Chapter 10
Chapter 10
DRAFT 1
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 2
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
1. Measure the income share (percent of all income) held by various groups
ordered by income from poorest to richest, such as the bottom 20 percent, the
middle 20 percent, the top 1 percent, etc.
2. Measure the overall distribution of income in a society, using mathematical and
graphical techniques.
Using these data, we can now construct several measures of inequality based
on the ratios of the income share of one group compared to another group. One
common measure is the ratio of the income share of the richest fifth to that of the
poorest fifth of the population; in this case, we obtain 52.2/3.0 = 17.4—that is,
households in the richest quintile have over 17 times the income, on average, of
households in the poorest quintile. We can then see how this ratio has changed over
time to track changes in inequality. For example, in 1980 this ratio was only about 10,
indicating an increase in the spread between the richest and poorest fifth of the
population. The U.S. Census Bureau publishes various ratios based on the incomes
DRAFT 3
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
at different percentiles of the distribution, such as the 90th/10th ratio, the 95th/20th
ratio, and the 80th/50th ratio. Again, these can be tracked over time to determine how
inequality has changed.
Lorenz curve: a line used to portray an income distribution, drawn on a graph with
percentiles of households on the horizontal axis and the cumulative percentage of
income on the vertical axis
We use the data in Table 10.1 to draw the Lorenz curve in Figure 10.1. Point A
represents the fact that the poorest 20 percent of households received 3.0 percent of
all income. To obtain point B, we need to calculate the cumulative percent of income
received by the bottom 40 percent of households. So, we add the income received by
the bottom 20 percent to the income received by the next 20 percent. Thus the
cumulative percent of income received by the bottom 40 percent is 3.0 + 8.1 = 11.1
percent of total income. For point C, we need to calculate the cumulative percent of
income received by the bottom 60 percent of households, which is 3.0 + 8.1 + 14.0 =
25.1 percent of total income. Similarly, point D shows that the income share of the
bottom 80 percent is 47.8 percent of all income. Finally, point E shows that the bottom
95 percent received 77.0 percent of all income (everyone except the top 5 percent).
The Lorenz curve must start at the origin, at the lower-left corner of the graph (because
0 percent of households have 0 percent of the total income) and must end at point F
in the upper right corner (because 100 percent of households must have 100 percent
of the total income).
The Lorenz curve provides information about the degree of income inequality
in a country. Note that the 45-degree line in Figure 10.1 represents a situation of
absolute equality. If every household had exactly the same income, then, for example,
the “bottom” 40 percent of households would receive 40 percent of all income. This is
shown by point G in Figure 10.1. Imagine the other extreme—a situation in which one
household received all the income in a country. In this case, the Lorenz curve would
be a flat line along the horizontal axis at a value of zero until the very end, where it
would suddenly shoot up to 100 percent of income (at point F).
Of course these two extremes do not occur in reality, but they infer that the
closer a country’s Lorenz curve is to the 45-degree line, the more equal its income
distribution. This is illustrated in Figure 10.2, which shows the Lorenz curve for four
countries: Brazil, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United States. Income is
distributed relatively equally in Sweden; its Lorenz curve is closest to the 45-degree
line of absolute equality. Brazil has one of the most unequal income distributions— we
DRAFT 4
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
see its Lorenz curve bows far from the line of equality. We can also conclude that
economic inequality is higher in the U.S. than in the U.K.
Thus the more the Lorenz curve bows away from the line of absolute equality,
the greater is the extent of inequality in the income distribution. This observation led a
statistician by the name of Corrado Gini to introduce a numerical measure of inequality
that came to be known as the Gini ratio (or “Gini coefficient”), which is defined as
the ratio of the area between the Lorenz curve and the diagonal line of equality to the
total area under the diagonal line.
Figure 10.2. Lorenz Curves for Brazil, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the
United States
Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators database. Data are for 2018, except for
the United Kingdom (2017).
DRAFT 5
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Referring to areas A and B in Figure 10.3, the Gini ratio is A/(A+B). Clearly, the
Gini ratio can vary from 0 for absolute equality (since in such a case area A would
equal zero as the Lorenz curve overlaps the line of absolute equality) to 1 for absolute
inequality (where area B would equal zero). According to U.S. Census Bureau
calculations, the Gini ratio for U.S. household income in 2020 was 0.489. We will
present international comparisons of inequality, along with data trends, later in the
chapter.
Gini ratio (or Gini coefficient): a measure of inequality, based on the Lorenz curve,
that goes from 0 (absolute equality) up to 1 (absolute inequality). Greater inequality
shows up as a larger area between the Lorenz curve and the diagonal line of absolute
equality
Note that the definition of income used for the data in Table 10.1 is pre-tax
income excluding the value of noncash government benefits such as food assistance
and Medicare, and also excluding the value of employer-provided benefits such as
health care. How might the Gini coefficient change if we defined income differently?
Higher-income people, after all, pay more in taxes, so perhaps we should look instead
at disposable income after taxes. Meanwhile, poor people may qualify for noncash
programs such as food assistance, or for subsidized housing and medical care, and
arguably the value of these programs should be included as part of income.
On the basis of considerations like these, the U.S. Census Bureau has
experimented with at least 15 different definitions of income. In addition to the
definition used in Table 10.1, another definition is meant to approximate what the
distribution of income would be if—hypothetically—the impact of government activity
were excluded. For this definition, the Census Bureau starts with pre-tax income and
subtracts government cash transfers (such as welfare payments). Then it adds the
value of employer-provided health insurance benefits, generally received by workers
with higher incomes. Under this definition, the Gini ratio, not surprisingly, rises,
showing greater inequality. The share of income received by the bottom fifth drops
considerably, while the share of the top fifth rises.
DRAFT 6
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Adjusting income for the effects of the tax system mainly lowers incomes at the
top, though as we will see in the next chapter all households pay taxes to some extent.
