Cs Ardl Paper
Cs Ardl Paper
com
DOI: https://doi.org/10.54660/.IJMRGE.2023.4.2.373-382
1. Introduction
In the last one and half decades, the literature on the nexus between infrastructure and growth in developing countries in general
and in Sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries in particular has shifted to the investigation of the factors that moderate the nexus.
This is because efforts at scaling up the stock of infrastructure in these economies have not really translated to the much desired
growth. This experience of developing countries in terms of the growth effect of infrastructure, however, contradicts that of a
country like China. The Chinese economy has been able to record significant growth in the last two decades due to massive
investment in infrastructure, among other factors. This contradiction has, therefore, prompted scholars to search for factors which
are responsible for the differences in the effects among countries. One of the factors that have been touted to be capable of
causing the differences in the returns to infrastructure is institutional quality.
The fact that the infrastructure-growth link is moderated by the quality of institutions has been established in both the theoretical
and empirical literature.
373 | P a g e
International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Growth Evaluation www.allmultidisciplinaryjournal.com
In the theoretical literature, scholars have argued that, based ground of its inability to capture cross-section dependence
on their quality, institutional indicators will either limit or and slope parameter homogeneity (Amin et al., 2022; Chudik
enhance the efficient use of infrastructure. For example, Hall, & Pesaran, 2015; Sarafidis et al., 2008; Saygin &
Sobel and Crowley (2010) [17] argued that countries with Iskenderoglu, 2022) [2, 6, 38]. To correct this second limitation,
well-developed institutions, which do not encourage scholars have suggested the use of the Cross-Sectional-
unproductive activities, tend to experience growth when they Autoregressive Distributed Lag (CS-ARDL) estimator.
increase their capital stock. Conversely, investing in Another important advantage of CS-ARDL is its ability to
infrastructure in countries where corruption, rent seeking and yield robust estimates even when available dataset is
other unproductive activities are prevalent may lead to zero relatively small (Amin et al., 2022) [2].
if not negative growth rates. Also, Agénor and Montiel Hence, this study was conducted to investigate the role of
(2010) [1] posited that devoting resources to infrastructure institutions in the infrastructure-growth relationship in SSA
development is a necessary but not sufficient condition for over the period 1996 to 2020 using the CS-ARDL approach.
boosting economic growth. The authors underscored the
importance of strong institutions which play the role of 2. Literature Review
catalyst in the efficiency of capital. Furthermore, Wu, Tang This section reviews the literature on the relationship
and Lin (2010) [44] have attributed the efficacy of government between infrastructure and economic growth, while paying
spending on growth to the institutional quality of the country particular attention to the role of institutions, in line with the
in question. They argued that in low-income countries, which belief among economists and other stakeholders in recent
are usually characterised by poor institutions, government years that “institutions matter”.
expenditures have the tendency to retard growth or become
ineffective. While also supporting this line of thought, Dabla- 2.1 Theoretical Review
Norris et al. (2012) [8] argued that embarking on considerable Available theories regarding the economic impact of
infrastructure development in an environment characterised infrastructure can be reviewed from three fields based on the
by weak institutions has the tendency of potentially different analytical approaches: traditional approach,
undermining its growth benefits. endogenous growth approach, and the new institutional
In SSA in particular, many countries are plagued by poor economics.
