, and China declared
that its naval presence is part of an ambition to protect its economic interests in the Middle East,
North Africa, and East Africa. It can also be seen as part of the “Maritime Silk Road”, a major
infrastructure project proposed by President Xi Jinping in 2013, which would primarily involve
Chinese investment in ports.[53] The Chinese naval presence was further expanded by a naval
base in Djibouti. On 1 August 2017, the 90th anniversary of the founding of the People’s
Liberation Army, the base was inaugurated. It is the country’s first naval military base outside
China, and is leased for ten years, for which China pays USD 20 million annually.
China’s military presence in Africa goes back to the 1970s, when it supported guerrilla groups
such as Unita in Angola and Frelimo in Mozambique with financing, weapons, and logistics.
Today, China sells weapons to many countries in the region and offers training for African
officer aspirants.[54] There are extensive contacts between China’s military leaders and their
African counterparts. For one, China is training on-site African armies, police forces and soldiers
involved in multilateral peacekeeping operations. China also provides financial support to the
African Union’s military operations, conducts military exercises with African countries, and
plays an active role in UN peacekeeping operations in the continent.
At the same time, the United States, like erstwhile colonial powers such as Britain and France,
have extensive military cooperation in the continent going far back in time. France is estimated
to house about 9,000 people in its military operations, mainly in West Africa and the Sahel. The
UK has significantly fewer permanent staff but trains up to 10,000 each year in Kenya through a
mutual defence cooperation agreement. The United States is considered to hold about 7,200
personnel in the continent, but this commitment will face cutbacks in the coming years. The
Chinese naval force in Djibouti is today estimated to comprise 300 military personnel and 1,700
civilians.[55]
Russia has also expanded its presence in Africa in recent years, through the training of military
personnel and arms exports to some 20 countries. Japan, for its part, opened a military base in
Djibouti in 2011, with the aim of protecting shipping and raw material supplies, but also in view
of supporting access to African markets and balancing the presence of China.[56] Turkey and the
United Arab Emirates have also expanded their military activities in recent years but have no
fixed bases.
Since 1989, about 40,000 Chinese soldiers have been involved in a total of 24 UN peacekeeping
operations in Africa. Today, about 2,400 Chinese soldiers participate in seven of these
operations. In 2019, China contributed USD 7 billion to the UN peacekeeping forces, equivalent
to 15 percent of the UN budget.[57] Among the permanent members of the Security Council,
China today contributes the largest contingent of personnel in UN peacekeeping operations.[58]
Over the years, China has signed bilateral agreements on arms deliveries to Namibia, Botswana,
Angola, Sudan, Eritrea, Zimbabwe, and Sierra Leone, among others. Helicopters have been
delivered to Ghana, Mali, and Angola, as well as tanks to Zimbabwe. In Sudan and Zimbabwe,
the Chinese military has had factories to produce small arms.[59]
In 2014, the Chinese People’s Liberation Army conducted its first joint military exercise with an
African country in Tanzania. In 2018, units from the Chinese Navy visited naval bases in
Cameroon, Gabon, Ghana, and Nigeria and conducted bilateral exercises there.
The Horn of Africa consists of Ethiopia, Eritrea, Djibouti, and Somalia. With the completion of
the Suez Canal in 1896, the area became an important transit route for international trade, by
significantly shortening the transport routes for trade between Asia and Europe. It is through the
Horn of Africa that Africa is linked to the Arab world. Djibouti has become something of a
commercial hub, where ships from all corners of the world reload goods and refuel their ships.
Important commercial transit routes run outside the Horn of Africa, and the area is close to
current conflict areas such as Yemen. Even before the civil war broke out in the region, it had
undergone extensive militarisation. France, Italy, Egypt, Israel, the United States, Japan,
Germany, and Spain are a selection of countries with a military presence in the area.
China’s military presence in Djibouti has several purposes. Owing to its military presence there,
China can take part in military operations to combat terrorism and protect Chinese ships from
piracy.
During the conflict in Libya in 2011, the Chinese military evacuated 35,000 Chinese citizens
stranded in the country. From Djibouti, in 2015, the Chinese military was able to evacuate 800
Chinese from the civil war in Yemen. In view of its major economic interests in Africa, it is
inevitable that China will take an active interest in dealing with the continent’s political
emergencies. An important purpose of the military presence is to protect Chinese factories,
transport routes, and personnel in Africa. Another purpose is to use military hardware as a means
of projecting Chinese soft power.
Through large-scale economic and personnel engagement in the UN’s military operations, China
hopes to be seen as a responsible actor for maintaining order in the region. In times when other
countries have reduced such support, China’s increased involvement has mainly been viewed
positively in Africa. Of course, the continent also offers an arena where China is given the
opportunity to test weapons systems and other military skills. By nurturing ties with military
leaders in African countries, China seeks to incorporate Africa into the country’s wider
geopolitical strategy. China has long been a key political and economic player in Africa; in
recent years, it has become a significant military player.
Conclusion
How should other stakeholders interpret China’s increased activity in Africa?
First, it should be said that this is a matter for the states and people of Africa. Africans rightly
react negatively when representatives of world powers mostly regard the continent as an arena
for their own strategic or economic interests, as was largely the case during the Cold War.
Second, there are few obstacles for other countries to go on a diplomatic offensive in Africa,
should they so decide. The concern is not that China has an increased economic and political
presence in Africa, but that others have ignored it for long. The surrounding world, i.e., the EU
and US, does not seem to have a strategy for how to face the Chinese offensive or to increase its
own presence and confidence in Africa.
Some initiatives are emerging to give alternatives to the Chinese economic offensive, involving
the EU, US, Japan, and India. It would be wise to consider reducing the bureaucracy and the lists
of requirements surrounding such investments, to be able to act in a more pragmatic way without
giving up the most fundamental values.
Third, African countries should be wary of becoming heavily indebted to China. They must
consider the involved political risks of dependency.
Fourth, the EU, US and allies should work more systematically and consistently to incorporate
China into common diplomatic, commercial and NGO forums in African countries, where
mutually beneficial norms and practical solutions can be identified.
Although Africa still makes up a small part of the world economy, population forecasts by the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) show that in 20 years, sub-Saharan Africa will have more
people of working age than the rest of the world. Over the next 40 years, one billion potential
consumers and producers will be added to the region. With better institutions and greater
investment in human capital, Africa can add considerable dynamism to the world and the world
economy. The future of this continent may well hold important tipping points for the world’s
development, including climate change and terrorism.
Geopolitical tensions between China on the one hand, and the West and its allies on the other,
have increased, but Africa is hardly the primary arena for this. The world community should be
alert to any signs of antagonistic or expansionist ambitions that China may have in the continent.
It would be wise for African countries as well as for the West and its allies to prepare for how
such developments should be handled.
Peter Stein is an economist and a noted expert on the economies of Sub-Saharan Africa. Emil
Uddhammar is a professor of political science at Linnaeus University, Sweden
https://www.orfonline.org/research/china-in-africa
Iza Lejarraga
ECFR Alumni · Visiting Fellow
Policy Brief
9 March 2023
Data center with multiple rows of fully operational server racks. Modern cloud computing
technology concept.
Image by picture alliance / Zoonar | Channel Partners
©
Download PDF
Share
Tweet
Facebook
LinkedIn
Reddit
WhatsApp
Table of contents
Go to top
1. Summary
2. Introduction
3. Trade in services: From oxymoron to opportunity
4. Africa’s services trade
1. The potential of trade in services for African countries
2. Leveraging services trade for Africa’s economic transformation
5. EU-Africa trade in services
1. Mutually beneficial trade
2. Existing obstacles
3. Breaking down the barriers
6. Liberalising services through the AfCFTA
7. Conclusions and recommendations
1. Strengthen the data on Africa’s services trade
2. Promote regulatory transparency and cooperation between Africa and the EU
3. Exploit synergies between the AfCFTA and multilateral initiatives on services
4. Experiment with non-traditional, light institutional structures
8. About the author
9. Acknowledgments
Summary
Services are increasingly important for international trade, accounting for about half of
global trade flows. Trade in services is growing more rapidly than trade in goods.
Trade in services is critical for improving the competitiveness of African economies,
increasing their participation in regional and global value chains, and promoting inclusive
growth.
Improved trade in services with African countries could help the EU diversify its supply
chains, strengthening resilience and reducing dependencies on China and other Asian
countries.
The cooperation on domestic regulatory frameworks required for trade in services can
promote a shared understanding of regulatory goals and standards between the EU and
Africa across many sectors.
None of the trade agreements between the EU and African countries currently covers
services, and only one African country is part of the WTO Joint Initiative on Domestic
Services Regulation. There is therefore no dedicated platform for cooperation on services
regulations.
The African Continental Free Trade Area agreement provides an unprecedented
opportunity for African countries to improve domestic services regulations and could be a
new basis for cooperation with the EU.
Introduction
Despite the growing importance of services in the global economy, Europe’s trade cooperation
with Africa is almost exclusively focused on commodities and other primary goods. Services –
which range from banking and insurance to transport – are largely missing from Europe’s trade
and development cooperation agenda with Africa. Yet the services sector has outstripped the
primary and secondary sectors in their contribution to African output, making up more than half
of the continent’s gross domestic product (GDP). The rapid expansion of information and
communication technology (ICT) and the digital economy, the ‘servicification’ of
manufacturing, and the cross-border fragmentation of production processes make trade in
services more important than ever before for industrialisation and integration processes.
Services not only enhance participation in trade and global supply chains, they also contribute to
more equal and diversified growth. More women, young people, and micro enterprises operate in
the services sector than in agriculture or manufacturing. Expanding opportunities in services is
therefore particularly important for creating more inclusive employment. The high costs of
energy, transport, logistics, and other backbone services across Africa make the production of
goods and services expensive, impeding the competitiveness of firms across all sectors. Trade in
services is a powerful tool to increase the efficiency and reliability of services, which in turn
brings down production costs across the economy and facilitates diversification – and its
importance goes beyond trade to offer possibilities for structural transformation.
