Block 1
Block 1
Managerial Economics
Indira Gandhi
National Open University
School of Management Studies
BLOCK 1
INTRODUCTION TO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS 5
BLOCK 2
DEMAND AND REVENUE ANALYSIS 69
BLOCK 3
PRODUCTION AND COST ANALYSIS 131
BLOCK 4
PRICING DECISIONS 217
COURSE DESIGN AND PREPARATION TEAM
Prof. K. Ravi Sankar
Director. SOMS, *Prof. V. L. Mote (Retd.)
IGNOU, New Delhi II M, Ahmedabad
Pro. Qamar Ahsan
*Prof. G.S. Gupta
Retd . Prof. of Economics and Vice Chancellor,
IIM, Ahmedabad
Magadh University, Bihar
Prof. K.V. Bhanu Murthy *Prof. Arindam Banik
Former Dean IMI, New Delhi
Faculty of Commerce and Business
Delhi School of Economics, Delhi *Prof. Atmanand
MDI , Gurgaon
Prof. Sunitha Raju
Indian Institute of Foreign Trade
*Prof. Rajat Kathuria
New Delhi
IMI, New Del hi
Dr. Utpal Chattopadhyay
Associate Professor *Dr. C.G. Naidu
National Institute of Industrial Engineering, Planning & Development Division
Mumbai IGNOU, New Del hi
Prof. Biswajit Nag
Prof. Kamal Vagrecha
Indian Institute of Foreign Trade
School of Management Studies,
New Delhi
IGNOU, New Delhi
Dr. Alka Mittal
Associate Professor Prof. Nayantara Padhi
G.G. Singh Indraprastha University, Delhi School of Management Studies
IGNOU, New Delhi
Pro f. G. Subbayamma
School of Management Studies,
Sh. T.V. Vijay Kumar
IGNOU, New Delhi
School of Management Studies
Prof. Srilatha IGNOU, New Delhi
School of Management Studies,
IGNOU, New Delhi Course Coordinator and Editor:
Dr. Leena Singh
Prof. Neeti Agrawal SOMS, IGNOU
School of Management Studies, New Delhi
IGNOU, New Delhi
Prof. Anjali C. Ramteke
School of Management Studies
IGNOU, New Delhi
This course (MCO-021) is adopted from the MMPC-010: Managerial Economics, and the course
coordinator for adopted course MCO-021 is Dr. Anupriya Pandey, SOMS, IGNOU
Acknowledgement : Parts of this course is adopted from the earlier MS-09: Managerial Economics
course and the persons marked with (*) were the original contributors and the profiles are as it was in
that material.
PRINT PRODUCTION
Mr. Tilak Raj
Assistant Registrar,
MPDD, IGNOU, New Delhi-110 068
July, 2022
© Indira Gandhi National Open University, 2022
ISBN : 978-93-5568-272-7
All rights reserved. No part of this work may be reproduced in any form, by mimeograph or any other
means, without permission in writing from the Indira Gandhi National Open University.
Further information about the School of Health Sciences and the Indira Gandhi National Open University
courses may be obtained from the University’s office at Maidan Garhi, New Delhi-110 068.
Printed and published on behalf of the Indira Gandhi National Open University, New Delhi by the
The Registrar, MPDD, IGNOU.
Laser Typesetting : Akashdeep Printers, 20-Ansari Road, Daryaganj, New Delhi-110002
Printed at : Akashdeep Printers, 20-Ansari Road, Daryaganj, New Delhi-110002
MCO-021: MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
Managerial Economics can be viewed as an application of that part of
microeconomics that focuses on topics such as risk, demand, production, cost,
pricing, and market structure. Understanding these principles will help to develop
a rational decision-making perspective and will sharpen the analytical framework
that the executive must bring to bear on managerial decisions.