maintenance of existing facilities, coupled with wanton
vandalisation and destruction of infrastructure facilities as a A) Traditional Theory
result of high rates of corruption and terrorism. The estimates The traditional neoclassical growth theory, which is largely
arrived at by Gulati and Rao (2006) [16] on the cost of due to the work of Solow (1956) [40], assumes that capital has
corruption in infrastructure suggest that between 5% and 20% diminishing returns. This leads to the condition that there is
of construction costs are being lost to bribe payments, while an inverse relationship between per capita income growths of
as much as between 20% and 30% of electric power is being countries and their initial income levels. If economies are
stolen by consumers who collude with staff. Using similar in the sense of preferences and technology, countries
investment and maintenance estimates from Fay and Yepes that are poor in the level of capital grow faster than capital
(2003) [13], Kenny (2009) [18] found that the financial burden rich countries (Olson, Sarna & Swamy, 2000) [31]. In this
may sum up to around US$18 billion annually in low-income model, technology is assumed to be exogenously given. Thus
countries if as much as 5% of expenditure and maintenance taking the saving and population growth rates as constant, the
outlays in infrastructure are lost to institutional failure. What model predicts that countries would tend to converge into
this suggests is that “better infrastructure (that is, infrastructure similar steady state level. Diminishing returns to physical
development embedded within a sound institutional capital is thus a force that allows countries to converge into
framework), more growth” is a more accurate proposition than income equability when they reach similar steady states level
“more infrastructure, more growth”. Hence, investigating the (Barro et al., 1991; Barro & Sala-i-Martin, 1992) [5, 4].
relationship between infrastructure and growth without Despite its ability to explain international differences as a
paying attention to how institutional factors contribute to this result of conditional convergence, the neoclassical model
relationship as a complementary factor may lead to seriously cannot however explain why the income gap between rich
misleading inferences. and poor countries is still widening (Mankiw, 1995) [21].
Although many studies acknowledge the high a priori Beside this, there is no room for public decisions to have
probability that the linear relationship between infrastructure long-term effects on the economy since exogenous technical
and economic growth is moderated by institutions, only a few progress is the sole determinant of long-run growth in
have subjected this hypothesis to empirical testing in both the traditional neoclassical growth models (Getachew, 2009) [15].
developed and developing countries. Studies that have been A policy shock will have a transitory effect, influencing the
conducted to address this gap in SSA include Damijan and level of (long-run) output only. Thus, an economy’s
Padilla (2014) [9], Esfahani and Ramirez (2003) [11], Garlick institutions and infrastructure development, among others,
(2008) [14], Kodongo and Ojah (2016) [19], as well as Okoh will have no lasting effect on its output. By and large,
and Ebi (2013) [30]. These studies suffer two serious economic agents are assumed to operate almost in a vacuum.
limitations, one of which is their inability to capture recent However, the developments in post-independence Africa told
changes in the trend of infrastructure in particular, especially a different story. Economic growth at that time was
in the last decade. The other one concerns the methodology disappointing. Many of the economies were growing very
used by these studies, especially the few that employed panel slowly and some were even retrogressing. The problem then
data estimation techniques. For example, the System was not attributed to resource constraint but was linked to
Generalised Method of Moments (GMM) adopted by poor policies. Most countries had implemented a
Kodongo and Ojah (2016) [19] has been criticised on the “government led” development paradigm that restricted
374 | P a g e
International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Growth Evaluation www.allmultidisciplinaryjournal.com
private sector development. Heavy intervention in the growth models to address the remarkable fact of the
economy in the form of government production, control of contemporary cross-country growth disparities led a large
prices and exchange rates, over-regulation of the economy number of scholars to seek for other fundamental factors that
and the adoption of import substitution strategies that are necessary in explaining economic growth and cross-
included severe import controls and foreign exchange country income disparities. Towards this end, economists
rationing inhibited economic growth. incrementally advanced the notion that, in addition to
government policies, high institutional quality is required to
B) Endogenous Growth Theory bring about higher economic growth.
Due to the less convincing empirical relevance of the The phrase “New Institutional Economics (NIE)” was
neoclassical model, subsequent researches took a more coined by Williamson (1985) [43] in order to distinguish it
radical approach to the study of economic growth. The goal from the “old institutional economics” which was pioneered
of this approach, known as “endogenous growth theory”, is by Veblen (1899) [41] and Commons (1934) [7]. Although the
to develop models of persistent growth that give up the old institutional school regarded institutions as a key factor
assumption of exogenous technological change (Mankiw, in defining and determining economic performance, but it
1995; Weil, 2005) [21, 42]. The approach embraces diverse had little analytical rigour and lacked theoretical framework
body of theoretical and empirical works that emerged in the as a school of thought. Its operation was outside of
1980s, following the path pioneered by Arrow (1962) [3]. neoclassical economics and deriving reliable generalization
Notable contributions include, among others, Romer (1986) or making sound policy choices was impossible because there
[36]
, Lucas (1988) [20] and Robelo (1991) [36]. was no quantitative theory for doing so. Unlike neoclassical
Instead of diminishing returns to capital, endogenous growth economics, a striking feature of the theory is that the
theory assumes constant returns to capital, i.e., doubling institutional framework is not assumed to be exogenous.