A stronger services trade between the European Union and Africa would allow European
multinationals to near-shore their production processes and diversify away from Asia-focused
supply networks. As barriers to trade in services are embedded in domestic regulations, trade
agreements covering services entail a degree of cooperation and shared understanding. Improved
trade in services would also allow the EU to influence regulatory models across various sectors.
China and other non-Western powers wield significant economic influence in Africa, which they
can use to shape regulatory processes and influence standards in their favour. Faced with
geopolitical competition with China, the EU should be wary of this influence. In this regard,
trade cooperation on services could be a powerful means for the EU to nurture a shared
understanding with African countries on economic, environmental, digital, and social goals.
No modern trade partnership can exclude services, which are central to the value of what
businesses trade. While the so-called first-generation free trade agreements reached in the 1970s
and 1980s only liberalised and addressed standards in the goods trade, services became an
integral part of the ‘new generation’ agreements that emerged in the mid-1990s. These new
agreements included goals for so-called deep integration, which covers a variety of issues
beyond tariffs, including services, investment, competition, intellectual property rights,
environmental standards, and other domestic policies that affect international competitiveness.
More than 90 per cent of all free trade agreements signed in the 21st century cover services,
making it the most widespread area of deep integration.
The 2018 African Continental Free Trade Area (AfCFTA) agreement includes a protocol on
trade in services, which aims to liberalise services markets and improve their domestic
regulation. The agreement provides an unprecedented opportunity for African countries to
strengthen their domestic regulations to support more open and efficient services markets. It also
offers an occasion for the EU to encourage intra-regional trade by supporting the AfCFTA
negotiations, and to build on the agreement to create new opportunities for diversifying EU-
Africa trade.
This paper explores the implications of cooperation on trade in services for the Europe-Africa
relationship. The first section sets out the complex nature of the services trade and addresses
misconceptions around it. The second section analyses the importance of the services trade for
the industrialisation and integration objectives set out in the African Union’s (AU) Agenda 2063.
The third section discusses the EU-Africa trade relationship, including the benefits for Europe of
a more efficient African services sector and the existing obstacles and policy frameworks that
govern services trade between the EU and Africa. The fourth section explains how the AfCFTA
offers new opportunities for promoting more open and effective regulation of services markets.
The paper concludes with recommendations for how Europe and Africa can enhance their
cooperation on trade in services.
Trade in services: From oxymoron to opportunity
Traditionally, policymakers did not consider services as something that could be traded across
international borders. As a result, governments have often focused their foreign trade strategies
on agricultural and industrial goods. Yet the world has changed enormously, and technological
and regulatory developments have made a growing range of services tradable across the world.
From call centre operators to cloud computing, internationally traded services continue to
emerge and expand.
For many years, services accounted for a small but stable share of global trade. But in the past
decade, data that measures services in value-added terms have shown that they account for over
50 per cent of the value added in gross exports. This data only covers cross-border supply trade,
and does not fully account for digitally enabled services, which are difficult to capture.
Meanwhile, services account for over two-thirds of global foreign direct investment (FDI).
Services are also critical for the production of all goods in the economy, including in agriculture
and manufacturing. The role of services as an input into consumer and capital goods is
substantial, both in developed and in developing countries. A study by the OECD found that
between 25 per cent and 60 per cent of employment in manufacturing firms is attributed to
service functions, including research and development (R&D), engineering, transport, and
logistics. The OECD database on trade in value added shows that services represent 30 per cent
of the value added in exports of manufacturing goods. The total value added has been growing
over time, as manufacturing companies increase the use, production, and exports of services.
Given that goods and services are intertwined, increasing the efficiency of services improves the
competitiveness of the overall economy.
In modern manufactured goods, much of the value added is created in the early stages of R&D,
design, and commercialisation as the product is being conceived, and in the late stages of
marketing, logistics, and after-sales services once production is complete. Countries that do not
offer high-quality services relevant to the international production process are often confined to
the assembly of goods, in which productivity growth tends to be lower. By improving the
competitiveness of these services, a country can increase its prospects to improve its position in a
regional or global value chain and capture activities with greater value added in the international
production chain.
Services only appeared in international trade policy when the World Trade Organization (WTO)
was established in 1995. Before that, countries’ trade relations were governed by the 1947
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, which only covered trade in industrial goods. The
Uruguay round of multilateral talks on trade liberalisation (1986-1994) – which established the
WTO – also led to the creation of an analogous instrument for trade in services: the General
Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). This agreement was part of the so-called great bargain
of the negotiations, in which developing countries accepted the agreements on services and
intellectual property rights – in which they saw few benefits for themselves – in exchange for
ones covering two sectors of interest to them: agriculture and textiles.
The GATS classifies trade in services by the way they are delivered, known as “modes of
supply”:
Cross-border supply: The consumer and the service supplier remain in their respective
countries. The service is transmitted online, or by telephone, email, or post. This mode
includes digitally enabled services.
Consumption abroad: The consumer travels to another country to obtain a service.
Classic examples are tourism and courses for foreign students.
Commercial presence:A company establishes a presence in another country to provide
services to foreign consumers. This mode essentially refers to FDI in sectors such as
banking, transport, and energy.
Presence of natural persons: A supplier, such as an architect, nurse, or musician, travels
to a foreign country to provide a service. The supplier remains temporarily (for a number
of months or years) in the country, and does not obtain residency, citizenship, or
permanent employment.
Unlike trade in goods, trade in services does not have tariffs, but is instead restricted by domestic
regulations, which often apply equally to domestic and foreign actors. Services markets tend to
be highly regulated, much more so than those for goods, hampering the potential for trade. Trade
partnerships on services therefore require regulatory cooperation mechanisms that promote
greater convergence or compatibility across domestic regulatory frameworks, from licensing
procedures to mutual recognition of professionals.
These regulations are intertwined with a broad range of domestic policies that, though not
motivated by trade protectionism, significantly affect trade. For example, regulations related to
shipping and port services are often deeply rooted in national security, territorial, and other
geopolitical factors, but they have become critical in modern services trade negotiations due to
their importance for facilitating global value chains. Similarly, trade in services depends on the
movement of service providers across borders, which is limited by migration and labour policies.
The geopolitics around issues such as climate change and clean energy, technology and
digitalisation, and cultural or indigenous promotion have also been acquiring growing
importance in services trade negotiations. This complicates trade negotiations, which necessitate
agreements around other policies. Yet it also means that the commitments made on these issues
with regards to trade in services can significantly shape broader geopolitical relations.
Cooperation between the EU and Africa in services trade negotiations could therefore promote
understanding on a wide range of policies, deepening EU-Africa relations more broadly.
Africa’s services trade
The potential of trade in services for African countries
Many policymakers still see trade in services as the preserve of high-income countries and do not
consider developing countries as having a comparative advantage in exporting services beyond
tourism. But the trading landscape has changed significantly over the past two and a half
decades, providing more opportunities to participate in trade in services. The increasing
fragmentation of production processes – with different stages carried out in different countries –
has generated fresh opportunities for countries to specialise in and export particular tasks, for
example, marketing, logistics, or legal services, making it easier for companies in developing
countries that cannot produce an entire product to participate in trade.
African countries should have a special interest in promoting an agenda for services trade. The
sector provides opportunities for international research collaboration, and for young people to
pursue education and work abroad – both of which are key for knowledge-oriented societies.
Trade in services also offers possibilities to improve the reliability of transport and logistics; to
expand the digital economy; and to exploit Africa’s comparative advantage in renewable energy.
These sectors are key to African economies, and African governments should therefore not
overlook the role of trade in services in strengthening them.
Trade in services also promotes inclusive economic growth. Unlike trade in commodities or
manufacturing – which entails significant transport costs and cumbersome customs procedures –
services can be traded across borders at lower costs. Services are also increasingly traded
digitally, removing the need for transport and its complexities altogether. This enables smaller-
scale traders, including micro enterprises and entrepreneurs, to import and export services from
distant markets. Given that the services sector has a particularly high concentration of small and
medium-sized enterprises, boosting their trade can induce economic growth at all levels.
African countries have untapped opportunities to trade services. Although data show that
Africa’s exports of cross-border services make up just 2 per cent of the global total, this does not
account for the value added to goods by services, which, as mentioned above, is substantial.
Moreover, the fact that Africa’s exports of services have been growing relatively quickly in
recent years suggests that the continent has a growing comparative advantage in trading services.
Case study evidence also suggests that a significant part of the dynamism in Africa’s services
exports is due to intra-regional trade.
Leveraging services trade for Africa’s economic transformation
The AU’s Agenda 2063 sets out a number of goals to transform Africa into a dominant global
player, prioritising inclusive social and economic development, continental and regional
integration, and democratic and security goals. The AfCFTA aims to boost the levels of intra-
regional trade in Africa, and further diversify and increase the sophistication of traded products.
This prioritisation of regional and continental integration above global trade is driven by the fact
that African countries already trade an increasingly diversified and high value-added set of goods
with one another.
Meanwhile, African exports to the EU remain largely concentrated in primary goods, including
food and drink, raw materials, and energy, with most processing and value addition performed
abroad. African countries are also not well integrated into global value chains, where they
generally perform lower value-added tasks, such as the assembly of different parts. Services are
high value-added activities, so making them more competitive and increasing their trade will
help improve the position of African countries in both regional and global value chains. In
addition, the lower sunk costs of intra-African trade – in part due to lower standards and greater
knowledge of neighbouring markets – means that a greater number of African companies can
export processed goods within the region, whereas only the most productive can export to the
EU.
However, in the long run, Africa’s growth can best be supported by trade beyond the continent.
New types of exports need to acquire scale, which would be challenging to achieve solely within
African markets. Furthermore, the opportunities for technology transfers from trade, FDI, and
strategic partnerships are typically greater with firms located in more advanced economies, such
as those in the EU. African countries experience several common challenges in their efforts to
boost trade with the region and beyond, which trade in services can either alleviate or avoid.
Distance to markets and border friction: High transport costs in the region, especially
between Regional Economic Communities, and customs ‘red tape’ are key impediments
to Africa’s trade competitiveness. These costs are largely reduced or eliminated in
services trade.