Individuals and firms interact in both the product and the factor markets. Prices
of outputs and inputs are determined in these markets and guide the decisions of
all market participants. The firm is an entity that organizes factors of production
in order to produce goods and services to meet the demands of consumers and
other firms. In a market system, the interplay of individuals and firms is not
subject to central control. The prices of both products and factors of production
guide this interaction. Within firms, however, transactions and information costs
are reduced. The size of the firm is limited because transaction costs within the
firm will rise as the firm grows, and because management skill is limited.
It is assumed that the goal of the firm is to maximize the value of the firm or the
present value of all future profits, defined as revenue less all costs, explicit and
implicit. Implicit costs such as the remuneration and interest that owners and
managers earn are not accounted and may result in an inefficient allocation of
resources. The objective of profit maximization is subject to legal, moral,
contractual, financial, and technological constraints. Some economists argue that
the firm’s objective is a “satisfactory” level of profit rather than maximum profit.
The principal-agent problem arises where the owner of a firm and the manager
of that firm have different objectives. The problem can be solved by tying part of
the manager’s salary to profits and /or changes in the price of the firm’s stock.
Profit plays two primary roles in the free-market system. First, it acts as a signal
to producers to increase or decrease the rate of output, or to enter or leave an
industry. Second, profit is a reward for entrepreneurial activity, including risk
taking and innovation. In a competitive industry, economic profits tend to be
transitory. The achievement of high profits by a firm usually results in other
firms increasing their output of that product, thus reducing price and profit. Firms
that have monopoly power may be able to earn above-normal profits over a
longer period; such profit does not play a socially useful role in the economy.
Different types of pricing strategies are adopted, keeping in mind, the varying
market structure for products.
The primary role of economics in management is in making optimizing decisions
where constraints apply. The application of the principles of managerial economics
will help manager ensure that resources are allocated efficiently within the firm,
and that the firm reacts to changes in the economic environment.
Block 1
1.0 Objectives
1.1 Introduction
1.2 Fundamental Nature of Managerial Economics
1.3 Scope of Managerial Economics
1.4 Appropriate Definitions
1.5 Managerial Economics and other Disciplines
1.6 Economic Analysis
1.7 Basic Characteristics: Decision-Making
1.8 Let Us Sum Up
1.9 Terminal Questions
1.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you hould be able to:
understand the nature and scope of managerial economics;
familiarize yourself with economic terminology;
develop some insight into economic issues;
acquire some information about economic institutions; and
understand the concept of trade-offs or policy options.
1.1 INTRODUCTION
For most purposes economics can be divided into two broad categories,
microeconomics and macroeconomics. Macroeconomics as the name
suggests is the study of the overall economy and its aggregates such as Gross
National Product, Inflation, Unemployment, Exports, Imports, Taxation
Policy etc. Macroeconomics addresses questions about changes in
investment, government spending, employment, prices, exchange rate of the
rupee and so on. Importantly, only aggregate levels of these variables are
considered in the study of macroeconomics. But hidden in the aggregate data
are changes in output of a number of individual firms, the consumption
decision of consumers like you, and the changes in the prices of particular
goods and services.
Although macroeconomic issues are important and occupy the time of media
and command the attention of the newspapers, micro aspects of the economy
are also important and often are of more direct application to the day to day
problems facing a manager. Microeconomics deals with individual actors in
the economy such as firms and individuals. Managerial economics can be
thought of as applied microeconomics and its focus is on the interaction of
firms and individuals in markets.
There are many general insights economists have gained into how the
economy functions. Economic theory ties together economists’ terminology
and knowledge about economic institutions. An economic institution is a
physical or mental structure that significantly influences economic decisions.
Corporations, governments, markets are all economic institutions. Similarly
cultural norms are the standards people use when they determine whether a
particular activity or behaviour is acceptable. For example, Hindus avoid
meat and fish on Tuesdays. This has an economic dimension as it has a direct
impact on the sale of these items on Tuesdays. Further, economic policy is
the action usually taken by the government, to influence economic events.
And finally, economic reasoning helps in thinking like an economist.