capital would double output. Technological change is Instead, it is clearly treated as an object of research such that
assumed endogenous. As a result of the assumption of the way and manner any given institutional arrangements
constant returns to capital, endogenous growth model affect economic behaviour is accorded due consideration
predicts the gap between rich and poor countries remaining (Richter, 2005) [35].
the same or even widening (Lucas, 1988; Mankiw, Romer & This new thinking in economics believes that the cost of
Weil, 1992) [20, 22]. The main contribution of the theory of transacting, which is determined by institutions and
endogenous growth as far as the advancement of economic institutional arrangements, is critical to economic behaviour.
growth is concerned, according to Fanta (2011) [12], is that it It is therefore posited that a country’s institutions, such as its
helps in explaining the existence of worldwide technological legal, political, and social systems, define its economic
process, which is assumed to be exogenous by the performance. The proponents of NIE argue for the need to put
neoclassical model. In this context, infrastructure is seen to in place regulatory mechanisms and other institutional
affect productivity and aggregate output through direct and frameworks in addition to substantive policies so that the
indirect channels. efficient operation and functioning of the “hard” component
This important contribution to knowledge notwithstanding, can be facilitated. The bottom line of this argument is that it
endogenous growth model has succeeded little in explaining is the responsibility of the government to put in place
cross-country income differences because growth is a appropriate institutions that allow the positive effects of
complex phenomenon which cannot be explained by the infrastructure development to reflect on the country’s
theory of the creation of technology alone (Mankiw, 1995) economic performance. This emphasises the proposition that,
[21]
. Although policy reforms yielded some gains in terms of while it is true that inputs and good policy are important
economic growth, these gains were small and far apart. Of components of the economic growth process, it is largely the
particular concern was that for the majority of countries, the quality of institutions that determines wealth accumulation.
instituted reforms had serious adverse impacts on the
wellbeing of the majority of the citizens. Poverty rates tended 2.2 Brief Empirical Review
to increase and also the policies magnified inequalities in the The failure of the traditional economic analysis on the growth
distribution of income. As a result, there were frequent policy effect of infrastructure to capture the mediating role of
reversals resulting in stagnation. In some cases, dissatisfied institutions in the relationship led to the emergence of a new
citizens engaged in violent protests and in others, poor strand. This strand of the literature is preoccupied with the
economic outcomes and the increasing inequality were used need to assess the extent to which institutions affect the
to justify military takeovers. Evidently, many of the policies relationship between the two variables. Studies in this
instituted were not sustainable. Through the 1980s, most category can be broadly divided into two based on their
countries in SSA regressed in many of the dimensions of modelling of the relationship. The first category assumes a
welfare. linear or symmetric relationship, while the second one
assumes a non-linear or asymmetric relationship. The focus
C) New Institutional Economics of this study is, however, limited to the first category of
Following the seminal works of North and Thomas (1973) studies whose analysis is based on the use of a linear
[27]
, Williamson (1985) [43], Matthews (1986) [23], and North interaction model. The model is made up of a linear
(1990) [26], economists have emphasized the instrumentality interaction term between infrastructure and institutions.