Supply chain constraints: Many African companies and countries are not able to take
full advantage of new market access opportunities, intra- or extra-regionally, due to
supply side constraints. Improved services would lessen these supply bottlenecks, both in
terms of human and physical capital. Services trade notably addresses ‘soft’ infrastructure
– the regulation of services that operate on the ‘hard’ physical infrastructure platforms.
For example, the economic activity that a port or airport generates is not solely
determined by the physical infrastructure, but by open regulations that allow private and
foreign shipping, logistics, and airline service providers to operate. This is less
straightforward to address than hard infrastructure issues, but equally important.
Lack of value addition: Many African agricultural exports – from cocoa to cotton to
cashews – are exported raw to global markets. The domestic processing industries that do
exist are often hampered by costly and ineffective services and high subsidies, create
little employment, and struggle to add value. Services make up a significant share of the
value added by processing primary goods, making the end product more competitive.
Limited expansion of regional value chains: Africa is the region with the lowest degree
of integration in global value chains, with integration largely limited to South Africa, and
a few countries in North Africa. Governments have promoted the creation and expansion
of regional value chains, but these remain short, with difficulties scaling up. The
operation of cross-border value chains is highly sensitive to the cost and reliability of
transport, logistics, distribution, and a range of other services. Regional value chains
suffer even more from these factors, as companies are typically smaller than in global
networks and less able to absorb costs related to inefficient and unreliable services.
Improving these services would allow regional and global value chains to scale up.
Trade in services can therefore play an important role in improving the integration of African
countries, regionally and with external partners. The growing middle class, increasing use of
technology, and rapid urbanisation all contribute to the rising importance of service sectors. As
African countries develop, and a growing share of their GDP is driven by services,
diversification into service exports, particularly those that can be traded digitally, will be critical
to maintain growth rates.
EU-Africa trade in services
Despite the rising importance of services, the EU and Africa have not been able to integrate
services in any of their bilateral trade relationships. Similarly, the Aid-for-Trade initiative – a
WTO scheme through which the EU and others channel trade-related technical assistance and
capacity building to developing countries – focuses largely on the goods trade. Globally, nine out
of ten bilateral or regional trade agreements (RTAs) signed since 2000 address the liberalisation
of services and domestic regulations. The EU covers services in its bilateral arrangements with
other trading partners, as well as in a number of trade agreements with developing regions,
including the Economic Partnership Agreements with the Caribbean and with Central America.
Although most recent bilateral agreements between the EU and African countries include
provisions to negotiate services in the future, this has been difficult to put into practice. The two
regions need fresh approaches to cooperation in order to modernise and diversify their trade
relationship and increase its economic impact.
Mutually beneficial trade
Enhanced trade in services with Africa would also benefit the EU. Many European countries are
net exporters of services, and European companies want to expand their presence in Africa in
sectors that currently have high barriers to trade and FDI, such as commercial banking.
Addressing Africa’s deficiencies in services such as transport, logistics, and distribution could
help European multinationals to diversify their trade strategies, making them more competitive
and resilient.
Trade in services does not carry the same risks for trading partners as trade in goods. Liberalising
the goods trade in a bilateral or regional agreement often diverts trade away from more efficient
third-party suppliers. By deepening their trade relationship in agriculture and primary goods,
both the EU and Africa risk reducing trade with more efficient suppliers in other regions, such as
Asia, north America, or Latin America. In contrast, trade liberalisation in services entails
domestic regulatory reform, which often applies to all trading partners as it is not practical to
maintain different domestic regulations for different partners. This limits the risks of diverting
trade away from other partners and allows countries to maintain beneficial trading relationships
with various partners. Trade in services therefore provides an opportunity for the EU to deepen
its trade relationship with Africa, without jeopardising trade with other partners.
Trade agreements that include services not only have greater trade-boosting effects than those
that only liberalise goods, they also affect the location of global value chains. The covid-19 crisis
has intensified efforts from businesses and policymakers in the EU to diversify and near-shore
global value chains, and to balance efficiency with resilience. Supply security vulnerabilities and
dependencies on particular trading partners also have geopolitical ramifications, weakening the
EU’s ability to act autonomously. Intensified geopolitical competition with China has also
increased the EU’s desire to diversify away from its traditional partners in Asia. Open services
markets in Africa would help Europe support both the security of its key supply chains and its
autonomy. European companies would benefit from locating value chains in African countries
too, given the geographical proximity of and lower production costs in Africa.
The EU and Africa have the potential to be natural trading partners in direct services. Trade in
services is highly sensitive to factors that impede people-to-people contact, such as language
barriers; differences in time zones; and cultural, historical, and institutional divides. Conversely,
trade in services largely avoids the costs of distance and crossing borders, such as transport,
customs, and complex rules of origin. Africa and the EU share similar time zones and some of
the same languages. In addition, some of the regulatory frameworks and institutions in African
countries have been modelled on European legal and institutional systems. The two continents
therefore have relatively few of the common obstacles to trading services to contend with.
Existing obstacles
There is a lack of systematic and comprehensive information on barriers to trade in services
across Africa, but the available data suggest that these are high. For example, an OECD index
(covering 38 OECD countries and seven emerging economies) that measures policy restrictions
in services finds that South Africa – the only African country covered – is more restrictive than
the average EU, OECD, and emerging market economy covered in 15 of 22 service sectors. Over
the years, new legislation passed in South Africa – where services represent 60 per cent of GDP
and 70 per cent of employment – has increased the regulatory restrictions. Key sectors such as
commercial banking, cargo-handling, and courier services have higher than average policy
restrictions. On the other hand, South African policies in a few sectors, such as road freight
transport, legal, and accounting services are closely aligned with those in advanced OECD
countries and large emerging economies.
A 2010 World Bank index for 27 African countries, based on 2008 information, found great
variation in the barriers to trade in services across African countries, ranging from Mauritius as
the most liberal to Ethiopia as the most restrictive. However, the index only tracks regulations on
services that explicitly discriminate against foreign services suppliers, while the problem for
trade in services in many African countries is the absence of a regulatory framework. As a result,
some countries that appear relatively liberal in this area in fact lack regulation, leaving decisions
on whether foreigners can operate in the country to ministerial discretion.
Breaking down the barriers
In the absence of a bilateral agreement covering services, the trade relationship between the EU
and African countries is governed by the GATS. However, when the GATS was concluded, most
African countries were not interested in committing to comprehensive liberalisation in service
sectors. There has been little substantive global liberalisation in services since, with the
exceptions of financial services and ICT – for which WTO members concluded negotiations
after finalising the GATS. In 2010, 70 countries attempted to conduct wider services
liberalisation through an agreement on trade in services, but only one African country –
Mauritius – participated in these negotiations, which were never concluded.
In December 2021, 70 countries – including all EU and other major European countries –
concluded the first successful global services trade cooperation pact since the GATS: the Joint
Initiative on Domestic Regulation. The agreement does not address market access, but
participants commit to improving domestic regulation of services and to streamlining procedures
such as certification and licensing. Only two African countries – Nigeria and Mauritius – are
currently parties to the agreement. But, because participants have agreed to implement these
commitments for all their trading partners, there will be export benefits for all African countries.
In particular, they will benefit from more transparent and streamlined procedures for exporting
services. Moreover, African countries can join the agreement if they wish, and there is a
mechanism for least-developed countries (LDCs) to modify their commitments according to their
capacities.
In June 2022, WTO members committed to reinvigorating efforts to operationalise a waiver that
allows governments to grant more favourable services market access to LDCs. The LDCs
‘services waiver’, created in 2015, is similar to the duty-free and quota-free market access for
goods given to LDCs under the WTO enabling clause. Unfortunately, implementation has been
limited and ineffective. The waiver also has limitations: trade-related restrictions are higher on
services than on goods in EU and other OECD countries, and have been rising in recent years in
many sectors, including digital-related sectors. Moreover, because the liberalisation that is taking
place multilaterally and in RTAs on services has been limited, the potential for trade preferences
is more significant. In the case of goods, tariff preferences obtained in RTAs have been largely
eroded as the level of tariffs has come down through WTO negotiations and more RTAs
liberalising goods have been concluded. The waiver is also limited to LDCs, and so would only
apply to 32 African countries. A similar waiver on goods has been in place for LDCs for
decades, and it has arguably failed to substantially increase their participation in world trade.
Many of the impediments to trade in services are embedded in non-discriminatory domestic
regulations. In practice, it is difficult to convince regulators to accord preferential waivers. In
addition, trade in a service often requires several different modes of supply, which may face
different degrees of regulation. For example, granting market access to allow a business to
establish a commercial presence in a country without granting market access on the movement of
persons means that a business would be allowed to invest abroad but would not be able to move
its personnel. Given that multiple modes often co-exist, waivers are ineffective if they are limited
to certain modes.
Liberalising services through the AfCFTA
EU and African policymakers should engage in renewed efforts to facilitate trade in services
between the EU and Africa. The AfCFTA provides a unique opportunity for them to do so. The
agreement is often hailed for its size and far-reaching tariff-free regime, but the liberalisation of
trade in services is one of its most important features. Its protocol on trade in services is the
continent’s first broad effort to liberalise trade in services and improve the domestic regulation of
key services sectors. The protocol provides a framework, and actual liberalisation is taking place
through subsequent negotiations.
The 54 countries that have ratified the AfCFTA to date have agreed on liberalising five priority
services – financial, communication, transport, tourism, and business services – and are currently
engaging in negotiations to make specific-sector commitments. This process was supposed to be
completed by June 2022, but at the time of writing (January 2023) negotiations had not
concluded, and the schedules of specific commitments were not publicly available. As a result, it
is impossible to assess the extent of liberalisation to trade in services under the AfCFTA.
However, the AfCFTA agreement has several advantages which can aid the process of
liberalisation.
The negotiations are using a positive list approach (the so-called GATS approach), which is
sometimes perceived as a less effective means of liberalisation than a negative list (the so-called
North American Free-Trade Agreement approach). A positive list indicates all the sectors and
measures that are being liberalised, whereas a negative list indicates the sectors and measures
that are exempted from liberalisation (thereby liberalising all sectors or measures that are not
listed). The same degree of liberalisation can be achieved through either approach. It is
understandable and perhaps advisable that countries with limited administrative capacities adopt
a positive list approach, which does not require internal consultation concerning all service
sectors of the economy – just those in which there is a decision to liberalise. Moreover, the
GATS followed a positive list approach, and using the same approach facilitates synergies
between regional and multilateral negotiations.