Economists analyze questions and issues on the basis of trade-offs i.e. they
compare the cost and the benefits of every issue and make decisions based on
those costs and benefits.
The market is perhaps the single most important and complex institution in
our economy. A market is not necessarily a physical location, but a
description of any state that involves exchange. The exchange could be
instantaneous or it could be over time i.e. exchange which is agreed today but
where the transaction takes place, say after 3 months. You will learn in this
course the myriad functions that markets perform, most significantly bringing
buyers and sellers together. Markets could be competitive or monopolistic,
with a large number of firms or a small number of firms, with free entry and
exit or government licensing restricting entry of firms and so on. The major
point is that firms operate in different types of markets and use the well-
established principles of managerial economics to improve profitability.
Managerial economics draws on economic analysis for such concepts as cost,
demand, profit and competition. It attempts to bridge the gap between the
10
purely analytical problems that intrigue many economic theorists and the Scope of Managerial
day-to-day decisions that managers must face. It offers powerful tools and Economics
approaches for managerial policy-making. It will be relevant to present here
several examples illustrating the problems that managerial economics can
help to address. These also explain how managerial economics is an integral
part of business. Demand, supply, cost, production, market, competition,
price etc. are important concepts in real business decisions.
Coordination,
An activity or an ongoing process,
A purposive process, and
An art of getting things done by other people.
What to produce?
How to produce? and
For whom to produce?
These three choice problems have become the three central issues of an
economy as shown in figure 1.1. Economics has developed several concepts
and analytical tools to deal with the question of allocation of scarce resources
among competing ends. The non-trivial problem that needs to be addressed is
how an economy through its various institutions solves or answers the three
crucial questions posed above. There are three ways by which this can be
achieved. One, entirely by the market mechanism, two, entirely by the
government or finally, and more reasonably, by a combination of the first two
approaches. Realistically all economies employ the last option, but the
relative roles of the market and government vary across countries. For
example, in India the market has started playing a more important role in the
11
Introduction to economy while the government has begun to withdraw from certain
Managerial Economics activities. Thus, the market mechanism is gaining importance. A similar
change is happening all over the world, including in China. But there are
economies such as Myanmar and Cuba where the government still plays an
overwhelming part in solving the resource allocation problem. Essentially,
the market is supposed to guide resources to their most efficient use. For
example if the salaries earned by MBA degree holders continue to rise, there
will be more and more students wanting to earn the degree and more and
more institutes wanting to provide such degrees to take advantage of this
opportunity. The government may not force this to happen, it will happen on
its own through the market mechanism. The government, if anything, could
provide a regulatory function to ensure quality and consumer protection.
In rich countries, markets are too familiar to attract attention. Yet, certain awe
is appropriate. Let us take an incident where Soviet planners visited a
vegetable market in London during the early days of perestroika, they were
impressed to find no queues, shortages, or mountains of spoiled and
unwanted vegetables. They took their hosts aside and said: “We understand,
you have to say it’s all done by supply and demand. But can’t you tell us
what’s really going on? Where are your planners and what are their
methods?”
Monopoly: By reducing his sales, a monopolist can drive up the price of his
good. His sales will fall but his profits will rise. Consumption and production
are less than the efficient amount, causing a deadweight loss in welfare.
The labour market, many economists believe, is another such ‘market for
lemons’. This may help to explain why it is so difficult for the unemployed to
price themselves into work.
When markets fail, there is a case for intervention. But two questions need to
be answered first. How much does market failure matter in practice? And can
governments put the failure right? Markets often correct their own failures. In
other cases, an apparent failure does nobody any harm. In general, market
failure matters less in practice than is often supposed.
Pricing Problem: Fixing prices for the products of the firm is an important
decision-making process. Pricing problems involve decisions regarding
various methods of prices to be adopted.
Activity 1
15
Introduction to 2. Which statement is true of the basic economic problem?
Managerial Economics
(i) The problem will exist as long as resources are limited and
desires are unlimited.
(ii) The problem exists only in less developed countries.