of strong institutions to growth (Fanta, 2011) [12]. This is as a One of the studies in the first category in the context of
result of an expanding argument about the inability of countries in SSA is Esfahani and Ramirez (2003) [11]. The
markets alone to ensure economic efficiency. While earlier study examined the role of institutional factors in shaping the
works on growth take the existence of institutions as given, growth effects of infrastructure in 75 countries out of which
more recent works showed the flaw in such approach. In 19 are from SSA between 1965 and 1995. Using instrumental
particular, the failure of both the neoclassical and endogenous variable (IV)/two stage least squares (2SLS) technique, the
375 | P a g e
International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Growth Evaluation www.allmultidisciplinaryjournal.com
results showed significant growth effects of infrastructure in regards institutions as “soft” infrastructure, i.e., regulatory
the data set in which the contribution of infrastructure is mechanisms and other institutional frameworks that must be
affected by institutional factors. Also, Garlick (2008) [14] put in place to facilitate the efficient operation and
investigated the relationship among infrastructure, output and functioning of the “hard” component. In countries with good
institutional quality in South Africa using time series data institutions, investments in infrastructure are both privately
over the period 1960-2006. Results of their univariate beneficial to individuals and also create a positive return for
cointegrating autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) and society as a whole. In countries with poor institutions,
multivariate cointegrating vector error correction model however, the higher returns to investments in rent-seeking
(VECM) estimations revealed that institutions are an activities that plunder the wealth of others, through lobbying
important factor in the infrastructure-output nexus, although and lawsuit abuse, for example—draw significant resources
the exact form of this relationship is not clear. into these privately beneficial, but socially unproductive
In addition, Okoh and Ebi (2013) [30] examined the effect of activities.
the interaction of infrastructure investment and institutional In the absence of strong institutions, the link between
quality in Nigeria using the pair-wise Granger causality infrastructure spending and growth is weakened by evidence
approach. Findings revealed that the effects of the interaction of low efficiency of public investment, and where a high
between infrastructure investment and institutional quality on degree of inefficiency and/or waste, often distorts the impact
economic growth are insignificant. Furthermore, Damijan of infrastructure investment, leading to poorly executed
and Padilla (2014) [9] investigated the impact of various types and/or ineffective projects. The prevalence of corruption in
of infrastructure investment on Gross Domestic Product such a setting reduces the quality of infrastructure investment
(GDP) per capita growth conditional on institutional and its economic benefits, in addition to raising the cost of
advancement and foreign co-financing. The study used panel infrastructure. Awarding public procurement contracts within
data on Egypt, Morocco, Tunisia, Namibia and South Africa the context of a corrupt system may lead to inferior public
for the period 1990-2010 as well as the fixed effects infrastructure and services. This is because when the
approach. Results showed that infrastructure projects are government official saddled with the responsibility of
long-term sustainable in a less corrupt environment. Finally, monitoring infrastructure projects is corrupt, he or she may
Kodongo and Ojah (2016) [19] assessed whether infrastructure allow the use of substandard materials. In weak government
availability and quality act through the mediating effects of quality conditions, therefore, new investment in
institutions to impact economic growth for a panel of 45 SSA infrastructure may respond more to political and individual
countries from 2000 to 2011. Using the system GMM, the interests than to economic and collective ones.
study found that a largely insignificant effect of infrastructure Weak institutions will not only reduce the rate of return to
access and quality on economic growth due to Africa’s new investment in infrastructure, but will also affect the rate
relatively low institutional quality which has made of return to existing stock. A common phenomenon in
infrastructure less effective as a growth catalyst. developing countries where governments are ineffective is
Some important points can be drawn from the brief empirical the poor condition of existing infrastructure (roads with
review above. One, existing empirical evidence on the role of potholes, water and sanitation facilities in bad state, buildings
institutions in mediating the effect of infrastructure on the in need of serious repairs, etc.). More often than not, new
growth of SSA countries is not conclusive. Two, the existing projects are undertaken while the existing ones are
studies did not capture the recent changes in the trend of abandoned to deteriorate as a result of poor maintenance
infrastructure in the selected countries. Finally, the system culture. Also, in cases of very high incidence of corruption,
GMM technique employed by Kodongo and Ojah (2016) [19], operation and maintenance on the physical infrastructure may
whose analysis is close to the one done by this current study, be purposely reduced so that some infrastructures may
has some limitations. The System GMM lacks the capacity to deteriorate quickly to the point that they will need to be built
to capture cross-section dependence and slope parameter again, thus affording some high-level officials the
homogeneity (Amin et al., 2022; Chudik & Pesaran, 2015; opportunity of collecting commission from the enterprise that
Sarafidis et al., 2008; Saygin & Iskenderoglu, 2022) [2, 6, 38]. will handle the project. By and large, we have a situation in
To correct this second limitation, scholars have suggested the which the deterioration in the existing infrastructure retards
use of the Cross-Sectional-Autoregressive Distributed Lag growth more than the rate at which the new ones add to it.