A key difference between the AfCFTA services protocol and the GATS is the treatment of
commitments by LDCs. Unlike the GATS framework and LDCs waiver – in which LDCs are not
required to make any substantive liberalisation commitments – in the AfCFTA, any differential
treatment is considered on a case-by-case basis. This encourages all countries regardless of their
level of development to liberalise services and strengthen their domestic regulatory frameworks,
which in turn allows them to be more competitive in exports. This departure from an LDC-
centred form of special and differential treatment can provide inspiration for new approaches of
engagement in the WTO and other trade partnerships between developed and developing
countries.
There are open questions about the effectiveness of the AfCFTA in facilitating domestic reforms.
Yet, given the difficulty of passing reforms at the domestic level, it is hard to imagine that such
reforms would more readily take place without an external anchor. It is very difficult to change
shipping, ports, and logistics regulations that are embedded in maritime and ports laws which
often date back to or predate countries’ independence, and which are grounded in national
security motives. A major RTA such as the AfCFTA provides governments with an external
mandate to review and modernise these laws and generates peer pressure as other African
countries pass reforms and gain the benefits from doing so. It also provides incentives for the
less appealing measures (for example, visas for temporary study and work abroad in exchange
for resisted changes in transport services or warehousing regulations) and avoids policy reversals
when governments or regulators change. Furthermore, it often brings external technical
assistance and capacity building to implement reforms. With sustai
https://ecfr.eu/publication/tricks-of-the-trade-strengthening-eu-african-cooperation-on-
trade-in-services/
Get monthly
e-newsletter
Cover Story
Trade between two unequal partners
Africa and Europe search for an elusive agreement
Trade Integration in Africa: Unleashing the Continent's Potential in a Changing World
Author:
Ms. Asmaa A ElGanainy
,
Shushanik Hakobyan
,
Fei Liu
,
Hans Weisfeld
,
Céline Allard
,
Hippolyte W. Balima
,
Celine Bteish
,
Rahul Giri
,
Mr. Daniel S Kanda
,
Sergii Meleshchuk
,
Mr. Gustavo Ramirez
,
Robert Zymek
,
Mr. Vivek B. Arora
,
Mr. Subir Lall
,
Benjamin R Kett
, and
Miss Megan M Pohl
Publication Date:
05 May 2023
eISBN:
9798400232794
Language:
English
Keywords:
trade centrality index; trade openness; improvements in the trade environment; trade cost;
infrastructure indicator; trade environment elasticity; trade infrastructure indicator
Download PDF (1 MB)
Abstract
Full Text
Related Publications
Abstract
Since the 1960s, several initiatives have been undertaken to enhance trade integration in Africa.
However, substantial tariff and nontariff barriers remain in place. In recent years, African leaders
have shown a renewed push for regional integration by signing the agreement on the African
Continental Free Trade Area (AfCFTA). The AfCFTA has the potential to transform regional
trade and thereby lift growth and support livelihoods across the continent. This paper lays out the
benefits that successful AfCFTA implementation could unlock for Africa in terms of income,
jobs, and other benefits. It is based on an empirical analysis of the obstacles to trade in goods and
services and regional value chain integration along with a discussion of how regional trade
integration and supporting policies could help African countries cope with ongoing global and
domestic trends. The empirical analysis investigates the role of trade policy and the broader
trade-enabling environment in determining the bilateral goods trade flows and country-level
trade in services. It sheds light on how the implementation of AfCFTA and supporting policies
could boost trade and income as well as help African countries integrate into regional value
chains. The findings suggest that plausible reductions in tariffs and nontariff barriers under
AfCFTA, along with improvements in broader trade-enabling environment (trade infrastructure,
financial development, and domestic security), would substantially boost intra-African trade in
goods and services, and support integration into regional value chains. Further, regional trade
integration could be an important element of a strategy for African countries to cope with rapid
population growth, climate change, and emerging geopolitical fragmentation.
1. Overview-Unlocking the Benefits of Regional Trade
Integration in Africa
Initiatives to foster greater economic integration in Africa over several decades culminated in the
creation of the African Continental Free Trade Area (AfCFTA) in 2018, with the goal of
expanding intra-African trade and promoting economic diversification and industrialization of its
member countries. The AfCFTA aims to achieve this through the liberalization of goods and
services trade across the continent, trade facilitation by enhancing border processes, and
implementation of certain “behind the border” measures (Box 1). This paper discusses how
implementation of the AfCFTA, when complemented with other reforms, could catalyze deeper
trade integration both within the African continent and with the rest of the world, thereby
embracing the opportunities offered by technological change, a growing working-age population,
and a changing global environment. By facilitating specialization, exploitation of scale
economies in production, productivity growth and strengthening of cross-border value chains,
closer regional trade integration would raise growth rates and living standards in African
countries and enhance their resilience to shocks.
The experience of globalization in past decades suggests there is a large unrealized potential for
African economies to enhance trade with each other and the rest of the world in terms of both
volume and share of value added. The growth in the continent’s overall trade has been modest,
reflecting limited growth of merchandise trade and an unchanged share of services trade in GDP.
The evolution of intra-African trade in particular reflects two main considerations: the trade
policy landscape is fragmented with multiple regional economic communities (RECs) that
generally have provided limited within-bloc integration and little between-bloc integration, with
still substantial tariff and nontariff measures (NTMs);4 and a trade environment (structural
factors that affect trade such as transport networks and border processes) that is more challenging
than elsewhere. As detailed in the 2021 World Trade Organization (WTO) report, while global
trade has had positive effects for African industrialization and development, efforts must
continue to help Africa build capacity and take fuller advantage of the benefits offered by trade.5
Implementing AfCFTA provides such an opportunity to enhance trade capacity and reap the
benefits from trade. This paper examines the potential impact of implementing AfCFTA on
Africa’s intraregional and overall trade and recommends policies that are needed to ensure
sustained gains from trade integration.
This paper’s analysis suggests that AfCFTA goals to lower tariffs and NTMs across the
continent, if combined with reforms to the trade environment, could significantly boost Africa’s
trade in goods and services both within the region and with the rest of the world, raising income
levels and supporting integration into crossborder value chains:
Regarding merchandise trade, a lowering of tariffs and NTMs between African countries
as planned under the AfCFTA would lead to notable increases in trade and incomes.
These gains would be amplified considerably if complemented with improvements in the
trade environment, for example, transport and telecommunications infrastructure, access
to finance, and domestic security, to bring them to levels comparable to those in other
regional free trade agreements (FTAs). More concretely, a cut in tariffs on intra-African
trade by 90 percent and NTMs by half could increase the median merchandise trade flow
between African countries by 15 percent and real per capita GDP in the median country
by 1.25 percent. However, if accompanied by complementary improvements in the trade
environment, the median merchandise trade flow between African economies would rise
by 53 percent and with the rest of the world by 15 percent, raising real GDP per capita in
the median country by more than 10 percent. World Bank estimates of a broadly similar
growth scenario suggest that this would help 30-50 million people in Africa emerge from
extreme poverty.
Under a scenario of broad-based trade reforms combining AfCFTA implementation with
improvements in the trade environment, the composition of trade would also change to
include more sophisticated products. This would support integration into regional and
global value chains, opening up opportunities for diversification of sectors and expansion
of manufacturing industries. Improvements in the trade environment would boost
services exports by about 50 percent.
Importantly, increasing the role of trade in Africa would allow countries to embrace the
opportunities provided to Africa by the continent’s rising working-age population against
the backdrop of ongoing technological progress to raise incomes and living standards for
all. An improved trade environment would also provide diversification benefits in terms
of food availability and affordability, resilience to shocks such as from natural disasters
including due to climate change, and the ability to navigate and adapt to dislocations or
shifts in global trade patterns.
In addition to policies that directly facilitate trade expansion, complementary policies are needed
to ensure gains from trade integration can be sustained and that the benefits are shared as widely
as possible across the population. For the growing workforce to take advantage of the
opportunities that trade integration brings, it will be important to invest in their education and
skills. Protecting those that are adversely affected during the transition will require upgrading
social safety nets to be able to efficiently target the most vulnerable in a fiscally sustainable way.
More broadly, for comprehensive reforms to be sustained and generate the largest possible
benefits in terms of income and employment creation, they need to be embedded in policy and
institutional frameworks that safeguard macroeconomic stability and promote a favorable
business environment
https://www.elibrary.imf.org/view/journals/087/2023/003/article-A001-en.xml
May 2020
Robert Kappel
AFRICA-EUROPE
ECONOMIC
COOPERATION
»Towards a Comprehensive
European Union.
AFRICA-EUROPE
ECONOMIC
COOPERATION
WITH AFRICA
nual GDP growth rate for the last 20 years has been 4.6 per
cent, but growth has been uneven across the African con-
the increase for the last 15 years, the current trends sug-
gest that by 2030, there will still be more than 400 million
and Africa reached a total value of 235 billion euros (32 per
than five times the figure for either of the other two major
world powers China and the US. Companies from the UK,
the US, UK and France. But China’s FDI stock in Africa, ac-
counting for just five per cent of the total, remains low
EU-Africa relations.
via more Aid for Trade (AfT), and enhancing intra- and in-
The AEA had the goal of creating ten million jobs within
five years.
and youth.
weak.
logue (pillar 3). The EIP’s financial arm, the European Fund
EIP has a high level of funding, and this alone could mean a
proactive policy.
China and the US. The crisis in Africa also reveals the
sponsibility.
EIP.
states.
WITH AFRICA
PARTNERSHIP REQUIRED.
problem.
actors in the informal sector are the key basis for the sur-
ers for SMEs can stimulate economic growth and thus in-
average of just 100,000 new jobs per year. Jobs for 20 mil-
ment-intensive FDI.
jobs.
which also creates jobs, is not only useful for Africa’s devel-
region.
Trade in Africa.
PUSh DIGITAlISATION
tion.
ed are:
supported.