When the Census Bureau further adds in the effects of noncash government transfer
programs such as food assistance and Medicare, the distribution becomes somewhat
less unequal.
Discussion Questions
1 What are some of the differences between inequality of income and inequality of
“capabilities” or well-being? How are these three concepts related? Which one do
you think deserves the most attention from policymakers?
2 What do you think is the minimal amount of annual income that an individual, or a
small family, would need to live in your community? (Think about the rent or
mortgage on a one- or two-bedroom residence, etc.) What does this probably mean
about where the average level of income in your community fits into the U.S. income
distribution shown in Table 10.1?
DRAFT 7
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 8
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 9
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
capital gains: increase in the value of an asset at the time it is sold compared to the
price at which it was originally purchased by the same owner
Just as income inequality has been increasing in recent decades, so has wealth
inequality. A plot of the wealth shares owned by the top groups in the United States
over time looks much like the income shares in Figure 10.5. According to one study,
the share of national wealth owned by the top 1 percent was over 50 percent prior to
the Great Depression, declined to less than 25 percent by the late 1970s, but then
steadily increased to around 45 percent more recently.15
Contemplating such vast wealth inequality brings us back to the question of
opportunity. Do those with little or even negative wealth have the opportunity to
achieve an adequate level of well-being? In addition, great wealth often confers upon
its owners both economic and political power. When the ownership of wealth is highly
uneven, the ability to direct the operations of businesses and to influence government
policy through campaign contributions and the like may become concentrated in the
hands of relatively few. They may then use this power to maintain or exacerbate
existing inequalities. We return to this point again later in the chapter.
DRAFT 10
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Figure 10.7. Actual, Estimated, and Ideal Distribution of Wealth in the United
States
DRAFT 11
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 12
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Economic inequalities based on race, age, and other demographic factors are
even more pronounced when we consider household wealth. Figure 10.9 presents
data on the median value of household assets for different types of households.18 In
some cases, we can see how inequalities arising due to differences in income are
magnified when it comes to wealth. While white households’ incomes are 63 percent
higher than the incomes of black households, the assets of white households are more
than 13 times higher than those of black households. Hispanic households also have
little in assets, only about $32,000. The median value of household assets tends to
rise with age. So while older households (aged 65 and older) have relatively low
income as seen in Figure 10.8, they have comparatively high assets. While married
couples have incomes nearly twice as high as households with just one adult, their
assets are more than 6 times larger. We also see that education has a significant
impact on household assets. For example, those with a college degree have nearly
five times as much household wealth as those with only a high school diploma. Finally,
those owning their own homes (including those still paying a mortgage) have 75 times
the assets of renters. This demonstrates the importance of real estate equity in
building household wealth.
Economic inequality is also evident in the United States beyond the categories
currently considered by the Census Bureau. For example, households with one or
more disabled members (someone with ambulatory, vision, cognitive, or other
difficulties) are more likely than other households to face income poverty and have
over 40 percent less in household assets.19 Similarly, individuals that identify as
lesbian, gay, bisexual, or transgender (LGBT) are more likely to face income poverty
and have lower assets than those that identify as straight. LGBT adults were twice as
likely to report that they experienced discrimination in 2019 than non-LGBT adults.20
DRAFT 13
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Meanwhile, people raised in families from the top quintile are 47 percent likely to also
be in the top quintile as adults, with about 25 percent in the fourth quintile and 7 percent
falling all the way to the bottom quintile. So while some economic mobility exists, one’s
background is clearly an important determinant of one’s adult income. A 2015 study
summarized the situation:
[C]hildren raised in low-income families will probably have very low incomes as
adults, while children raised in high-income families can anticipate very high
incomes as adults. The differences are extreme: The expected income of
children raised in well-off families (90th percentile) is about 200 percent larger
than the expected income of children raised in poor families (10th percentile)
and about 75 percent larger than that of children raised in middle-class families
(50th percentile).22
Figure 10.9. Median Value of Household Assets in the United States by Select
Characteristics, 2019
Source: U.S. Census Bureau, Wealth, Asset Ownership, and Debt of Households
Detailed Tables: 2019. Table 1.
DRAFT 14
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Table 10.2. Probability of Earning More than One’s Parents, United States
Decade Born Low-Income Parents Middle-Income Parents High-Income Parents
1940s 95% 93% 41%
1950s 90% 81% 15%
1960s 86% 62% 7%
1970s 90% 59% 16%
1980s 79% 45% 8%
Source: Lu, 2020.
Discussion Questions
1 Were your parents better off economically than their parents? Do you believe that
you will be better off than your parents? Do you think that this is true of most of your
friends?
DRAFT 15
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
2 Make a list of the reasons that inequality can be considered desirable, and the ways
in which inequality hurts social well-being. Is it possible to limit the negative
consequences of inequality while still harnessing the positive aspects?
DRAFT 16
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
declined during this period, and it increased for 40 countries. While this suggests that
national-level inequality has remained about constant, on average, it fails to account
for differences in population across countries. Between 1990 and 2015 the Gini
coefficient increased in each of the world’s five most populous countries: China, India,
the United States, Indonesia, and Pakistan. The increase in inequality was particularly
high in China, with its Gini coefficient rising from 0.35 to 0.50. India’s Gini coefficient
also increase substantially, from 0.30 to 0.35. Thus, we can conclude that more people
are living in countries where inequality has been increasing rather than decreasing.
As we saw previously for the United States, wealth tends to be more unevenly
distributed than income. Figure 10.11 presents the wealth Gini coefficients for select
countries. National wealth Gini coefficients range from 0.52 in Iceland to 0.91 in the
Bahamas.
DRAFT 17
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 18
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
As mentioned at the start of the chapter, the COVID-19 pandemic most likely
increased global income inequality, and it clearly increased the number of people living
in absolute poverty. However, analysis by Nobel Prize-winning economist Angus
Deaton shows that the impact of the pandemic on global inequality has been
comparatively small.37 The percentage decline in GDP per capita due to the pandemic
has generally been larger in high-income nations than in low-income nations, with
India being the major exception. In fact, Deaton concludes that global income
inequality would have continued to decline even during the pandemic except for the
significant reduction of economic growth in India. However, it is unclear what the
longer-term impacts of the pandemic will be on global inequality.