(CS-ARDL) estimator. Another important advantage of CS- From the NIE perspective, therefore, modelling the growth
ARDL is its ability to yield robust estimates even when effects of infrastructure without incorporating the quality of
available dataset is relatively small (Amin et al., 2022) [2]. institutions will yield inconsistent results. Hence, the analysis
This current study was therefore conducted to address the in this study is based on the assumption that the quality of
limitations in the existing empirical literature in the context institutions affects output through the effect that institutions
of countries in SSA. have on the productivity of infrastructure. This is opposed to
the usual practice of implicitly assuming an underlying set of
3. Methodology good institutions. The proposition that emanates from the
This section presents the methodology that is employed to position adopted is that countries with strong institutions
achieve the objectives of the study. Specifically, it presents benefit more from infrastructure development policies as
the theoretical framework, estimating model, techniques of strong institutions enhance the efficient use of infrastructure
analysis, as well as measurements and sources of data. assets.
376 | P a g e
International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Growth Evaluation www.allmultidisciplinaryjournal.com
where ln denotes natural logarithm, y is real GDP per 3.4 Definitions of Variables and Sources of Data
The data employed in this study is a panel of forty-one (41)
worker, yt 1 is lagged real GDP per worker, k is physical SSA countries over the period 1996-2020. The list of the
capital per worker, x is infrastructure per worker, q is selected countries is presented in the appendix section.
institutional quality, q ln k is the interaction term between Details of the measurement of variables and sources of data
institutional quality and physical capital, q ln x is the
used for analysis are shown in Table 1. The table shows that
economic growth, which is the dependent variable, is
interaction term between institutional quality and physical measured using real GDP per capita. Gross capital formation
capital, the disturbance term is assumed to have two is employed to measure investment in physical capital.
orthogonal components: the fixed effects, i , and the Physical measures of infrastructure rather than monetary ones
are used. Due to data availability, the study considered four
idiosyncratic shocks, v , i denotes country, while t is time out of the five infrastructure sub-sectors (telecommunications,
series observation. electric power, clean water and improved sanitation). Using
In equation (1), emphasis is on the statistical significance of the Principal Component Analysis (PCA) method, the four
the interaction coefficient 5 . Depending on its sign, it can be sub-sectors are built into a synthetic index summarising
inferred whether infrastructure and institutions are complements different dimensions of infrastructure in line with Badalyan
or substitutes in the growth process. A negative coefficient et al (2015), Calderón et al. (2015) as well as Chakamera and
will indicate that infrastructure development is more effective Alagidede (2017).
in boosting economic growth in countries with weak Following Kurul (2017), Helliwell, Huang, Grover, and
institutions (Effiong, 2015) [10]. In other words, a negative Wang (2018), Seth (2018), as well as and Sondermann
interaction (i.e. 5 0 ) provides evidence of substitutability (2018), institutional quality was measured using the
between infrastructure and institutions. On the other hand, a indicators developed by Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi
(2010). The three authors have provided measures of national
positive interaction (i.e. 5 0 ) would imply that the growth
institutional environments through their work on the World
effects of infrastructure are enhanced in a strong institutional Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI). The WGI
environment, thus supporting the complementarity of have lately become one of the most commonly used
infrastructure and institutions. indicators of governance or institutional quality in empirical
studies undertaken by academics as well as policymakers.
