c4 Notes
c4 Notes
i.c
CM2-04: Measures of investment risk Page 1
ng
si
om
m
o
as
.m
w
w
w
Measures of investment risk
Syllabus objectives
2.1 Properties of risk measures
2.1.2 Describe how the risk measures listed in 2.1.1 above are related to the
form of an investor’s utility function.
2.1.3 Perform calculations using the risk measures listed in 2.1.1 above to
compare investment opportunities.
2.1.4 Explain how the distribution of returns and the thickness of tails will
influence the assessment of risk.
2.2 Risk and insurance companies
ng
si
om
o m
0 Introduction
as
.m
w
In financial economics, it is often assumed that the key factors influencing investment decisions
w
w
are ‘risk’ and ‘return’. In practice, return is almost always interpreted as the expected investment
return. However, there are many possible interpretations and different ways of measuring
investment risk, of which the variance is just one, each of which corresponds to a different utility
function.
This chapter outlines a small number of such measures, together with their relative merits, and
then moves on to discuss how insurance can be used to reduce the impact of risk.
ng
si
om
o m
1 Measures of risk
as
.m
w
1.1 Introduction
w
w
Most mathematical investment theories of investment risk use variance of return as the
measure of risk.
Examples include (mean-variance) portfolio theory and the capital asset pricing model, both of
which are discussed later in this course.
Some investors might not be concerned with the mean and variance of returns, but simpler things
such as the maximum possible loss. Alternatively, some investors might be concerned not only
with the mean and variance of returns, but also more generally with other higher moments of
returns, such as the skewness of returns. For example, although two risky assets might yield the
same expectation and variance of future returns, if the returns on Asset A are positively skewed,
whilst those on Asset B are symmetrical about the mean, then Asset A might be preferred to
Asset B by some investors.
( x )
2
f ( x ) dx
where is the mean return at the end of the chosen period and f(x) is the probability
density function of the return.
‘Return’ here means the proportionate increase in the market value of the asset, eg x 0.05 if
the asset value has increased by 5% over the period.
The units of variance are ‘%%’, which means ‘per 100 per 100’.
Question
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using a probability distribution
with density function:
f (x) 0.00075 100 (x 5)2 where 5 x 15
ng
si
om
o m
Solution
as
.m
The density function is symmetrical about x 5 . Hence the mean return is 5%. Alternatively, this
w
w
could be found by integrating as follows:
w
15
E[ X ] 0.00075 x 100 (x 5)2 dx
5
15
0.00075 75 x 10 x 2 x 3dx
5
15
75 10 1
0.00075 x 2 x 3 x 4
2 3 4 5
0.000757,031.25 364.5833
5
ie 5% pa.
15
Var ( X ) 0.00075 (5 x)2 100 (x 5)2 dx
5
15
0.00075 100(x 5)2 (x 5)4 dx
5
15
100 1
0.00075 (x 5)3 (x 5)5
3 5 5
0.0007513,333.33 (13,333.33)
20
ie 20%% pa.
Alternatively, we can calculate the variance using the formula: Var( X ) E[ X 2 ] (E[ X ])2 , where
E[ X 2 ] can be found by integration to be 45%%.
ng
si
om
o m
Question
as
.m
w
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using the probability
w
distribution:
w
X Probability
7 0.04
5.5 0.96
Solution
ie 5% pa.
ie 6%% pa.
Alternatively, we can calculate the variance using the formula: Var( X ) E[ X 2 ] (E[ X ])2 , where
E[ X 2 ] is 31%%.
Variance has the advantage over most other measures in that it is mathematically tractable,
and the mean-variance framework discussed in a later chapter leads to elegant solutions for
optimal portfolios. Albeit easy to use, the mean-variance theory has been shown to give a
good approximation to several other proposed methodologies.
Mean-variance portfolio theory can be shown to lead to optimum portfolios if investors can
be assumed to have quadratic utility functions or if returns can be assumed to be normally
distributed.
In an earlier chapter we discussed how the aim of investors is to maximise their expected utility.
The mean-variance portfolio theory discussed in a later chapter assumes that investors base their
investment decisions solely on the mean and variance of investment returns. This assumption is
consistent with the maximisation of expected utility provided that the investor’s expected utility
depends only on the mean and variance of investment returns.
ng
si
om
m
It can be shown that this is the case if:
o
as
.m
the investor has a quadratic utility function, and/or
w
w
investment returns follow a distribution that is characterised fully by its first two
w
moments, such as the normal distribution.