Considering the broad trend of declining global inequality in recent decades,
how can the Gini coefficient for most countries be increasing while the global Gini
coefficient is declining? Essentially, the growth of the global middle class is reducing
global inequality even as it increases national-level inequality in many countries.
Consider that several decades ago nearly all people in China and India— the world’s
two most populous countries—had very low incomes by global standards. Recent
economic growth in these countries has increased national-level inequality,
specifically between relatively high incomes in urban areas and the still-low incomes
in rural areas. But economic growth in these two countries has led to a surge in the
number of people classified in the global middle class. This emerging global middle
class is reducing global inequality.
We can see evidence of this shift in Figure 10.12, which shows the global
distribution of income in 1980 and 2020. Note that this income distribution graph is
different from our Lorenz curve graphs, as the y-axis shows shares of the world’s
population at various income levels, and the x-axis presents income levels using a
nonlinear scale. In 1980 we see a distribution with two “peaks”: one around $1,000 per
person per year and another around $15,000. Thus there were two large
concentrations of people in 1980—those who were very poor and those who were
DRAFT 19
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
relatively well-off, with comparatively few people in the middle. But in 2020 we see that
the “valley” has been filled in as the percentage of people with incomes between
$5,000 and $15,000 per year has grown. This largely represents the emerging global
middle class in China, India, and other rapidly developing countries. While relatively
few people were considered middle-class by global standards in 1980, now the global
middle-class has become the dominant group. This corresponds to a dramatic
reduction in the number of people considered poor by global standards—from 44
percent of the world’s population in 1980 to less than 10 percent now, according to the
World Bank.38
Figure 10.13. Median Net Worth per Adult, Select Countries, 2020
DRAFT 20
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
South Korea, and Canada. However, the United States has a high average net worth
of about $500,000 per adult, ranking second globally behind Switzerland. The large
difference between median and average net worth in the U.S. further illustrates its high
degree of wealth inequality; it indicates that a few very wealthy people raise the
average wealth considerably. Median net worth in China is about $24,000 per adult,
which has increased by a factor of twelve between 2000 and 2020. Meanwhile, India’s
median wealth has grown by a factor of four from 2000 to 2020, to $800 per person.
Median net worth in the world’s poorest countries is less than $1,000 per person.
Discussion Questions
1 What do you think are the reasons that the United States is more unequal than other
developed countries, and has lower economic mobility? What policies might be
used to address this issue?
2 What are the main trends in global inequality? Do these seem to be positive or
negative in terms of human well-being?
DRAFT 21
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
use the term, refers not just to rent for housing but to payments for the use of any
capital asset, such as machinery or an e-mail list. (See Box 10.3 on “rent-seeking.”) In
general, higher-income households receive a larger portion of their total income from
capital income. Increases in wealth and income inequality are strongly related to
patterns of capital ownership, with those who have little or no capital failing to capture
economic gains.
labor income: payment to workers, including wages, salaries, and fringe benefits
capital income: rents, profits, and interest
rent: payments for the direct or indirect use of any capital assets
Among developed countries, the labor share of total income has generally been
declining since the 1970s.43 Generally, a declining labor share over time suggests that
wage growth, if present, is not keeping up with overall productivity growth. Real
median wages in the United States, for example, only grew by 11.6 percent from 1979
to 2018—that’s not annual growth, but total growth over 40 years! Meanwhile, real
productivity in the United States grew by 70 percent over this same time period.44 In
other words, there has been significant economic growth, but little of that growth is
going to the average worker.
The critical question is why this has been happening, and on this there is no
universal agreement. In what follows, we consider the four most prominent
explanations for the increase in income inequality in many developed nations:
1. globalization and trade
2. technological changes
DRAFT 22
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 23
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
percent more than those with just a high school degree. But by 2021 this differential
had risen to 67 percent.49
The third likely cause of rising income inequality is the progressive weakening
of labor unions. Government policy in many developed countries has become
decidedly less supportive of unions and low-wage workers, and the rate of union
participation has declined markedly, as discussed in Chapter 9. Recall that labor union
membership in the United States declined from a peak of around 35 percent in the
1950s to only about 11 percent today. Labor union membership has also been falling
recently in Germany, Japan, Sweden, Australia, the United Kingdom, and most other
wealthy nations.50 A 2015 analysis by the International Monetary Fund finds that
weaker unions increase income inequality, but more by fostering higher incomes at
the top rather than depressing wages in the middle.51 A 2021 study of European labor
unions concludes that:
Workers need strong collective mechanisms and bargaining power to
countervail the bargaining power of employers, obtain a fair wage share and
limit wage inequality. … And if union density continues to decline in the great
majority of EU countries and/or bargaining coverage continues to fall in an
important number of them, inequality is bound to continue to increase.52
The final reason proposed to explain rising inequality is that policies have been
instituted that, intentionally or unintentionally, have led to higher inequality. In the
United States there has, for example, been a series of tax cuts—during the 1980s
under Ronald Reagan, during the 2000s under George W. Bush, and during the 2010s
under Donald Trump—that primarily reduced the tax burden on the wealthiest groups
(though some of these tax cuts were reversed during the presidencies of Bill Clinton
and Barack Obama). A 2015 study finds that the income share of the top 1 percent
increased the most in those countries that lowered their top marginal tax rates by the
most percentage points.53
Another policy change has been reduction in support for lower-income workers.
The federal minimum wage in the United States ($7.25 as of 2022) has fallen
significantly behind inflation, lowering the purchasing power of the lowest-income
workers. In addition to the negative effect on minimum wage workers, this trend also
adversely affects other workers’ bargaining power reducing the “floor” against which
other wages are set.