3.3 Technique of Data Analysis The WGI dataset summarizes six dimensions of institutional
The main objective of this study is to examine the interactive quality or governance as follows: Voice and Accountability
influence of infrastructure and institutions on economic (VAC), Political Stability and Absence of Violence/Terrorism
growth in SSA. This objective is achieved by estimating (PSV), Government Effectiveness (GEF), Regulatory
equation (1) using the CS-ARDL in view of its strength over Quality (RQL), Rule of Law (ROL), as well as Control of
other panel data estimators especially the System GMM. Corruption (COC). The scores range between −2.5 and +2.5.
However, the validity of the CS-ARDL depends on the The classification by Omilola and Akanbi (2014) is adopted
existence of cross-sectional dependence and slope parameter in order to categorise institutional quality at different levels.
heterogeneity (Saygın & Iskenderoglu, 2022) [39]. In view of For the purpose of analysis, the study used an indicator of the
this, the study tested the two conditions to confirm the overall quality of institutions by combining all six
validity and reliability of the estimates obtained from the dimensions into a single index using the PCA method.
empirical analysis.
377 | P a g e
International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Growth Evaluation www.allmultidisciplinaryjournal.com
378 | P a g e
International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Growth Evaluation www.allmultidisciplinaryjournal.com
4.2 Cross-Sectional Dependence, Heterogeneity and under cross-sectional dependence. Based on the results in
Order of Integration Table 3, the Cross-Sectional Augmented Im–Pesaran–Shin
Prior to estimating equation (1) using the CS-ARDL (CIPS) test proposed by Pesaran (2007) was employed for
estimator, this study carried out some important tests for the this purpose. The results of the test in Table 5 shows that the
purpose of obtaining estimates that are reliable. The first variables are of mixed orders, i.e., they are integrated of
among these tests is the cross-section dependence (CD) test, orders zero and one. Thus, these results as well as the findings
which also helps to choose the unit root test that is appropriate of the presence of CD and homogeneity tests confirm that the
for determining the orders of integration of the series used for CS-ARDL approach is the appropriate tool for estimating
analysis. In lie with extant studies such as Nathaniel (2021), equation (1).
the CD tests proposed by Pesaran (2004) was employed for
this purpose. The results of the test, which are reported in Table 5: Panel Unit Roots Test Results
Table 3, show the existence of cross-sectional dependence in Variable CIPS (Level) CIPS (1st Difference)
each series. lnGDPPC -1.489 -5.327***
lnLAGGDPPC 0.091 7.318***
Table 3: Cross-Sectional Dependence Test Results lnPCP 1.539 5.184***
Breusch–Pagan Pesaran scaled Pesaran lnINF 2.103** -
Variable IIQ 1.047 10.824***
LM LM CD
lnGDPPC 559.8701*** 50.4327*** 20.5748*** Source: Authors’ computations (2022) based on WDI and WGI of
lnLAGGDPPC 474.0912*** 41.8361*** 16.9754*** the World Bank (2021).
lnPCP 855.8923*** 70.5290*** 7.8934*** Notes: ln denotes natural logarithm, GDPPC represents real GDP
lnINF 1421.6267*** 122.6984*** 35.4512*** per capita; LAGGDPPC represents real GDP per capita from
IIQ 505.6634*** 67.9523*** 24.9030*** previous period; PCP represents physical capital per capita; INF
represents index of infrastructure stock; and IIQ represents index of
Source: Authors’ computations (2022) based on WDI and WGI of
the World Bank (2021). institutional quality. *** and ** denote statistical significance at 1%
and 5% levels, respectively.