If, however, neither of these conditions holds, then we cannot assume that investors make
choices solely on the basis of the mean and variance of return. For example, with more complex
utility functions and non-normal return distributions investors may need to consider other
features of the distribution of returns, such as skewness and kurtosis.
Question
Define both the skewness and the fourth central moment (called the kurtosis) of a continuous
probability distribution.
Solution
The skewness of a continuous probability distribution is defined as the third central moment.
It is a measure of the extent to which a distribution is asymmetric about its mean. For example,
the normal distribution is symmetric about its mean and therefore has zero skewness, whereas
the lognormal distribution is positively skewed.
The kurtosis of a continuous probability distribution is defined as the fourth central moment.
It is a measure of how likely extreme values are to appear (ie those in the tails of the distribution).
For example, all rational investors would choose a security that offered a chance of either a 10%
or 12% return in preference to one that offered a certain 10%, despite the greater uncertainty
associated with the former.
One measure that seeks to quantify this view is downside semi-variance (also referred to as
simply semi-variance). For a continuous random variable, this is defined as:
( x )
2
f ( x ) dx
ng
si
om
o m
Question
as
.m
w
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using a probability distribution
w
with density function:
w
f (x) 0.00075 100 (x 5)2 where 5 x 15
Solution
We saw in an earlier question that the variance of investment returns for this asset is 20%%.
Since the continuous distribution f (x) is symmetrical, the downside semi-variance is half the
variance, ie 10%%.
( x)2 P(X x)
x
Question
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using the probability
distribution:
X probability
7 0.04
5.5 0.96
Solution
We saw in an earlier question that the mean investment return for this asset is 5%. So the
downside semi-variance is given by:
ie 5.76%% pa.
ng
si
om
o m
1.4 Shortfall probabilities
as
.m
A shortfall probability measures the probability of returns falling below a certain level. For
w
w
continuous variables, the risk measure is given by:
w
L
Shortfall probability f ( x ) dx
where L is a chosen benchmark level.
Shortfall probability P( X x )
x L
The benchmark level, L, can be expressed as the return on a benchmark fund if this is more
appropriate than an absolute level. In fact, any of the risk measures discussed can be
expressed as measures of the risk relative to a suitable benchmark which may be an index,
a median fund or some level of inflation.
Question
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using a probability distribution
with density function:
f (x) 0.00075 100 (x 5)2 where 5 x 15
Solution
0
P( X 0) 0.00075 100 (x 5)2 dx
5
0
1
0.00075 100 x (x 5)3
3 5
0.15625
ng
si
om
o m
Question
as
.m
w
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using the probability
w
distribution:
w
X probability
7 0.04
5.5 0.96
Solution
P( X 0) 0.04
The main advantages of the shortfall probability are that it is easy to understand and calculate.
The main drawback of the shortfall probability as a measure of investment risk is that it gives no
indication of the magnitude of any shortfall (being independent of the extent of any shortfall).
For example, consider two securities that offer the following combinations of returns and
associated probabilities:
Investment A: 10.1% with probability of 0.9 and 9.9% with probability of 0.1
Investment B: 10.1% with probability of 0.91 and 0% with probability of 0.09
An investor who chooses between them purely on the basis of the shortfall probability based
upon a benchmark return of 10% would choose Investment B, despite the fact that it gives a much
bigger shortfall than Investment A if a shortfall occurs.
VaR ( X ) t where P ( X t ) p
VaR represents the maximum potential loss on a portfolio over a given future time period
with a given degree of confidence, where the latter is normally expressed as 1 p . So, for
example, a 99% one-day VaR is the maximum loss on a portfolio over a one-day period with
99% confidence, ie there is a 1% probability of a greater loss.
ng
si
om
m
Note that Value at Risk is a ‘loss amount’. Therefore:
o
as
.m
a positive Value at Risk (a negative t ) indicates a loss
w
w
a negative Value at Risk (a positive t ) indicates a profit
w
Value at Risk should be expressed as a monetary amount and not as a percentage.
Question
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using a probability distribution
with density function:
f (x) 0.00075 100 (x 5)2 where 5 x 15
Calculate the VaR over one year with a 95% confidence limit for a portfolio consisting of £100m
invested in the asset.
Solution
t
0.00075 100 (x 5)2 dx 0.05
5
t
1
0.00075 100 x (x 5)3 0.05
3 5
Since the equation in the brackets is a cubic in t , we are going to need to solve this equation
numerically, by trial and error.