A major problem associated with increased inequality is that those who gain a
greater share of total wealth are able to translate it into greater political power. This
plays out, particularly in the United States, through the system of campaign finance,
in which candidates for political office can accept disproportionate donations from
wealthy individuals or large corporations with an interest in, say, keeping taxes low for
the rich or minimizing regulations on the financial sector. This is another example of
“rent-seeking” activity that does not produce any economic value but, rather,
redistributes it, accentuating other trends towards greater income inequality.
Policy choices also affect the impact of other changes such as globalization.
According to one analysis:
The standard framing presents globalization, like technological process, as an
exogenous force, something that happens to us. In reality, globalization is a
complex process of integrating capital, product, and labor markets, where
almost every characteristic of those newly integrated markets is the subject of,
or should be the subject of, political and regulatory debate. Over the last 30
DRAFT 24
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 25
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Kuznets curve hypothesis: the theory that economic inequality in a country initially
increases during the early stages of economic development, but eventually decreases
with further development
DRAFT 26
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
5. RESPONDING TO INEQUALITY
While there is no consensus regarding the “right” amount of inequality in a society, as
we mentioned at the beginning of the chapter, to many people there is something
disturbing about the current degree of inequality in the United States and other
countries. We now consider what policies might be instituted to respond to inequality.
DRAFT 27
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
One way of reversing the trend toward greater inequality is through the tax
system. By shifting more of the overall tax burden to high-income households, after-
tax income inequality can be reduced. In other words, a more progressive tax system
will, ceteris paribus, reduce a country’s after-tax Gini coefficient. A 2018 analysis by
the International Monetary Fund documents an overall decline in tax progressivity in
OECD countries, particularly in the 1980s and 1990s, that likely contributed to rising
inequality in many countries. The authors conclude that “making a tax system more
progressive does have a real impact on market economy outcomes by reducing
inequality”.69
Given that the United States has the highest income inequality among
developed nations, you may assume that the U.S. has a less progressive tax system
compared to other high-income countries. But according to analysis by the OECD the
United States has one of the most progressive tax systems of any industrialized
country.70 While most European countries have high overall taxes relative to the United
States, their tax systems are rather proportional, largely due to their reliance on value-
added taxes (as we’ll discuss in Chapter 11). In other words, European countries do
not use their tax systems to significantly reduce economic inequality. The tax system
in the United States is slightly progressive overall, mainly due to a highly progressive
federal income tax. As mentioned earlier, a trend toward declining tax progressivity in
recent decades in the United States is partly responsible for increasing inequality.
Another tax policy to reduce inequality is to provide low-income households
with tax credits or rebates. In the United States, the earned income credit, which
provides a tax benefit to lower-income workers, has proven to be effective in reducing
poverty and inequality.71 A 2020 analysis found the tax credit to be particularly effective
at reducing child poverty in the U.S.72
At the other end of the income spectrum, wealth taxes are a highly progressive
form of taxation to address wealth inequality. Four countries, Colombia, Norway,
Spain, and Switzerland, levy annual wealth taxes on high-asset households. For
example, Norway’s wealth tax rate is 0.85 percent assessed on net assets above
about $180,000 for single individuals and $360,000 for married couples. 73 A 2019
analysis argues that wealth taxes can be particularly effective at reducing inequality
related to rent seeking (see Box 10.3), and recommends spending the revenues from
wealth taxes on productivity-enhancing investments such as infrastructure and human
capital.74
Inequality of wages is widespread in developed nations. Considering inequality
based solely on market income—income before any taxes or government benefits—
the United States has a similar Gini coefficient as countries such as France, Germany,
Belgium, and Finland, as shown in Figure 10.14. So why does the United States end
up with a higher Gini coefficient than all other industrialized countries?
While tax systems in European countries aren’t particularly progressive, their
high overall tax rates provide a source of public revenues that can be used to address
inequality. These revenues are used by most European countries to fund a broad
system of transfer programs. Government transfers include social security payments,
the monetary value of medical benefits, unemployment insurance, food subsidies, and
other cash and non-cash benefits. A country’s Gini coefficient based on disposable-
income, which includes adjustments for both taxes and transfers, is the common
metric used to compare income inequality across countries.
DRAFT 28
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
disposable income: income after subtracting all taxes paid from market income, and
then adding the monetary value of cash and non-cash transfers
Figure 10.14 shows how the adjustment for taxes and transfers changes
various countries’ Gini coefficients. We see that only two countries, South Korea and
Switzerland, start off with a market-income Gini coefficient below 0.42. Most countries
rely upon taxes and transfers (but again, primarily transfers), to substantially lower
their final disposable-income Gini coefficient. The length of each country’s arrow
represents the extent to which taxes and transfers lower their Gini coefficient. Belgium,
for example, starts off with a market-income Gini coefficient of 0.49, about the same
as the United States. But after taxes and transfers its disposable-income Gini
coefficient falls to 0.26, a reduction of 0.23 points. The largest Gini coefficient
reduction, 0.25 points, occurs in Finland. The Gini coefficient reduction in the United
States of 0.12 points is among the lowest in the figure. The only two countries that do
less than the United States to reduce inequality through taxes and transfers, South
Korea and Switzerland, start off with a relatively equal distribution of market income.
The policy implication of this analysis is that the countries with the lowest
disposable-income Gini coefficients achieve this not necessarily through an equitable
market-income distribution or highly progressive tax systems, but through substantial
and progressive transfer systems. For example, cash transfers, including old-age,
DRAFT 29
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
universal basic income (UBI): a periodic cash payment to all citizens (or all adult citizens)
regardless of income
DRAFT 30
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 31
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 32
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
discussion of dual labor markets from last chapter). And as more workers shift to jobs
in the “gig economy,” income unpredictability is likely to become a problem for an
increasing share of people, and exacerbate income inequality.95 In Europe, more than
half of all new jobs created since 2010 are based on temporary contracts. 96 Some
countries, including Norway, France, and Sweden, have laws mandating that
employers must provide equal pay and benefits to temporary workers.97
DRAFT 33
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
DRAFT 34
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Discussion Questions
1 Do you generally believe that raising taxes on the rich is an appropriate approach
for reducing economic inequality? What level of taxation on the rich do you think is
fair? (Note that we will also consider this topic in the next chapter.)