(iii) The problem will disappear as production expands.
(iv) The advancement of technology will cause the problem to
disappear.
Statistics: Statistics helps in empirical testing of theory. With its help, better
decisions relating to demand and cost functions, production, sales or
distribution are taken. Managerial economics is heavily dependent on
statistical methods.
16
Management Theory and Accounting: Maximization of profit has been Scope of Managerial
Economics
regarded as a central concept in the theory of the firm in microeconomics. In
recent years, organisation theorists have talked about “satisficing” instead of
“maximizing” as an objective of the enterprise. Accounting data and
statements constitute the language of business. In fact the link is so close that
“managerial accounting” has developed as a separate and specialized field in
itself.
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
3. Name the kind of economic analysis that is appropriate for each of the
following:
The best way to get acquainted with managerial economics and decision
making is to come face to face with real world decision problems.
India is one of the biggest retail markets in the world in terms of size and the
growth potential in future. An American multinational retail company looked
at this potential and decided to choose among different alternatives of
entering foreign markets such as strategic partnership, joint venture, FDI,
wholly owned subsidiary etc. Joint ventures were chosen as the first step of
entering the new market keeping in mind several economic and regulatory
restrictions (of India as 100% FDI was not allowed in multi brand retailing).
It decided to enter India in 2007 via joint venture with an Indian enterprise by
setting up cash-and-carry wholesale outlets where it planned to supply to an
Indian retail company which would help it in getting share in consumer
market of India. But this did not fulfill the dream of the multinational and this
venture did not survive for long and ended in 2014.
18
The American retail giant had two options; to leave India or stay back. The Scope of Managerial
company stayed back as it looked at the consumer market potential and it had Economics
invested too much already. It kept looking at different options and then in
2018 it acquired 77% stake of an Indian e-commerce company for $16 billion
(about `1.05 lakh crore). The decision to acquire the Indian e-commerce
company was well thought as it is one of the biggest e-commerce company in
India which would give access to a large number of consumers of India and
on the other hand would help in giving direct competition to its old rival an
American e-commerce company. These types of major decision-making
problems are faced by managers in business world and the managers have to
choose the best alternative from the available alternatives for the firm.
Haynes, W.W. (1979). Managerial Economics: Analysis and Cases (3rd Ed.).
Business Publications, Inc., Texas.
Baumol, W.J. (1979). Economic Theory and Operations Analysis (4th Ed.).
Prentice Hall India Pvt. Ltd., New Delhi.
21
Introduction to T
Managerial Economics
UNIT 2 THE FIRM: STAKEHOLDERS, O
OBJECTIVES AND DECISION
ISSUES
Structure
2.0 Objectives
2.1 Introduction
2.2 Objective of the Firm
2.3 Value Maximization
2.4 Alternative Objectives of the Firms
2.5 Goals of Real World Firms
2.6 Firm’s Constraints
2.7 Basic Factors of Decision-Making: The Incremental Concept
2.8 The Equi-Marginal Principle
2.9 The Discounting Principle
2.10 The Opportunity Cost Principle
2.11 The Invisible Hand
2.12 Let Us Sum Up
2.13 Terminal Questions
2.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you should be able to:
understand the rationale for existence of firms;
understand the concept of economic profit and accounting profit;
appreciate the use of opportunity cost; and
differentiate between various objectives of the firm.
2.1 INTRODUCTION
The firm is an organisation that produces a good or service for sale and it
plays a central role in theory and practice of Managerial Economics. In
contrast to non-profit institutions like the ‘Ford Foundation’, most firms
attempt to make a profit. There are thousands of firms in India producing
large amount of goods and services; the rest are produced by the government
and non-profit institutions. It is obvious that a lot of activities of the Indian
economy revolve around firms.
However, the size of the firm has to be limited because as the firms grow
larger, a point is reached where the cost of internal transaction becomes equal
to or greater than the cost of transaction between firms. When such a stage is
reached, it puts a limit to the size of the firm. Further, the cost of supplying
23
Introduction to additional services like legal, medical etc. within the firm exceeds the cost of T
O
Managerial Economics purchasing these services from other firms; as such services may be required
occasionally.