3
1
t 3 0.00075 100 x (x 5)3 0.028
3 5
2
1
and t 2 0.00075 100 x (x 5)3 0.06075
3 5
0.05 0.028
Interpolating between the two gives: t 3 2.3
0.06075 0.028
In fact, the true value is t 2.293 . Since t is a percentage investment return per annum, the
95% Value at Risk over one year on a £100m portfolio is £100m 2.293% £2.293m . This means
that we are 95% certain that we will not lose more than £2.293m over the next year.
ng
si
om
o m
Question
as
.m
w
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using the probability
w
distribution:
w
X Probability
7 0.04
5.5 0.96
Calculate the 95% VaR over one year with a 95% confidence limit for a portfolio consisting of
£100m invested in the asset.
Solution
Since t is a percentage investment return per annum, the 95% Value at Risk over one year on a
£100m portfolio is £100m 5.5% £5.5m . This means that we are 95% certain that we will
not make profits of less than £5.5m over the next year.
VaR can be measured either in absolute terms or relative to a benchmark. Again, VaR is
based on assumptions that may not be immediately apparent.
The problem is that in practice VaR is often calculated assuming that investment returns are
normally distributed.
Question
Calculate the 97.5% VaR over one year for a portfolio consisting of £200m invested in shares.
Assume that the return on the portfolio of shares is normally distributed with mean 8% pa and
standard deviation 8% pa.
Solution
Standardising gives:
t 8 t 8
P Z 0.025
8 8
ng
si
om
m
t 8
o
Now (1.96) 0.025 from page 162 of the Tables, so: 1.96 t 7.68 .
as
8
.m
w
w
Since t is a percentage investment return per annum, the 97.5% Value at Risk over one year on a
w
£200m portfolio is £200m 7.68% £15.36m . This means that we are 97.5% certain that we will
not lose more than £15.36m over the next year.
Portfolios exposed to credit risk, systematic bias or derivatives may exhibit non-normal
distributions. The usefulness of VaR in these situations depends on modelling skewed or
fat-tailed distributions of returns, either in the form of statistical distributions (such as the
Gumbel, Frechet or Weibull distributions) or via Monte Carlo simulations. However, the
further one gets out into the ‘tails’ of the distributions, the more lacking the data and, hence,
the more arbitrary the choice of the underlying probability becomes.
Hedge funds are a good example of portfolios exposed to credit risk, systematic bias and
derivatives. These are private collective investment vehicles that often adopt complex and
unusual investment positions in order to make high investment returns. For example, they will
often short-sell securities and use derivatives.
If the portfolio in the previous question was a hedge fund then modelling the return using a
normal distribution may no longer be appropriate. A different distribution could be used to
assess the lower tail but choosing this distribution will depend on the data available for how
hedge funds have performed in the past. This data may be lacking or include survivorship bias,
ie hedge funds that do very badly may not be included.
The Gumbel, Frechet and Weibull distributions are three examples of extreme value distributions,
which are used to model extreme events.
The main weakness of VaR is that it does not quantify the size of the ‘tail’. Another useful
measure of investment risk therefore is the Tail Value at Risk.
The risk measure can be expressed as the expected shortfall below a certain level.
L
Expected shortfall = E max(L X ,0) (L x )f ( x ) dx
where L is the chosen benchmark level.
If L is chosen to be a particular percentile point on the distribution, then the risk measure is
known as the TailVaR.
The (1 p) TailVaR is the expected shortfall in the p th lower tail. So, for the 99% confidence
limit, it represents the expected loss in excess of the 1% lower tail value.
ng
si
om
o m
Question
as
.m
w
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using a probability distribution
w
with density function:
w
f (x) 0.00075 100 (x 5)2 where 5 x 15
Calculate the 95% TailVaR over one year for a portfolio consisting of £100m invested in the asset.
Solution
In a previous question, we calculated the 95% VaR for this portfolio to be £2.293m based on an
investment return of –2.293%.
0.00075
2.293
5 171.975 97.93x 7.707x2 x3 dx
2.293
0.00075 171.975 x 48.965 x 2 2.569 x 3 0.25x 4
5
0.0462
On a portfolio of £100m, the 95% TailVaR is £100m 0.000462 £0.0462m . This means that the
expected loss in excess of £2.293m is £46,200.
Question
Investment returns (% pa), X , on a particular asset are modelled using the probability
distribution:
X Probability
7 0.04
5.5 0.96
Calculate the 95% TailVaR over one year for a portfolio consisting of £100m invested in the asset.
ng
si
om
o m
Solution
as
.m
w
In a previous question, we calculated the 95% VaR for this portfolio to be –£5.5m based on an
w
investment return of 5.5%.
w
The expected shortfall in returns below 5.5% is given by:
On a portfolio of £100m, the 95% TailVaR is £100m 0.005 £0.5m . This means that the
expected reduction in profits below £5.5m is £0.5m.