2 Do you think the spending priorities of the government should be changed in order
to reduce economic inequality? Beyond the suggestions in the text, can you think
of any other ways that government spending priorities could be changed?
REVIEW QUESTIONS
1. About what share of aggregate income does each quintile of households receive
in the United States?
2. How is a Lorenz curve constructed? What does it measure?
3. What is the Gini coefficient (or ratio)? What does a higher value of the coefficient
signify?
4. What effect do taxes and transfer payments have on the distribution of U.S.
household income?
5. What tends to be more unequal—the distribution of income or wealth? Why?
6. How has income inequality in the United States changed in recent decades?
7. How does income and wealth vary by race?
8. What is economic mobility?
9. How does economic mobility in the United States compare to that in other
industrialized countries?
DRAFT 35
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
10. How does economic inequality in the United States compare to other countries?
11. How is it that the global Gini coefficient for income is higher than the Gini coefficient
for any single country?
12. How is it that the global Gini coefficient is declining but the Gini coefficients in most
countries are increasing?
13. How do median wealth levels in the United States compare to other industrialized
countries?
14. What are the four main reasons proposed to explain growing inequality in the
United States and other developed countries?
15. What is the Kuznets curve hypothesis? Does the research generally support the
theory?
16. What are some of the consequences of inequality?
17. How can tax and transfer policies be used to reduce inequality?
18. What is the difference between market and disposable income?
19. Does economic research generally support the view that increasing the minimum
wage will reduce income inequality?
20. How can government spending policies and other regulations impact inequality?
21. What are some policies that have been effective at reducing income inequality in
developing countries?
EXERCISES
1. Statistics from the World Bank indicate the household income distribution in
Thailand for 2019 was:
Group of Households Share of Aggregate Income
Poorest quintile 7.7%
Second quintile 11.5%
Third quintile 15.7%
Fourth quintile 22.3%
Richest quintile 42.8%
a. Create a carefully labeled Lorenz curve describing this distribution. (Be precise
about the labels on the vertical axis.)
b. Compare this distribution to the distribution in the United States. Would you
expect the Gini ratio for Thailand to be higher, lower, or about the same? Why?
2. You can access the World Bank’s World Development Indicators database online
to download income share data for various countries, and construct Lorenz curves.
Choose two countries you are interested in and construct their Lorenz curves on
the same graph. Note that the WDI database does not have data for all countries,
or for the most recent years. Also, the database provides income shares for the top
and bottom 10 percent, in addition to each quintile—include the data points for the
top and bottom 10 percent in your graph. Which one of your two countries seems
to have a more unequal distribution of income?
DRAFT 36
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Column A Column B
c. Capital gain 3. Income not adjusted for taxes and
transfers
d. Quintile 4. Payments for the use of an asset
e. Labor income 5. A very equal income distribution
f, A Gini ratio close to 1 6. A group containing 20 percent of the
total
g. Disposable income 7. Changes in one’s economic status
over time
h. A Gini ratio close to 0 8. An increase in the value of an asset at
the time of sale
i. Rent 9. Inequality first increases, then
decreases, with development
j. Market income 10. Income adjusted for taxes and
transfers
REFERENCES
Acemoğlu, Darren, and James Robinson. 2017. “The Economic Impact of Colonialism.”
VoxEU-CEPR, January 30. https://voxeu.org/article/economic-impact-colonialism.
Alderman, Liz. 2017. “Feeling ‘Pressure All the Time’ on Europe’s Treadmill of Temporary
Work.” The New York Times, February 9.
Ambrosino, Brandon. 2016. “The Gig Economy Is Coming. You Probably Won’t Like It.”
The Boston Globe Magazine, April 20.
Autor, David H., Alan Manning, and Christopher L. Smith. 2016. “The Contribution of the
Minimum Wage to US Wage Inequality over Three Decades: A Reassessment.”
American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 8(1):58–99.
Bengali, Leila, and Mary Daly. 2013. “U.S. Economic Mobility: The Dream and the Data.”
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter, March 4.
Bondolfi, Sibilla. 2019. “Is Switzerland a Utopia of Wealth Distribution?” SWI, swissinfo.ch,
December 13. https://www.swissinfo.ch/eng/social-inequality_is-switzerland-a-utopia-
of-wealth-distribution-/45431050.
Boushey, Heather. 2019. Unbound: How Inequality Constricts Our Economy and What
We Can Do about It. Harvard University Press. Cambridge, MA.
Breen, Richard, and Inkwan Chung. 2015. “Income Inequality and Education.”
Sociological Science, 2:454–477.
Browne, James, and Herwig Immervoll. 2017. “Mechanics of Replacing Benefit Systems
with a Basic Income: Comparative Results from a Microsimulation Approach.” Journal
of Economic Inequality, 15:325-344.
Bunn, Daniel. 2021. “What the U.S. Can Learn from the Adoption (and Repeal) of Wealth
Taxes in the OECD.” Tax Foundation, February 5.
Chancel, Lucas, Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and Gabriel Zucman. 2021. World
Inequality Report 2022. World Inequality Lab.
Checchi, Daniele, and Herman G. van de Werfhorst. 2014. “Educational Policies and
Income Inequality.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 8222, May.
Chetty, Raj, David Grusky, Maximilian Hell, Nathaniel Hendren, Robert Manduca, and
Jimmy Na-rang. 2017. “The Fading American Dream: Trends in Absolute Income
Mobility since 1940.” Science, April 24.
DRAFT 37
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Collins, Chuck, Darrick Hamilton, Dedrick Asanta-Muhammad, and Josh Hoxie, 2019. Ten
Solutions to Bridge the Racial Wealth Divide. Institute for Policy Studies, Washington,
DC.