Notes: ln denotes natural logarithm, GDPPC represents real GDP
per capita; LAGGDPPC represents real GDP per capita from
previous period; PCP represents physical capital per capita; INF 4.3 Interactive Influence of Infrastructure and
represents index of infrastructure stock; and IIQ represents index of Institutions on Growth
institutional quality. *** denotes statistical significance at 1%. Table 6 presents the results obtained from the estimation of
equation (1) using the CS-ARDL estimator. The table shows
The second test is the homogeneity test which is required for that the error correction term (ECT) is negative and
determining the appropriate unit roots and cointegration significant. This implies that the system returns to
estimator. Following Sanyin and Indes (2022), the Delta Test equilibrium in case of a shock that causes a disequilibrium. It
proposed by Pesaran and Yamagata (2008) was employed for also implies that a stable cointegrating relationship exists
this purpose. The results of the test, which are presented in among the variables in the long-run. More specifically, the
Table 4, show that economic growth is homogenous among coefficient implies that the short-run speed of adjustment
the selected countries. towards the long-run equilibrium is 67.2% per year, which is
equivalent to about one and half years.
Table 4: Delta Test for Slope Heterogeneity The coefficient of LAGGDPPC is negative and significant
Coefficient p -value in the long run, implying that per capita convergence holds
true in SSA. This finding is consistent with the prediction of
1.768 0.127
Mankiw et al. (1992) [22] that the SSA region will form a
adj. 1.8562 0.116
homogenous set of countries in many respects particularly in
(HAC) -1.372 0.193 the long run. In contrast, the coefficient of the series is
adj. -1.438 0.188 positive and significant in the short run, implying that per
Source: Authors’ computations (2022) capita convergence does not hold in SSA. This finding is not
surprising because, contrary to the prediction of Mankiw et
The third test is the panel unit roots test which was conducted al. (1992) [22], the SSA does not form a homogenous set of
to investigate the stationarity of homogenous panel series countries in many respects. Countries in the region vary
379 | P a g e
International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Growth Evaluation www.allmultidisciplinaryjournal.com
strongly in terms of natural endowments, educational system, In countries where such behaviour is not constrained by
macroeconomic targets, population structure, political institutional frameworks, there exists the possibility of
administration etc. All these factors tend to affect their per rendering fixed capital formation an unreliable determinant
capita income growth. As a result, the convergence of growth. For instance, the prevalence of corruption may
hypothesis as predicted by Mankiw et al. (1992) [22] may not bias commercial and public sector decision-making
apply to SSA in the short run. Overall, these findings indicate processes, leading to investment decisions that are relatively
that, while countries in SSA can show individual differences unproductive.
in the short run, they tend to converge to form a bloc in the The coefficients of ln INF and IIQ ln INF are both
long run. positive, but only the latter is significant in the long run. This
The coefficients of ln PCP and IIQ ln PCP are positive and implies that infrastructure has no significant effect on growth,
negative, respectively and significant in the long run. This and institutional quality lacks the necessary stimulus to make
implies that physical capital exerts a positive effect on it significant. Similarly, the two series are positive, and only
growth, but institutional quality acts as a drag that leaks out the latter is significant in the short run. This means that
the growth benefits of capital on growth. In contrast, the institutions and infrastructure are complements and any
coefficients of the two series are both negative and weakly improvement in the stock of infrastructure will promote
significant in the short run. This implies that physical capital institutional quality and vice versa. As a result of this, one
constitutes a drag to the growth process, while institutional can say that infrastructure is as important in explaining per-
framework aggravates this negative effect. These results are capita and growth differentials as institutions.
not surprising given that only better institutions increase the The coefficient of institutional quality is positive in both the
contribution of physical capital to output. Hall et al. (2010) long and short run, and the effect is significant in the short
[17]
explained that increases in capital retard growth in run only. This implies that the variable does not affect growth
countries characterised by weak institutions because in the long run. Rather, the effect of institutions on output in
additions to the capital stock tend to be devoted to rent- the long run is entirely captured by its effect on the
seeking and other activities that are not socially productive. productivity of infrastructure.
380 | P a g e
International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Growth Evaluation www.allmultidisciplinaryjournal.com
381 | P a g e
International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Growth Evaluation www.allmultidisciplinaryjournal.com
382 | P a g e