However, TailVaR can also be expressed as the expected shortfall conditional on there
being a shortfall.
To do this, we would need to take the expected shortfall formula and divide by the shortfall
probability.
conditional VaR
They all measure the risk of underperformance against some set criteria. It should be noted
that the characteristics of the risk measures may vary depending on whether the variable is
discrete or continuous in nature.
Downside risk measures have also been proposed based on an increasing function of
L x , rather than L x itself in the integral above.
In other words, for continuous random variables, we could use a measure of the form:
L
g(L x) f (x) dx
Two particular cases of note are when:
Note also that if g(x) x 2 and L = , then we have the semi-variance measure defined above.
ng
si
om
m
Shortfall measures are useful for monitoring a fund’s exposure to risk because the expected
o
as
underperformance relative to a benchmark is a concept that is apparently easy to
.m
understand. As with semi-variance, however, no attention is paid to the distribution of
w
outperformance of the benchmark, ie returns in excess of L are again completely ignored.
w
w
Question
Consider an investment whose returns follow a continuous uniform distribution over the range
0% to 10% pa.
(i) Write down the probability density function for the investment returns.
(iv) Calculate the shortfall probability and the expected shortfall based on a benchmark level
of 3% pa.
Solution
Useful information about the continuous uniform distribution can be found on page 13 of the
Tables, including the form of its probability density function, and formulae for its mean and
variance.
Working in % units, the investment return follows a U(0,10) distribution. So the probability
1
density function is f (x) for 0 x 10 and 0 otherwise.
10
If we work with the returns expressed in decimals instead, then f (x) 10 for 0 x 0.10 and 0
otherwise.
(ii) Mean
1
(0 10) 5
2
ie 5% pa.
1
(10 0)2 8.33
12
ie 8.33%% pa.
ng
si
om
m
Alternatively, we could evaluate the variance using the integral:
o
as
.m
10
5 x 2 dx
w
w
10
w
0
Since the uniform distribution is symmetric, the semi-variance is equal to half the variance,
ie 4.17%% pa.
5
5 x 2 dx
10
0
3 3
1 x
SP 10 dx 10 0.3
0 0
3
3 x dx 1 3
ES 10
2
10 3 x 0.5 x 0.45 %
0
0
ng
si
om
o m
2 Relationship between risk measures and utility functions
as
.m
w
An investor using a particular risk measure will base their decisions on a consideration of
w
the available combinations of risk and expected return. Given a knowledge of how this
w
trade-off is made it is possible, in principle, to construct the investor’s underlying utility
function. Conversely, given a particular utility function, the appropriate risk measure can be
determined.
For example, if an investor has a quadratic utility function, the function to be maximised in
applying the expected utility theorem will involve a linear combination of the first two
moments of the distribution of return.
In other words, if an investor has a quadratic utility function then their attitude towards risk and
return can be expressed purely in terms of the mean and variance of investment opportunities.
Question
Solution
(ii)
U(w)
0 w
Non-satiated investors prefer more wealth to less and so the graph slopes upwards,
ie U(w) 0 .
Risk-averse investors have diminishing marginal utility of wealth and so the slope of the
graph decreases with w, ie U(w) 0 .
ng
si
om
m
If expected return and semi-variance below the expected return are used as the basis of
o
as
investment decisions, it can be shown that this is equivalent to a utility function that is
.m
quadratic below the expected return and linear above.
w
w
w
Thus, this is equivalent to the investor being risk-averse below the expected return and
risk-neutral for investment return levels above the expected return. Hence, no weighting is given
to variability of investment returns above the expected return.
Use of a shortfall risk measure corresponds to a utility function that has a discontinuity at
the minimum required return.
Question
Solution
Sometimes it may be inappropriate to model an investor’s behaviour over all possible levels of
wealth with a single utility function. This problem can be overcome by using state-dependent
utility functions, which model the situation where there is a discontinuous change in the state of
the investor at a certain level of wealth.
ng
si
om
o m
3 Risk and insurance companies
as
.m
w
3.1 Introduction
w
w
Individuals and corporations face risks resulting from unexpected events.
Risk-averse individuals can buy insurance to remove their exposure to risks. Being risk-averse,
they will be willing to pay more for insurance than the expected cost of claims. The insurance
company is willing to offer insurance primarily because it is able to spread its risks.