Congressional Research Service. 2021. “The Growing Gap in Life Expectancy by Income:
Recent Evidence and Implications for the Social Security Retirement Age.” Report
R44846, July 6.
Cooper, David. 2017. “Raising the Minimum Wage to $15 by 2024 Would Lift Wages for
41 Million American Workers.” Economic Policy Institute, April 26.
Corak, Miles. 2016. “Economic Mobility.” The Poverty and Inequality Report 2016, The
Stanford Center on Poverty and Inequality.
Credit Suisse. 2021. Global Wealth Databook 2021. Credit Suisse Research Institute,
June.
Dabla-Norris, Era, Kalpana Kochhar, Nujin Suphaphiphat Frantisek Ricka, and Evridiki
Tsounta. 2015. “Causes and Consequences of Income Inequality: A Global
Perspective.” International Monetary Fund, IMF Staff Discussion Note 15/13, June.
Darity, William, Jr. 2021. “Why Reparations Are Needed to Close the Racial Wealth Gap.”
The New York Times, September 24.
Deaton, Angus. 2021. “COVID-19 and Global Income Inequality.” National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper 28392, February.
Deaton, Angus. 2018. “The U.S. Can No Longer Hide from Its Deep Poverty Problem.”
The New York Times, January 24.
Derenoncourt, Ellora, Claire Montialoux, and Kate Bahn. 2020. “Why Minimum Wages
Are a Critical Tool for Achieving Racial Justice in the U.S. Labor Market.” Washington
Center for Equitable Growth, October 29.
Diffenbaugh, Noah S., and Marshall Burke. 2019. “Global Warming Has Increased Global
Economic Inequality.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United
States of America (PNAS), 116(20):9808-9813.
Dynarski, Susan, and Katherine Michelmore. 2017. “Income Differences in Education:
The Gap Within the Gap.” EconoFact, Education Policy, April 20.
https://econofact.org/income-differences-in-education-the-gap-within-the-gap.
Engbom, Niklas, and Christian Moser. 2018. “Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage:
Evidence from Brazil.” Opportunity and Inclusive Growth Institute, Federal Reserve
Bank of Minneapolis, Institute Working Paper 7, March.
Ferreira, Francisco H.G. 2021. “Inequality in the Time of COVID-19.” International
Monetary Fund, Finance & Development, June:20-23.
Gerber, Claudia, Alexander Klemm, Li Liu, and Victor Mylonas. 2018. “Personal Income
Tax Progressivity: Trends and Implications.” IMF Working Paper WP/18/246.
Gilens, Martin. 2012. Affluence and Influence. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Godwin, Uyi Ojo, and Nosa Tokunbor. 2016. “Access to Environmental Justice in Nigeria:
The Case for a Global Environmental Court of Justice.” Environmental Rights Action
and Friends of the Earth.
Gould, Elise. 2020. State of Working America Wages 2019. Economic Policy Institute.
Greenwood, Jeremy, Nezih Guner, Georgi Kocharkov, and Cezar Santos. 2014. “Marry
your Like: Assortive Mating and Income Inequality.” National Bureau of Economic
Research, NBER Working Paper 19829, January.
Hallum, Christian, and Kwesi W. Obeng. 2019. The West Africa Inequality Crisis: How
West African Governments Are Failing to Reduce Inequality, and What Should Be
Done About It. Development Finance International and Oxfam.
Harris, Benjamin H., and Melissa S. Kearney. 2014. “The ‘Ripple Effect’ of a Minimum
Wage Increase on American Workers.” The Brookings Institution, January 10.
DRAFT 38
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Hassell, Joe. 2020. “Is Income Inequality Rising around the World?” Our World in Data,
April 30.
Hershbein, Brad, Melissa S. Kearney, and Lawrence H. Summers. 2015. Increasing
Education: What It Will and Will Not Do for Earnings and Earnings Inequality.”
Brookings Institute, March 31.
Hoffman, Kelly, and Miguel Angel Centeno. 2003. “The Lopsided Continent: Inequality in
Latin America.” Annual Review of Sociology, 29:363-390.
Hoynes, Hilary W., and Ankur J. Patel. 2018. “Effective Policy for Reducing Poverty and
Inequality? The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Distribution of Income.” Journal of
Human Resources, 53:859-890.
Ibarra, Alicia Bárcena, and Winnie Byanyima. 2016. “Latin America Is the World’s Most
Unequal Region. Here’s How to Fix it.” World Economic Forum, January 17.
International Monetary Fund. 2017. World Economic Outlook: Gaining Momentum? April.
Jaumotte, Florence, and Carolina Osorio Buitron. 2015. “Inequality and Labor Market
Institutions.” International Monetary Fund, IMF Discussion Note 15/14, July.
Joumard, Isabelle, Mauro Pisu, and Debbie Bloch. 2012. “Tackling Income Inequality: The
Role of Taxes and Transfers.” OECD Journal: Economic Studies.
Kanbur, Ravi, Yue Wang, and Xiaobo Zhang. 2017. “The Great Chinese Inequality
Turnaround.” BOFIT Discussion Papers, 6/2017, Bank of Finland, Institute for
Economies in Transition.
Kaufman, Peter. 2015. “The Birth Lottery and Global Inequality.” Everyday Sociology
Blog, January 13.
Keller, Wolfgang, and William W. Olney. 2017. “Globalization and Executive
Compensation.” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 23384, May.
Keune, Maarten. 2021. “Inequality between Capital and Labour and among Wage-
earners: The Role of Collective Bargaining and Trade Unions.” Transfer, 27(1):29-46.
Krugman, Paul. 2008. “Trade and Wages, Reconsidered.” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, Spring.
Kuhn, Mortiz, Moritz Schularick, and Ulrike I. Steins. 2018. “Income and Wealth Inequality
in America, 1949-2016.” Opportunity and Inclusive Growth Institute, Federal Reserve
Bank of Minneapolis, Institute Working Paper 9, June.