CONCLUSION: TOWARDS A
are largely rooted in the US, the EU and China with their
many well-known ideas but does not pave the way for ad-
The views expressed in this publication are not necessarily those of the
IMPRINT
Responsible:
Phone: + 32 22 34 62 90
Renate.Tenbusch@fes europe.eu
www.fes europe.eu
Phone: +49-30-269-35-7441
www.fes.de/en/africa department
To order publications
Coverillustration
annelehmann.de
ment.
https://library.fes.de/pdf-files/iez/16251.pdf
Suggested Citation: Abendin, Simon; Duan, Pingfang (2021) : International trade and
economic
growth in Africa: The role of the digital economy, Cogent Economics & Finance, ISSN
https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2021.1911767
http://hdl.handle.net/10419/270066
Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:
Terms of use:
licence.
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=oaef20
To cite this article: Simon Abendin & Pingfang Duan | (2021) International trade and
economic
growth in Africa: The role of the digital economy, Cogent Economics & Finance, 9:1,
1911767,
DOI: 10.1080/23322039.2021.1911767
Abstract: This paper examines the role the digital economy plays in international
2000–2018. We further divided the sample into five sub-regions, and the results are
estimated by POLS, random and fixed effects, and the GMM models. The findings
showed that (1) trade only has positive effects on economic growth when inter-
acted with the digital economy in the POLS estimations, (2) Trade has a significantly
positive impact on economic prosperity without and with the interactive term in the
RE, FE, and the sys-GMM estimations, (3) the output elasticities of capital and labor
have positive and negative impacts on economic growth, respectively, (4) the
output elasticities for the indicators. The study recommends that concentrated
Keywords: International trade; Africa; POLS; random effects; fixed effects; economic
growth and digital economy
1. Introduction
The economic growth effect of trade has been the subject of much debate among
academic
of economic growth worldwide. While international trade flows have often been volatile
and prone to
https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2021.1911767
Page 1 of 25
E-mail: [email protected]
Reviewing editor:
USA
© 2021 The Author(s). This open access article is distributed under a Creative
Commons
recurring trade barriers, many countries still seek international trade because of the
large, favorable
externalities associated with the trade. Trade’s position as a driver of economic growth
is fast
becoming crucial, particularly in African countries, since the region is endowed with
natural resources
with low industries to process these resources into consumable goods and other
intermediate
especially in Africa, have adopted trade policies, including import substitution strategies,
exchange
rates, tariffs, and quantitative controls, to promote international trade in the region.
These trade
Conventional trade theory has assumed that trade encourages economic prosperity as
trade leads to
the reallocation of capital, and countries engaging in trade tend to have a comparative
edge as they
Despite various initiatives taken by developing countries to liberalize trade with the rest
of the world,
a part (Asiedu, 2013; Doan, 2019; Haddad et al., 2013). This has given rise to an
intense debate among
development economists and other academics about whether international trade boosts
economic
effect of international trade on economic progress in Africa and the rest of the
continents. On the one
hand, some of the empirical studies have shown positive effects of international trade
on economic
growth (Ades & Glaeser, 1999; Badinger & Breuss, 2008; Brini et al., 2017; Doan, 2019;
Frankel & Romer,
1999; Gokmenoglu et al., 2015; Grossman & Helpman, 1990; Kumar, 2012; Le, 2020;
Manwa &
Wijeweera, 2016; Nkikabahizi et al., 2018; Van Den Berg, 1997; Zahonogo, 2017). On
the other hand,
some scholars reported negative or inconclusive impact of international trade on
economic growth in
Africa and the rest of the world (Cerdeira Bento & Moutinho, 2016; Manwa et al., 2019;
Menyah et al.,
2014; Mullings & Mahabir, 2018; Polat et al., 2015; Rahman & Mamun, 2016; Zheng &
Walsh, 2019).
These contradictory (inconclusive) findings continue to exist and call for more study to
fill the knowl-
edge gap.
In recent years, the digital economy has usually been credited with contributing to
sustainable
and natural resources; and the accumulation of productive capacity in the extractive
industries. The
digital economy-growth nexus has been theoretically well established in the literature,
followed by
country-level empirical evidence in studies such as (Cronin et al., 1991; Erumban &
Das, 2016; Ghosh,
2016; Saidi et al., 2017) indicating the crucial role of the digital economy in productivity,
growth, and
development. Empirical studies like (Bahrini & Qaffas, 2019; Ghosh, 2016; Hofman et
al., 2016; Njoh,
2018; Petersen, 2019) reported that the economy’s digitalization is improving economic
growth.
Theoretically, it is argued that the digital economy encourages trade as trade leads to
the
reallocation of capital, and countries engaging in trade tend to have a comparative edge
as they
specialize in development and exports to their trading partners, which boosts economic
growth
(Lwoga & Sangeda, 2019; Sassi & Goaied, 2013). For example, some scholars
(Abeliansky et al.,
2020; Freund & Weinhold, 2004; Lin, 2015; Ozcan, 2018; Rodríguez-Crespo &
Martínez-Zarzoso,
2019; Vemuri & Siddiqi, 2009) document that the digitization of the economy has had a
substantial
positive effect on foreign trade. It is necessary to note that international trade’s growth
effects will
economy guarantees low transaction costs, effective delivery of capital, quick access to
foreign
https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2021.1911767
Page 2 of 25
markets, the quicker transmission of business information and data, and thus boosts
economic
Despite the massive role that the digital economy plays in trade, this appears to be
disregarded by
the existing literature on the impact international trade has on economic growth.
Empirical surveys
have centered on the economic development effect of the digital economy, suggesting a
clear
correlation. These studies indicate that digital infrastructure improves economic growth
(Czernich
et al., 2011; David, 2013). In brief, theoretical literature suggests that foreign trade has a
favorable
impact on economic growth, although empiric literature reports mixed findings.
Simultaneously, the
economic growth impact. Thus, countries with a well-functioning digital economy are
projected to
correlate favorably with foreign trade and global growth rates (Abeliansky & Hilbert,
2017).
Our motive is to investigate the extent to which foreign trade facilitates economic growth
in Africa,
is focused on the fact that, to the best of our knowledge, no longitudinal studies were
performed at
the time of this study on the crucial role of digitalization in influencing the growth effects
of foreign
trade. The non-existence of studies on the economic growth effects of the interaction
between
international trade and the digital economy made this study stand uniquely from the
related
literature; hence its novelty sources. The study contributes to the existing literature in
that earlier
studies (Doan, 2019; Manwa & Wijeweera, 2016; Manwa et al., 2019; Zahonogo, 2017)
trying to figure
out the effect of international trade on economic growth seems to have ignored the role
the digital
economy in influencing the effect of trade on the economic growth, particularly in Africa.
Therefore,
the study contributes to the literature by incorporating the digital economy’s effects on
Africa’s trade-
led growth. Another gap in the literature that this study fills in is the weak measurement
of
digitalization. For instance, studies such as (Kouton, 2019; Myovella et al., 2019)
measured the digital
and broadband subscriptions. The inadequate digital economy proxies are insufficient to
assess the
digital economy’s interactive effect and international trade on economic growth. Poor
and inade-
quate digital economy measures may yield results that are misleading and meaningless
to policy-
makers. Our research aims to fill this void by utilizing three dimensions of the digital
economy, the
access, use, and skills aspect, to create a digital economy index. We employed the
principal compo-
Moreover, we show whether the contribution of international trade and the combined
effects of the
digital economy and trade on economic growth differs from Africa’s five regions: Central,
East, North,
South, and West. The rest of the article is structured as follows: first, we provide
theoretical and empirical
international trade issues in Africa. Second, we describe the data and overview the
digital development
and international trade in the countries under study. Next, we include the empirical
methods and
a discussion of the results. Summary and concluding remarks are made in the final
section.
2. Literature review
This section is dedicated to the review of literature relevant to international trade and
economic
growth. We first reviewed the theoretical literature on international trade and economic
growth,
The relation between international trade and economic growth has drawn a great deal of
interest
reviewed three theories below related to international trade and economic prosperity.
https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2021.1911767
Page 3 of 25
The mercantilist theory of trade argued that the only means a country or nation can
become
wealthy and powerful is by maintaining less import of goods and services but instead
encourages
more export of goods and services to other countries. The mercantilist claimed that
growing
exports and keeping imports at a minimum level would allow countries to achieve a
favorable
balance of trade, which, in turn, would contribute to national prosperity and, thus,
economic
development. Based on this notion, one can conclude that the mercantilist believes in a
one-way
Advantage theory) and David Ricardo (also credited with the Comparative Cost
Advantage theory)
positioned that both countries engage in international trade stand a chance to benefit
from the
trade even though some countries will gain more than others. Both Adam Smith and
David Ricardo
concluded that countries prosper from foreign trade if they specialize and export
commodities
(goods) with notably lower cost advantages and import goods with a significantly higher
cost
disadvantage. In this view, the classical theory’s primary implication is that a country
benefits from
theorists further suggest that trading with other nations will bring in new technology and
skills
to contribute to higher efficiency and economic development. They also positioned that
engaging
in foreign trade leads to economic growth since each country would share trade
benefits.
The Heckscher-Ohlin theory (H-O model) of trade suggests that the differences in
countries’
resources are the driving force of international trade. The theory states that the
comparative
advantage comes from the difference in the abundance of factor production and the
factor intensity
of the products (Morrow, 2010). It is also referred to as the 2x2x2 model, two countries,
two goods,
and two production factors. The theory emphasizes that a country should export
products that
require production factors that it has in abundance. It also emphasizes the importation
of goods
which cannot be produced as easily by a region. It is of the view that countries should
ideally export
surplus materials and energy while importing goods that they need proportionately.
Heckscher (1919)
and Ohlin (1933) concludes that a country with sufficient factor endowment would
increase growth if
Aside from the theoretical view of the economic growth effect of international trade, a
large number
of empirical studies have been conducted at the macro-level on the link between
international trade
and economic growth with contrary views, which has been attributed to the varying
econometric
methodologies used and the scope of the studies. Some of the earlier studies
conducted analyze
Bento and Moutinho (2016) used data from Italy and the autoregressive distributed lag
bound test
hypothesis. However, they revealed positive CO2 emission effects of international trade
in Italy.