Figure 4.1
The figure above shows the frequency-severity dynamics of four possible events.
ng
si
om
m
Event 4 is a low-frequency-high-severity event. Such events tend to be insured.
o
as
.m
For example, earthquake or hurricane damage.
w
w
In general, low severity events (such as events 1 and 2) are not generally insurable as the
w
cost of management per claim is too expensive. However micro-insurance for poorer
clients and new technologies that enable insuring small items over a short term (such as
gadgets during a holiday) have been gaining ground.
Consider a simple scenario of a property that has one hundredth chance of suffering
£10,000 in damages (and 99% of no damages). The expected cost is 1% of £10,000 which is
£100 while the VaR(99.5%) is £10,000.
Question
Solution
Let X be the impact suffered by the property, so P( X 0) 0.99 and P(X 10,000) 0.01 . Then
from the definition of Value at Risk for a discrete random variable we have:
If ten independent properties with similar characteristics are pooled together, the average
cost is still £100 per property. At the extreme, the probability of all of them suffering the
damage is 0.0110 . The VaR(99.5%) in this case is if one property suffers damage, that is
£100 on average (using a Binomial distribution).
Question
Solution
Let X be the total impact suffered by the properties, so X Binomial(10,0.01) (10,000) . Then
from the definition of Value at Risk for a discrete random variable we have:
ng
si
om
m
If no properties suffer damage then X 0 . The probability of this is:
o
as
.m
10
w
P( X 0) 0.010 (1 0.01)10 0.9910 0.9044
w
0
w
So: P( X 0) 1 0.9044 0.0956
If exactly one property suffers damage then X 10,000 . The probability of this is:
10 10!
P( X 10,000) 0.011 (1 0.01)9 0.011 0.999 0.0914
1 9!1!
Therefore:
This means that the Value at Risk is £10,000, which equates to one property suffering damage.
It arises because customers typically know more about themselves than the insurance company
knows.
To try and reduce the problems of adverse selection, insurance companies try to find out
lots of information about potential policyholders. Policyholders can then be put in small,
reasonably homogeneous pools and charged appropriate premiums.
Moral hazard describes the fact that a policyholder may, because they have insurance, act
in a way which makes the insured event more likely.
This is because having the insurance provides less incentive to guard against the insured event
happening. For example, while driving to work one day you realise that you forgot to lock the front
door of your house. If you didn’t have any household contents insurance, you might decide to go
back and lock it. If you had adequate insurance, you might decide to carry on to work. This
difference in behaviour caused by the fact that you are insured is an example of ‘moral hazard’.
Moral hazard makes insurance more expensive. It may even push the price of insurance
above the maximum premium that a person is prepared to pay.
ng
si
om
o m
as
.m
w
w
w
The chapter summary starts on the next page so that you can keep
all the chapter summaries together for revision purposes.
ng
si
om
o m
as
Chapter 4 Summary
.m
w
w
Measures of investment risk
w
Many investment models use variance of return as the measure of investment risk.
For a continuous random variable: V ( x)2 f (x) dx
Variance has the advantage over most other measures that it:
is mathematically tractable
leads to elegant solutions for optimal portfolios, within the context of mean-variance
portfolio theory.
The main argument against the use of variance as a measure of risk is that most investors do
not dislike uncertainty of returns as such; rather they dislike the downside risk of low
investment returns. Consequently, alternative measures of downside risk sometimes used
include (in the continuous and then discrete cases):
semi-variance of return: ( x)
2
f (x) dx ( x)2P(X x)
x
L
shortfall probability: f (x) dx P( X x )
x L
Value at Risk (VaR) represents the maximum potential loss on a portfolio over a given future
time period with a given degree of confidence (1 p) . It is often calculated assuming that
investment returns follow a normal distribution, which may not be an appropriate
assumption.
L
For a continuous random variable, expected shortfall = (L x) f (x)dx .
For a discrete random variable, expected shortfall = (L x)P(X x) .
x L
ng
si
om
o m
as
When L is the VaR with a particular confidence level, the expected shortfall is known as
.m
TailVaR. TailVaR measures the expected loss in excess of the VaR.
w
w
w
It is also possible to calculate the expected shortfall and TailVaR conditional on a shortfall
occurring by dividing through by the shortfall probability.
If expected return and semi-variance below the expected return are used as the basis of
investment decisions, it can be shown that this is equivalent to a utility function that is
quadratic below the expected return and linear above.
Use of a shortfall risk measure corresponds to a utility function that has a discontinuity at the
minimum required return.
Adverse selection describes the fact that people who know that they are particularly bad
risks are more inclined to take out insurance than those who know that they are good risks.
Moral hazard is the change in a policyholder’s behaviour once insurance has been taken out,
which makes the risk event more likely to occur.