Lin, Carl, and Myeong-Su Yun. 2016. “The Effects of the Minimum Wage on Earnings
Inequality: Evidence from China.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 9715, February.
Lu, Marcus. 2020. “Is the American Dream Over? Here’s What the Data Says.” World
Economic Forum, Sept. 2.
Mahler, Daniel, Gerszon, Nishant Yonzan, Christoph Lakner, R. Andres Castaneda
Aguiular, and Haoyu Wu. 2021. “Updated Estimates of the Impact of COVID-19 on
Global Poverty: Turning the Corner on the Pandemic in 2021?” World Bank Data Blog,
June 24.
Mattauch, Linus. 2019. “Reducing Wealth Inequality through Wealth Taxes without
Compromising Economic Growth.” Oxford Martin School, University of Oxford,
January 31.
Matthews, Dylan. 2012. “Ten Ways to Reduce Inequality without Raising Tax Rates.” The
Washington Post, December 6.
Milanovic, Branko. 2021. “Notes on Global Income Inequality: A Non-technical Summary.”
Global Policy, May 20.
Milanovic, Branko. 2015. “Global Inequality of Opportunity: How Much of our Income Is
Determined by Where We Live?” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 97(2):452–
460.
DRAFT 39
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Mineo, Liz. 2021. “Racial Wealth Gap May Be a Key to Other Inequities.” The Harvard
Gazette, June 3.
Moodley, Lohini, Mayowa Kuyoro, Tania Holt, Acha Leke, Anu Madgavkar, Mekala
Krishnan, and Folakemi Akintayo. 2019. The Power of Parity: Advancing Women’s
Equality in Africa. McKinsey Global Institute, November.
Moran, Timothy Patrick. 2005. “Kuznet’s Inverted U-Curve Hypothesis: The Rise, Demise,
and Continued Relevance of a Socioeconomic Law.” Sociological Forum, 20(2):209–
244.
Neumark, David. 2014. “Employment Effects of Minimum Wages.” IZA World of Labor
paper 2014:6.
Nord, Roger. 2021. “Africa: Reducing Inequality Boosts Growth Too.” iD4D, Sustainable
Development News, June 17.
Norton, Michael I., and Dan Ariely. 2011. “Building a Better America—One Wealth Quintile
at a Time.” Perspectives on Psychological Science, 6(1):9–12.
Obst, Thomas. 2013. “Income Inequality and the Welfare State – How Redistributive Is
the Public Sector?” Institute for International Political Economy Berlin, Berlin School
of Economics and Law, Working Paper No. 29/2013.
Olson, Mancur. 1984. The Rise and Decline of Nations. Yale University Press, New
Haven, CT.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 2015a. In It Together:
Why Less Inequality Benefits All. OECD Publishing, Paris.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 2015b. “Brazil Policy
Brief: Inequality.” November.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 2012. Economic
Policy Reforms: Going for Growth. OECD Publishing, Paris.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 2008. Growing
Unequal: Income Distribution and Poverty in OECD Countries. OECD Publishing,
Paris.
Ortiz-Ospina, Esteban. 2020. “Income Inequality and Happiness Inequality: A Tale of Two
Trends.” Our World in Data, April 30. https://ourworldindata.org/happiness-and-
income-inequality.
Ostry, Jonathan D., Andrew Berg, and Charalambos G. Tsangarides. 2014.
“Redistribution, Inequality, and Growth.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 14/02, April.
Pavcnik, Nina. 2011. “Globalization and Within-country Income Inequality.” Chapter 7 of
Making Globalization Socially Sustainable (Marc Bacchetta and Marion Jansen,
editors). World Trade Organization and International Labour Organization, Geneva.
Peterson-Withorn, Chase. 2021. “Led by Elon Musk’s Crazy Gains, American Billionaires
Have Added Nearly $2 Trillion to their Fortunes during the Pandemic.” Forbes, Nov.
7.
Prosperity Now. 2018. Financial Stability of People with Disabilities. Prosperity Now
Scorecard. https://prosperitynow.org/sites/default/files/resources/Financial-Stability-
of-People-with-Disabilities.pdf.
Ravallion, Martin. 2014. “Income Inequality in the Developing World.” Science,
344(6186):851–855.
Rothstein, Jesse, and Ben Zipperer. 2020. The EITC and Minimum Wage Work Together
to Reduce Poverty and Raise Incomes. Economic Policy Institute Report, Washington,
DC, January 22.
Saez, Emmanuel, and Gabriel Zucman. 2016. “Wealth Inequality in the United States
since 1913: Evidence from Capitalized Income Tax Data.” The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 131(2):519–578.
DRAFT 40
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
Schmitt, John. 2009. “Inequality as Policy: The United States since 1979.” Center for
Economic and Policy Research, October.
Schneider, Simone M. 2016. “Income Inequality and Subjective Well-Being: Trends,
Challenges, and Research Directions.” Journal of Happiness Studies, 17:1719-1739.
Shimeles, Abebe. 2016. “Can Higher Education Reduce Inequality in Developing
Countries?” IZA World of Labor paper 2016:273.
Shrider, Emily A., Melissa Kollar, Frances Chen, and Jessica Semega. 2021. Income and
Poverty in the United States: 2020. U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Reports,
P60-273, September.
Steverman, Ben, and Reade Pickert. 2020. “This Is What It Takes to Be in the 1% Around
the World.” Bloomberg, February 7.
Taconet, Nicolas, Aurélie Méjean, and Céline Guivarch. 2020. “Influence of Climate
Change Impacts and Mitigation Costs on Inequality between Countries.” Climate
Change, 160:15-34.
The Pew Charitable Trusts and the Russell Sage Foundation. 2015. Economic Mobility in
the United States. July.
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). 2013. Humanity Divided: Confronting
Inequality in Developing Countries. United Nations, New York.