Polat et al. (2015) reveal that the well-developed financial sector boosts economic
growth while
ment. Sun and Heshmati (2010) conducted a six-year study on the economic growth
effects of
international trade in China. The results suggest that international trade stimulates
national eco-
nomic growth. Similarly, Zheng and Walsh (2019) analyzed the effect of energy
consumption on
urbanization in the production model in the 2001–2012 provincial panel of evidence, the
findings
show that urbanization is a key determinant of economic growth, although not having
exact results
to support the hypothesis that international trade encourages economic growth in China.
https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2021.1911767
Page 4 of 25
In the same vein, Mitsek (2015) modeled the relationship between trade inflation and
economic
growth using Russia’s data for the next 2–3 years starting in 2015. The findings of the
model
revealed an adverse economic growth effect of foreign trade on the Russian economy.
The
equations suggest that a percentage rise in import and export rates leads to a 1.5%
decline in
the Russian economy’s economic growth rate. Gokmenoglu et al. (2015) confirmed that
trade and
well-functioning capital markets drive Pakistan’s economic progress. Also, the findings
further
Similarly, Shahbaz et al. (2013) applied the ARDL model to examine the link between
financial
sector development, energy use, economic growth, and trade in China. The authors
also identified
positive economic growth impacts of energy use, financial development, and trade.
Moreover, the results also revealed a bi-directional causality between international and
economic
growth. Using panel data from the pooled average group estimator (PMG) of six Gulf
Cooperation
Councils from 1980–2010, Jouini (2015) confirms that international trade positively
impacts economic
growth in both the short-and long-term. Yenokyan et al. (2014) conclude that trade
affects economic
activities in two ways: the overall impact of size and technologies’ transition. It also
clarified that the
average costs and higher productivity per firm. The transfer of the technology medium is
the product of
encourage more substantial foreign exchange. Another study by Rahman and Mamun
(2016) looked at
Australia’s energy-led development and trade-led growth over 1960–2012. Using the
ARDL estimation
process (Rahman & Mamun, 2016) provided data supporting the trade-led growth
hypothesis while they
do not find evidence to support the Australian economy’s energy-led growth. From the
theories and the
existing literature propositions, the authors deduced the following: trade brings in new
technology and
skills to contribute to higher efficiency and economic development. Exporting more and
import less
promotes economic prosperity, and that many empirical studies find support for the
theoretical views.
touted with low economic growth is essential. We, therefore, hypothesis that:
Africa
Many empirical studies have argued for a positive relationship between digital
development
and economic growth in developed and developing countries. For instance, Adeleye
and Eboagu
(2019) report that internet usage, mobile penetration, and fixed telephone increase
economic
growth by 0.22%, 0.86%, and 0.68%, respectively, in Africa. Similarly, (Chavula, 2013)
hypothesized
in the existing literature are that information and communication technology promotes
economic
Africa
Previous studies on the relationship between the digital economy and international trade
(Abeliansky et al., 2020; Freund & Weinhold, 2004; Lin, 2015; Ozcan, 2018; Rodríguez-
Crespo &
Martínez-Zarzoso, 2019; Wang & Choi, 2019) but not limited to documented positive
results.
Freund and Weinhold (2004) conclude that internet use positively influences
international trade.
Lin (2015) reported a shred of evidence that indicates international trade positive effects
of
internet use. Ozcan (2018) documented positive international trade effects of ICT.
Rodríguez-
https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2021.1911767
Page 5 of 25
Crespo and Martínez-Zarzoso (2019) examined the link between ICT and international
trade and
Similarly, Wang and Choi (2019) investigated the effects of ICT on trade for BRICS
countries,
covering 2000 to 2016 panel data. The results of their study suggest that ICT usage
promotes
international trade. They points out that the digital economy promotes international trade
as
revealed that the digital economy positively impacts trade. Bankole et al. (2015) argued
that
growth effects.
Studies linked to trade-led growth in Africa Chang and Mendy (2012) reported evidence
supporting
the international trade-led growth hypothesis for 36 African countries observed from
1980 to 2009.
Hossain and Mitra (2013) used the dynamic panel study methodology to examine
economic growth
determinants for 33 African countries and presented evidence to support trade’s positive
economic
growth impact. This means that international trade stimulates economic prosperity in
Africa. Caleb
et al. (2014) look at the relationship between international trade and Zimbabwe’s
economic growth
from 1975 to 2005. The analysts used a cointegration analysis and reported that trade
enhances
economic growth in Zimbabwe. Similarly, Ajmi et al. (2015) established a significant bi-
directional
causality link between exports and growth in the South African economy.
Likewise, Ehigiamusoe and Lean (2018) found evidence to support the trade-led
economic growth
in Ghana, Nigeria, and South Africa. The authors also revealed a tripartite causality
amongst financial
development, trade, and economic growth. Thus, trade and financial sector
development could be
ship between energy consumption, financial development, trade, and economic growth
in South
Africa. The study results suggest that trade has both short and long-run positive impacts
on economic
growth, while financial development hurts the South African economy. The results’
coefficients
0.24% rise in economic growth, respectively. On the other hand, a shock in financial
development
Oyebowale and Algarhi (2020) investigated using the pooled mean group estimation on
panel data
mations indicate that a shock in exports, gross fixed capital formation, and government
expenditures
produce positive economic growth in Africa, while a shock in broad money produces an
insignificant
growth impact. Nkikabahizi et al. (2018) examined similar relations employing data from
five East
African Community (EAC) countries and found a positive economic growth rate
measured as real
gross domestic product impact of exports. Asiedu (2013) have applied the ARDL
analysis to investi-
gate the relationship between trade liberalization and economic growth in Ghana.
Asiedu (2013)
ment hurts growth while insignificant positive growth affects the inflation rate.
https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/
10419/270066/1/10.1080_23322039.2021.1911767.pdf
23
23
differed extensively from year to year. It is possible that there are other factors which may
explain the decrease. The declining import does imply that these countries have reduced their
own export to South Africa since the EU-SA FTA was implemented. The import from Angola
has increased with remarkable 756 percent and import from Tanzania and Zambia has also
increased substantially. These figures prove that these three countries have not been affected
negatively by the agreement. South Africa has also increased its import from Botswana and
Lesotho. Their import from Lesotho has increased considerably (3365 percent) but the total
value of the purchased goods is only 1074 thousand Rands in 2004. South Africa purchases
mainly natural and cultured pearls from this country.56
Figure 5.2 demonstrates South Africa’s total exports and imports with the African countries. It
shows that exports have declined since 2002. It is possible that this negative trend is due to
the declining exports to the SACU countries. The total imports have nevertheless increased
since the implementation of the EU-SA FTA. It means that these countries have increased
their exports to South Africa.
FIGURE 5.2: South Africa’s Total Export and Import with African Countries in Billion Rands
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
Export Import
Source: The South African Department of Trade and Industry
56 The South African Department of Trade and Industry:
http://www.thedti.gov.za/econdb/raportt/rapmenu1.html (050517)
24
24
5.3.2 America, Asia and the Pacific
The empirical evidence of America, Asia and the Pacific is limited to several countries, which
are in some respects important for South Africa. The selected Asian countries are China,
Japan, India, Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand. The three last mentioned countries represent
the most developed countries in the AFTA 57 agreement. America is represented by the
NAFTA 58 countries which are Canada, Mexico and USA. South Africa’s trade with these
countries is relatively large and therefore important to investigate. Australia represents the
Pacific and it illustrates trade with this part of the world. Table 5.4 demonstrates South
Africa’s export to and import from these countries between 1999 and 2004.
TABLE 5.4: The Percentage Change of South Africa’s Trade with Asia, America and the
Pacific in Thousand Rands
Country Export Import
1999 2004 %-
increase59
1999 2004 %-
increase60
Australia 2.677.484 7.157.620 167 3.277.803 7.247.278 121
Cananda 1.282.885 2.345.792 83 1.149.838 2.021.875 76
China 1.657.646 6.580.392 297 5.010.606 23.021.153 359
India 2.362.443 3.713.043 57 1.512.306 4.547.261 201
Indonesia 781.310 1.070.972 37 1.164.790 1.986.812 71
Japan 11.236.396 26.601.871 138 11.434.740 20.942.096 83
Malaysia 749.960 1.749.677 133 1.781.860 3.793.912 113
Mexico 625.961 824.759 32 296.387 708.251 139
Thailand 1.176.422 2.577.869 119 1.494.548 4.261.537 185
USA 16.947.665 29.990.930 77 20.228.213 25.970.404 28
Source: The South African Department of Trade and Industry
Table 5.4 demonstrates that South Africa has increased its export to all listed countries.
Exports to China have increased by 297 percent and exports to Australia, Japan, Malaysia,
and Thailand have each increased over 100 percent. The export to the Asian countries has
57 AFTA stands for the “ASEAN Free Trade Area”. AFTA constitutes of ten Asian countries
and they have
eliminated tariffs, quantitative restrictions and other non-tariff barriers towards each other.
ASEAN:http://www.aseansec.org/viewpdf.asp?file=/pdf/afta.pdf (050506)
58 NAFTA stands for the “North American Free Trade Agreement”. The agreement was
implemented in January
1994 and the object is to eliminate tariffs towards each other.
Anne O. Krueger (1999) p. 3
59 (Export2004 ⁄ Export1999 ─ 1) × 100 = percentage export change
60 (Import2004 ⁄ Import1999 ─ 1) × 100 = percentage import change
25
25
improved more than the export to the NAFTA countries. South Africa’s imports from this part
of the world have also increased which is illustrated in table 5.4. They mainly import products
from the United States and the percentage increase between 1999 and 2004 is 28 percent. This
increase is small compared to the increase of China which is 359 percent. South Africa’s
export from and import to China, Australia, Malaysia, and Thailand has each increased by
over 100 percent. Only two European countries experienced this (Austria and Spain). The
positive export and import trend indicates that this part of the world has not been negatively
affected by the free trade agreement.61
Figure 5.3 and 5.4 illustrates South Africa’s export and import with Asia, Australia, and
NAFTA between 1998 and 2004.