Let us consider the size of different kinds of firms around us and try to
understand the reasons for such differences. Why are service firms generally
smaller than capital-intensive firms like steel and automobile producing
companies What is the reason that a number of firms are choosing the BPO
route? A part of the explanation must lie in the fact that it is cheaper to
outsource than to absorb that activity within the firm. Consider a firm that
needs to occasionally use legal service. Under what conditions will it choose
to hire a full time lawyer and take her on its rolls and under what conditions
will the firm outsource the legal activity or hire legal services on a case-by-
case basis. Naturally, the answer depends upon the frequency of use for legal
services. The transaction cost framework demonstrates that the firm will
contract out if the cost of such an arrangement is lower and will prefer in-
house legal staff when the opposite is true.
Some firms mentioned below are different from above. They may provide
service to a group of clients for example, patients or to a group of its
24 members only.
The Firm: Stakeholders,
a) Universities. Objectives and Decision
Issues
b) Public Libraries.
c) Hospitals.
d) Museums.
e) Churches.
f) Voluntary Organisations.
g) Cooperatives.
h) Unions.
i) Professional Societies, etc.
The concept of a firm plays a central role in the theory and practice of
managerial economics. It is, therefore, valuable to discuss the objectives of a
firm.
Sales `90,000
Less: Cost of Goods Sold `40,000
Gross Profit: `50,000
Less:
Advertising `10,000
Depreciation `10,000
Utilities `3,000
Property Tax `2,000
Misc. `5,000 =`30,000
Net Accounting Profit `20,000
The economist recognizes other costs, defined as implicit costs. These costs
are not reflected in cash outlays by the firm, but are the costs associated with
foregone opportunities. Such implicit costs are not included in the accounting
statements but must be included in any rational decision making framework.
There are two major implicit costs in this example. First, the owner has `1
lakh invested in the business. Suppose the best alternative use for the money
is a bank account paying a 10 per cent interest rate. This risk less investment
would return `10,000 annually. Thus, `10,000 should be considered as the
implicit or opportunity cost of having `1 lakh invested in the retail store.
25
Introduction to Let us consider the second implicit cost, which includes the manager’s time T
O
Managerial Economics and talent. The annual wage return on an M.Com degree may be taken as
`35,000 per year. This is the implicit cost of managing this business rather
than working for someone else. Thus, the income statement should be
amended in the following way in order to determine the economic profit:
Sales `90,000
Less: Cost of Goods Sold `40,000
Gross Profit: `50,000
Less:
Advertising `10,000
Depreciation `10,000
Utilities `3,000
Property Tax `2,000
Misc. `5,000 =`30,000
Thus, we can say that economic profit equals the revenue of the firm minus
its explicit costs and implicit costs. To arrive at the cost incurred by a firm, a
value must be put to all the inputs used by the firm. Money outlays are only a
part of the costs. As stated above, economists also define opportunity cost.
Since the resources are limited, and have alternative uses, you must sacrifice
the production of a good or service in order to commit the resource to its
present use. For example, if by being the owner manager of your firm, you
sacrifice a job that offers you ` 2,00,000 per annum, then two lakhs is your
opportunity cost of managing the firm. Similarly, if Suresh Kumar was not
playing cricket, he could have earned a living (perhaps, not such a good one!)
by being a cricket commentator. Suresh’s opportunity cost of playing cricket
is the amount he could have earned being a cricket commentator.
Profit plays two primary roles in the free-market system. First, it acts as a
signal to producers to increase or decrease the rate of output, or to enter or
leave an industry. Second, profit is a reward for entrepreneurial activity,
including risk taking and innovation. In a competitive industry, economic
profits tend to be transitory. The achievement of high profits by a firm
usually results in other firms increasing their output of that product, thus
reducing price and profit. Firms that have monopoly power may be able to
earn above-normal profits over a longer period; such profit does not play a
socially useful role in the economy.