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2021. "Earnings and Unemployment Rates by
Educational Attainment." April 21.
United States Federal Reserve. 2020. Distributional Financial Accounts, "Distribution of
Household Wealth in the U.S. since 1989."
Vidal, John. 2013. “Climate Change Will Hit Poor Countries Hardest, Study Shows.” The
Guardian, September 27.
Wade, Robert. 2011. “Global Trends in Income Inequality.” Challenge, 54(5):54–75.
Watson, Spencer, Oliver McNeil, and Bruce Broisman. 2021. The Economic Well-Being
of LGBT Adults in the U.S. in 2019. Center for LGBTQ Economic Advancement &
Research.
Weller, Christian. 2019. “Reparations Are Essential to Eliminating the Substantial Wealth
Gap between Black and White Americans.” The Conversation, September 17.
Wignaraja, Kanni, and Balazs Horvath. 2020. “Universal Basic Income Is the Answer to
the Inequalities Exposed by COVID-19.” World Economic Forum, April 17.
Williamson, Vanessa. 2020. Closing the Racial Wealth Gap Requires Heavy, Progressive
Taxation of Wealth. The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC, December 9.
World Bank. 2019. The Changing Nature of Work, World Development Report 2019.
Washington, DC.
World Economic Forum. 2021. Global Gender Gap Report 2021.
NOTES
1
Mahler et al., 2021.
2
Peterson-Withorn, 2021.
3
Ferreira, 2021.
4
Congressional Research Service, 2021.
5
Data from the United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Reports database.
6
Dynarski and Michelmore, 2017.
7
World Economic Forum, 2021.
8
Godwin et al., 2016.
9
Diffenbaugh and Burke, 2019.
10
Vidal, 2013.
11
Taconet et al., 2020.
12
Ortiz-Ospina, 2020.
DRAFT 41
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
13
Schneider, 2016.
14
Credit Suisse, 2021.
15
Saez and Zucman, 2016.
16
Norton and Ariely, 2011.
17
Ibid, p. 12.
18
Note that the categories presented in Figures 10.8 and 10.9 slightly differ, as the data come from
two different U.S. Census Bureau reports.
19
Prosperity Now, 2018.
20
Watson et al., 2021.
21
Bengali and Daly, 2013.
22
The Pew Charitable Trusts and the Russell Sage Foundation, 2015, p. 5.
23
Chetty et al., 2017.
24
Lu, 2020.
25
Ibid, p. 9.
26
All Gini coefficients from the CIA World Factbook.
27
Hassell, 2020.
28
Corak, 2016.
29
OECD, 2015a.
30
Milanovic, 2021.
31
Chancel et al., 2021.
32
Deaton, 2018.
33
Steverman and Pickert, 2020.
34
See Milanovic, 2015.
35
Kaufman, 2015.
36
Chancel et al., 2021.
37
Deaton, 2021.
38
World Bank, World Development Indicators database.
39
Credit Suisse, 2021.
40
Ibid.
41
Greenwood et al., 2014.
42
Olson, 1984.
43
IMF, 2017.
44
Gould, 2020.
45
Krugman, 2008.
46
Pavcnik, 2011.
47
Keller and Olney, 2017.
48
Pavcnik, 2011.
49
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2021.
50
OECD online statistics, trade union density.
51
Jaumotte and Buitron, 2015.
52
Keune, 2021.
53
Dabla-Norris et al., 2015.
54
Schmitt, 2009, pp. 3–4.
55
ChinaPower, https://chinapower.csis.org/poverty/.
56
Hassell, 2020.
57
Acemoğlu and Robinson, 2017.
58
Hoffman and Centeno, 2003.
59
Ibarra and Byanyima, 2016.
60
Moran, 2005.
61
Moran, 2005; Wade, 2011.
62
Kanbur et al., 2017.
63
Ostry et al., 2014.
64
Ibid, p. 25.
65
Ibid, p. 26.
66
Boushey, 2019.
67
Gilens, 2012.
68
Ibid., p. 1.
69
Gerber et al., 2018.
DRAFT 42
Microeconomics In Context – Sample Chapter for Early Release
70
OECD, 2008.
71
Hoynes and Patel, 2018.
72
Rothstein and Zipperer, 2020.
73
Bunn, 2021.
74
Mattauch, 2019.
75
Joumard et al., 2012.
76
World Bank, 2019.
77
Browne and Immervoll, 2017.
78
Wignaraja and Horvath, 2020.
79
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_countries_by_minimum_wage.
80
Bondolfi, 2019.
81
Autor et al., 2016.
82
OECD, 2012.
83
Neumark, 2014.
84
Harris and Kearney, 2014.
85
Cooper, 2017.
86
See https://www.australianunions.org.au/factsheet/minimum-wages/.
87
Obst, 2013.
88
Breen and Chung, 2015.
89
Hershbein et al., 2015.
90
Jaumotte and Buitron, 2015.
91
Checchi and van de Werfhorst, 2014.
92
Jaumotte and Buitron, 2015.
93
Matthews, 2012.
94
OECD, 2012.
95
Ambrosino, 2016.
96
Alderman, 2017.
97
See https://projects.propublica.org/graphics/temps-around-the-world.
98
Kuhn et al., 2018.
99
Mineo, 2021.
100
Derenoncourt et al., 2020.
101
Collins et al., 2019.
102
Williamson, 2020.
103
Darrity, 2021.
104
Weller, 2019.
105
Ravallion, 2014.
106
UNDP, 2013.
107
Lin and Yun, 2016.
108
Shimeles, 2016.
109
See http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/opinion/2013/ll/04/bolsa-familia-Brazil-quiet-revolution.
110
OECD, OECD.Stat, Real Minimum Wages.
111
Engbom and Moser, 2018.
112
OECD, 2015b.
113
Hallum and Obeng, 2019, p. 5.
114
Nord, 2021.
115
Moodley et al., 2019.
DRAFT 43