FIGURE 5.3: South Africa’s Export to Asia, Australia and NAFTA
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
Asia Australia NAFTA
Source: The South African Department of Trade and Industry
61 The South African Department of Trade and Industry:
http://www.thedti.gov.za/econdb/raportt/rapmenu1.html (050517)
26
26
FIGURE 5.4: South Africa’s Import from Asia, Australia and NAFTA
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
Asia Australia NAFTA
Source: The South African Department of Trade and Industry
27
27
5.4 European Union’s Trade with South Africa and the Rest of the World
It is interesting to investigate whether the European Union’s trade with South Africa and the
rest of the world has changed since the implementation of the free trade agreement. However,
this discussion will be brief since the main focus in the paper is put on South Africa’s trade
and its changes. Figure 5.5 below illustrates how the export from and import to South Africa
has changed between 2000 and 2004. From this figure it is possible to argue that the export to
South Africa has increased.
FIGURE 5.5: European Union’s Export and Import with South Africa in Billion Euros62
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
Export Import
Source: European Union 63
Figure 5.6 and 5.7 illustrates the European Union’s export to and import from Asia64 ,
Africa,65 and the United States. Exports to Africa have increased by about 27 percent between
1999 and 2003. During the same time exports to Asia have increased by about 31 percent. The
export to the United States has increased since 1999 but it started to decline again in 2002.66
62 The European Union’s trade with South Africa constitutes of all twenty five member states.
Statistics only for
the fifth teen member states are unavailable.
63 EUROPEAN UNION: http://trade-info.cec.eu.int/doclib/docs/2005/july/tradoc_113447.pdf
(050628)
64 Asia comprises: China, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, Thailand and Taiwan. Further
information is
unavailable.
65 Africa also includes the Caribbean and the Pacific countries. Detailed information about each
African;
Caribbean and Pacific countries are not available.
66 EUROSTAT:
http://epp.eurostat.cec.eu.int/portal/page?
_pageid=1996,39140985&_dad=portal&_schema=PORTAL&screen=d
etailref&language=en&product=Yearlies_new_external_trade&root=Yearlies_new_external_tra
de/F/F3/dcb192
16 (050627)
28
28
FIGURE 5.6: European Union’s Export to the Rest of the World in Billion Euros
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
Africa Asia USA
Source: Eurostat
Imports from Africa have increased by 33 percent between 1999 and 2003. This result is
preferential for this part of the world because it suggests that their exports to the European
Union have increased. Figure 5.7 demonstrates that the import from the United States has
decreased by 6 percent between 1999 and 2003 and the import from Asia has neither
increased nor decreased during this time period. However, the import has at some stages
varied from both Asia and America.67
FIGURE 5.7: European Union’s Import from the Rest of the World in Billion Euros
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
Africa Asia USA
Source: Eurostat
67 EUROSTAT:
http://epp.eurostat.cec.eu.int/portal/page?
_pageid=1996,39140985&_dad=portal&_schema=PORTAL&screen=d
etailref&language=en&product=Yearlies_new_external_trade&root=Yearlies_new_external_tra
de/F/F3/dcb192
16 (050627)
29
29
Conclusion
The empirical evidence suggests that South Africa’s exports to the European Union have
increased by 75 percent and their imports have increased by 93 percent between 1999 and
2004. These positive figures imply that South Africa has benefited from the agreement. This
increase also suggests that trade creation has taken place. This argument is in line with the
results from Lewis, Robinson, and Thierfelder (2000) and Jachia and Teljeur (1999) studies.
Nevertheless, it is not possible through this paper to state the value of the trade creation. In
their study, Jachia and Teljeur (1999) also argues that the impact of the agreement leads to
uneven figures in exports and imports for South Africa where imports are expected to be
bigger than the exports. Their result agrees with the outcome of this paper’s empirical
evidence.
On the basis of the results from the empirical evidence it is possible to conclude that there has
been improved trade between the European Union and South Africa. The founders of the free
trade agreement were aiming for this positive outcome. However, it is important to remember
that trade does improve even if there are no free trade agreements implemented. An
interesting angle to the discussion is if the trade between South Africa and the European
Union would have increased even if the two parties never had signed the agreement. I argue
that the trade would have increased between the two parties in the absent of an agreement but
not as much as it has with the agreement. I argue this because of the natural rate of the trade’s
development. The tariff liberalization has in my point of view given the two parties a further
reason to trade more with each other because of the new and improved trade conditions.
South Africa’s trade with the SACU countries fluctuates a great deal from year to year. This
event complicates the possibilities to conclude the impacts of the agreement for the SACU
countries. It is possible to argue that these countries have been negatively affected by the
agreement when considering the negative percentage changes between 1999 and 2004. In the
article by Lewis, Robinson, and Thierfelder (2003) it is argued that some SADC countries are
hurt by the agreement while others benefit from it (the SACU countries are included in the
SADC region). There might be a possibility that the SACU countries represent the countries
that are negatively affected by the agreement. For instance, the percentage changes in exports
to and imports from Namibia and Swaziland have both been negative. This may indicate trade
diversion at their expense. However, it seems that the EU-SA FTA may explain some parts of
30
30
the negative trend for these countries but since no linear negative trend exists there might be
other factors that can explain this event. For most of the Southern African countries (Angola,
Congo, Mauritius, Seychelles, Tanzania, Zambia and Zimbabwe) both the exports and the
imports have been positive. This is a sign of that trade diversion has not been at their expense.
South Africa’s trade with America, Asia and Australia does not provide any negative
percentage changes. However, these positive changes might have been greater if the EU-SA
FTA had never been imposed.
The European Union’s trade with Africa, Asia and the United States has increased since the
free trade agreement was implemented. However, the European Union’s imports from the
United States have decreased by 6 percent. In their article, Jachia and Teljeur (1999) write
that trade diversion towards the European Union mostly takes place at the expense of Japan
and the United States. This decrease in imports may be a sign of that trade diversion. The
European Union’s trade with Africa has shown a slightly positive trend in both imports and
exports. For instance Thurlow and Holden (2002) concluded that the impact of the EU-SA
FTA on COMESA’s export to the European Union would be small. Since the European
Union’s exports to and import from South Africa only consists of respectively 0.5 and 0.6
percent, it is difficult to imagine that the EU-SA FTA affects the European Union’s trade
pattern to a great extend.
The tariff liberalization does imply that the government of South Africa and the European
Union receive less revenue from tariffs. It also implies that the producer surplus for both
parties has decreased and that the consumer surplus has increased. This is good for the
inhabitants in South Africa and the European Union. Even with the loss of tariff revenues and
the fall in producer surplus, I consider that the liberalization is preferential for South Africa. It
gives them, for example, a greater opportunity to take advantage of the European Union’s
more advanced technology. It is good if South Africa purchases these commodities from the
European Union since they experience comparative advantages in this area.
The impact of the EU-SA Free Trade Agreement has so far been beneficial for South Africa
in terms of improved trade. The trade with the rest of the world has not been affected by the
agreement to a great extent. Nevertheless, some SACU countries have shown negative signs.
The trade agreement is so far not fully implemented and the trade pattern might differ from
the one today at the end of the transitional period.
https://www.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:130505/FULLTEXT01.pdf
Research
Research for the World
Economics
Race Equity
Economics, Race Equity
Share on X
Share by emailSubscription
Share on LinkedIn
Share by reddit
Download Understanding African trade PDF
Share on Facebook
Africa is currently home to 1.3 billion people, a figure projected to rise to 2.75 billion by 2060
when the continent is forecast to have a combined annual output of $16 trillion and an
increasingly middle-class market. And yet, although the continent will, in just 40 years, have a
market with more people than India and China combined, there is little mainstream discussion of
its trading practices and partnerships.
It is this gap that Professor David Luke, Professor in Practice and Strategic Director of the Firoz
Lalji Institute for Africa at LSE, aims to address in his new book, How Africa Trades, published
by LSE Press in Spring 2023.
Is African trade underperforming?
How can we boost trade flows inside and outside the continent to create more jobs and further
development? This film explores the recent history of African trade and what needs to change.
A specialist in African trade policy, and former head of the African Trade Policy Centre at the
UN Economic Commission for Africa, Professor Luke’s aim is three-fold. “First, to demystify
African trade policy and promote a deeper and broader understanding of how trade impacts the
lives of ordinary Africans and the continent’s development aspirations. Second, to provide up-to-
date information that is easily reachable through open access publication on Africa’s trade data,
trade negotiations, trade agreements and policy priorities, with analysis for clarity. And third, to
empower policymakers, stakeholders, scholars, and others to interrogate the effectiveness of
trade agreements and policy choices including the implementation dimensions from a normative
perspective that is pro-development, inclusive and gives precedence to overcoming pervasive
poverty on the continent”.
“My experience in the UN”, he continues, “was that people in development seem reluctant to
talk about trade, which is seen as too technical, something of an esoteric specialisation. I found
this to be strange, because at the same time, policymakers in Africa and development partners
are talking about private sector reform, competitiveness, investment, jobs, livelihoods, the
wellbeing of people, and so on. But trade - what makes it all happen - is somewhat left out of the
picture.”
One reason for this, Professor Luke believes, is that development in the sense of the inclusive,
sustained transformation of economies is marginalised in the traditional academic disciplines that
focus on trade policy such as international economics, international relations and international
law, while development studies disciplines marginalise trade policy. “Expertise at the moment is
very siloed - looking at different aspects of trade, but not really pulling it all together to get a
coherent picture on trade and development,” he explains. “But if you're looking at the poorest
continent – Africa - you need to understand all these different aspects - the trade agreements, the
border and behind the border issues, the economics of trade, political dynamics, formal and
informal trade and how trade interacts with development – and so that was the motivation behind
the book.”
To understand “how Africa trades”, the researchers first looked at what Africa trades, accessing
data from a range of sources including the IMF, UNCTAD, the World Bank, and sources of
usually unrecorded informal cross-border trade to uncover the composition of Africa’s trade in
goods and services within and outside the continent. Interrogating what that trade means in turn
took the work to the voices of African diplomats, ambassadors at the World Trade Organization
(WTO), negotiators, civil society activists, lobbyists and policymakers.
What Africa trades is as important as who it trades with
Analysis of the data revealed a detailed picture of trading relationships with African countries,
both between themselves and the rest of the world. While the EU is Africa’s biggest trading
partner, followed by China and then intra-African trade, the researchers also examined Africa’s
trade with the US, UK and emerging economies such as India, Brazil and Turkey. The findings
are instructive for those seeking to develop trading partnerships with the continent.
“We first looked at what Africa trades and found a clear difference in the type of trade being
carried out between African countries and with the rest of the world,” explains Professor Luke.
“Trade with the rest of the world in goods is mainly commodities, and in services, mainly
tourism, while intra-African trade - the trade between African countries - is more diversified in
value-added goods such as manufactures and processed food and services such as transport
services, financial services, business services etc. But intra-African trade is small accounting for
only 18 per cent of Africa’s total trade. We found that over 60 per cent of this trade, although
small, is diversified while Africa’s trade with the rest of the world is about 80 per cent
commodities, with a heavy concentration in minerals and fossil fuels.”
“In fact, manufactures”, he continues, “are the largest type of export between African countries –
accounting for 45 per cent of all formal intra-African trade. Foodstuff exports are also more
significant, amounting to a fifth of trade between African countries. These 'formal' figures miss
some of Africa’s trade which flows across contiguous borders informally and unrecorded. Recent
estimates are that such informal trade flows account for the equivalent of between 7 and 16 per
cent of formal intra-African trade flows. Much of that comprises foods and basic consumer
goods. Informal trade is an expression of pervasive poverty and tends to be skewed towards
women.”
The problem with this type of partnership is one of trade diversion - it can potentially displace
goods that Africa can produce itself, which is something we’re already seeing
Investment data were also found to be a mirror of the trade statistics. The investment stock of the
three largest economies, the US, China and the EU revealed an excessive concentration in
mining and extractive sectors associated with fuels and metals that is not representative of their
investments elsewhere in the world. This matters, Professor Luke explains, because commodities
tend to be subjected to extreme price volatility, liable to rent seeking and elite capture, and the
extraction of value through illicit financial flows. “Commodities create less jobs,” he adds.
“Mining, for example, uses a lot of capital equipment, but doesn’t need that many people.
Whereas, when you are producing things, agriculture, processing agriculture, and so on, you are
creating more jobs. This has huge implications for development and the workforce. In agriculture
in particular, we find that there are more women involved in processing food, while
manufacturing can create jobs for African youth”.
“It's important to link jobs to trade, especially in the African case,” he adds “because the
demographics suggest that, currently, Africa has around 252 million youth (aged 15-24 years)
that need to be absorbed in productive activities. The demographic issue is very important to
relate, both to development, and in terms of how trade impacts the economy, creates jobs,
incomes, and so on.”
Further, the trading relationships between Africa and the rest of the world were found to be
asymmetrical – with Africa exporting basic commodities and importing mainly manufactured
goods. “The problem with this type of partnership is one of trade diversion - it can potentially
displace goods that Africa can produce itself, which is something we’re already seeing,”
continues Professor Luke.
These asymmetrical trading partnerships therefore leave Africa at a disadvantage, Professor Luke
argues, with countries with a stronger manufacturing base trading with Africa with its own
weaker manufacturing base and displacing what they can produce.
On top of this, some major trading partners, especially the EU, have different trade agreements
with African countries depending on whether they are north of the Sahara or south of the Sahara,
developing or least developed. This creates a hard border for trade with the EU between African
countries, which undermines Africa’s own efforts to establish common trade rules across the
continent, and disincentivises the emergence of supply chains between African countries. The
UK, by copying the EU’s approach after Brexit, has not made this problem any easier, says
Professor Luke, who last year submitted evidence to the UK’s All-Party Parliamentary Group on
Africa.
Intra-Africa trade is more diverse and can drive Africa’s
transformation
Common trade rules across the continent is key for tapping into the enormous size of the
collective African market, building upon its potential for further diversification, attracting
investors in non-traditional sectors, and achieving competitive economies of scale. This is part of
the rationale of the African Continental Free Trade Area (AfCFTA) Agreement that entered into
force under African Union auspices in 2019. “You always trade with your neighbours because
trade costs are lower, so this is a principle that has existed throughout time,” says Professor
Luke.
“If fully implemented,” he adds, “liberalised trade on the African continent offers an incentive
for the restructuring of African economies through diversification, agricultural and industrial
development. The trade deal offers a framework for continent-wide reforms to bring trade costs
down, undertake border reforms and foster institutions and practices of modern trade
governance.” Economic modelling suggests the deal could be worth as much as $450 billion for
the continent by 2045. The biggest prize, he explains, is that the trade deal offers African
countries a credible pathway to follow the play book of successful development experiences in
countries that attained rapid transformation and diminished levels of poverty within a few
decades through carefully designed trade policy interventions, effective institutions and other
economic and social policy reforms.
External and internal hurdles
Professor Luke foresees two hurdles that need to be addressed for the trade deal to be successful:
one external to Africa and the other internal. The external hurdle is the need for Africa’s trade
partners to offer a trade deal that minimises the risk of trade diversion – the displacement of
good and services that can be produced in Africa. The internal hurdle is for African policymakers
and stakeholders to ensure implementation of the AfCFTA, to sustain border and behind the
border reforms, and for Africa to speak with one voice when negotiating with bilateral partners
or at a global forum such as the WTO.
“In the book we argue that the United States Growth and Opportunity Act (AGOA), a trade
concession to sub-Saharan African countries that was enacted during the Clinton Administration
and has since provided a policy framework for Africa’s trade with the US – with bipartisan
support that transcends the dysfunctionality of US politics - is the model to follow. AGOA is not
perfect and even the US recognises the need to overcome its bureaucratic division between North
Africa and sub-Saharan Africa and to buttress it with complementary investment and trade
facilitation initiatives. We suggest ways in which AGOA could be reformed. But AGOA
provides African countries with breathing space as it does not require reciprocal market access as
the EU (and UK) trade agreements do or China which offers minimal trade concessions. What is
more, the US successfully obtained a waiver from the WTO to discriminate in this way in favour
of African countries.”
He argues that if external market access is secured for Africa’s exports without the need for
reciprocity, it incentivises African countries to seek trade opportunities with each other and
mitigates the risks of trade diversion. Economic modelling evidence is cited in the book to show
that after full implementation of the AfCFTA, gains for Africa would essentially be concentrated
in intra-African trade which could see an increase of up to 33.8 per cent by 2045, as compared to
a baseline without the AfCFTA. Yet what is most significant is where these gains would be, with
manufacturing and Africa’s long-overdue industrialisation benefiting most. “This data-driven
projection may be considered to be a judicious timeframe for a transitional period that allows a
sequencing of AfCFTA implementation followed by reciprocal market access,” he suggests.
“This will help African countries to build productive capacities and achieve their potential for
strong and diversified growth in intra-African trade with inclusive and transformational
consequences.”
...African countries should work together in their bilateral partnerships and at the WTO.
As regards the internal hurdles, the key, Professor Luke argues, will be to build and sustain
political coalitions for implementation of the AfCFTA and trade reforms. There is already strong
political momentum behind the deal with all but one (Eritrea) of the members of the African
Union being signatories. COVID-19 threw unprecedented economic difficulties upon the
continent, yet despite this the AfCFTA has retained and even built upon attention as a tool for
transforming Africa. But implementation remains a hurdle. In recognition of this, the African
Union decided to name the year 2023 the year of accelerated AfCFTA implementation.
When it comes to speaking with one voice, experience has shown that African countries are
vulnerable to being outmanoeuvred in trade negotiations and in their engagement with their
better resourced trade partners. In geo-economics and geo-politics, individual African countries
lack influence on their own to achieve meaningful outcomes that impact their development
prospects.
“When we looked at the WTO,” Professor Luke continues, “we found that African countries are
somewhat disadvantaged, because, altogether, their share of world trade is only about 2 per cent
– which is another reason why in there is a need to rethink these current asymmetrical
relationships.”
Because African trade shares are so small and so highly concentrated in commodities, they tend
not to use the WTO for dispute settlement, he explains: “However, even if they did, the result
would be like shooting themselves in the foot, because although WTO rules would allow them to
reciprocate - to inflict some trade-related pain on the other country – their trade is so small that
this would have no impact.”
He continues: “so, we analysed the data to show that for all the disputes at the WTO, the African
countries really have been bystanders. We are also able to show that, and even on the
negotiations side, many of the proposals that the Africans bring forward as ways to rebalance
some of the rules to make them more development-friendly have not gone anywhere.”
“A major internal hurdle to overcome,” he notes “is that the African countries should work
together in their bilateral partnerships and at the WTO. The African Union Commission has no
mandate to negotiate on behalf of African countries. The book recommends that this should
change”. Looking to the future, one of the emerging issues that will impact how Africa trades
concerns initiatives to decarbonise economies and the role that border adjustment measures can
play in reducing the risk of carbon leakage. “It is essential that from this early stage, African
countries are able to shape new global rules on trade and climate. They will only be able to do so
if they act together,” he says.
“The stakes are high,” he concludes. A reliable revenue stream from trade is critical for
development finance and sustainable debt management. Transforming how Africa trades will
unlock structural changes in African economies that have proved elusive so far.
Professor David Luke was speaking to Jess Winterstein, Deputy Head of Media Relations at LSE
How Africa Trades edited by Professor David Luke is published by LSE Press. Read a review on
the LSE Review of Books.
Explore our dedicated hub showcasing LSE research and commentary on the UK economy.
Share on X
Share by emailSubscription
Share on LinkedIn
Share by reddit
Download Understanding African trade PDF
Share on Facebook
Related articles
Recommended reads for understanding the economy today
16 Nov 2023•3 min read
Can asset transfers help women in extreme poverty?
20 Oct 2023•6 min read
Topics
Africadevelopmentinequalitypolicytrade
Trending articles
https://www.lse.ac.uk/research/research-for-the-world/economics/understanding-african-trade-is-
key-to-helping-its-development