Activity 1
( )= + + ……+
(1 + ) (1 + ) (1 + )
=
(1 + )
Assumed profit is equal to total revenue (TR) minus total cost (TC), then the
value
of the firm can also be stated as:
TR − TC
Value of the irm =
(1 + r)
28
The Firm: Stakeholders,
2.4 ALTERNATIVE OBJECTIVES OF THE Objectives and Decision
FIRMS Issues
Another economist Robin Marris assumes that owners and managers have
different utility functions to maximize. The manager’s utility function (Um)
and Owner’ utility functions (Uo) are:
As is true with most economic models, the application will depend upon the
situation and one cannot say that a particular model is better than the other. In
general, one can assert that the profit maximising assumption seems to be a
reasonable approximation of the real world, although in certain cases there
might be a deviation from this objective.
29
Introduction to T
Managerial Economics
2.5 GOALS OF REAL WORLD FIRMS O
By now we know that firms that maximize profits are not just concerned
about short-run profits, but are more concerned with long-term profits. They
may not take full advantage of a potential monopolistic situation, for
example, many stores have liberal return policies; many firms spend millions
on improving their reputation and want to be known as ‘good’ citizens. The
decision maker’s income is often a cost of the firm. Most real-world
production takes place in large corporations with 8-9 levels of management,
thousands of stakeholders and boards of directors. Self-interested decision
makers have little incentive to hold down their pay. If their pay is not held
down, firm’s profit will be lower. Most firms manage to put some pressure on
managers to make at least a pre-designated level of profit.
For example, the manager may be given a basic salary plus potentially large
bonuses for meeting such goals as attaining a specified return on capital,
growth in earnings, and/or increase in the price of the firm’s stock. With
regard to the latter, the use of stock options awarded to top managers is a
most effective way to ensure that managers act in the interest of the
shareholders. Typically, the arrangement provides that the manager is to
receive an option to buy a specified number of shares of common stock at the
current market price for a specified number of years. The only way the
executives can benefit from such an arrangement is if the price of stock rises
during the specified term. The option is exercised by buying the shares at the
specified price, and the gain equals the increase in share price multiplied by
the number of shares purchased. Sometimes the agreement specifies that the
stock must be held for several years following purchase. Essentially, this
option arrangement makes the manager a de facto owner, even if the option
has not been exercised. In almost every case of a report of unusually high
executive compensation, the largest part of that compensation is associated
with gains from stock options.
Legal Constraints: Both individuals and firms have to obey the laws of the
State as well as local laws. Environmental laws, employment laws, disposal
of wastes are some examples.
Moral Constraints: These imply to actions that are not illegal but are
sufficiently consistent with generally accepted standards of behaviour.
A decision is profitable if
To illustrate the above points, let us take a case where a firm gets an order
that can get it additional revenue of ` 2,000. The normal cost of production of
this order is–
Labour : ` 600
Materials : ` 800
Overheads : ` 720
Selling and administration expenses : ` 280
Full cost : ` 2,400
Comparing the additional revenue with the above cost suggests that the order
is unprofitable. But, if some existing facilities and underutilized capacity of
the firm were utilized, it would add much less to cost than ` 2,400. For
example, let us assume that the addition to cost due to this new order is, say,
the following:
Labour : ` 400
Materials : ` 800
Overheads : ` 200
Total incremental Cost : ` 1,400
In the above case the firm would earn a net profit of ` 2000 – ` 1400 = ` 600,
while at first it appeared that the firm would make a loss of ` 400 by
32 accepting the order.
The worth of such a decision can be judged on the basis of the following The Firm: Stakeholders,
theorem. Objectives and Decision
Issues
Theorem I: A course of action should be pursued upto the point where its
incremental benefits equal its increment costs.
According to the theorem, the firm represented in Table 2.1 will produce only
seven units of output as its Marginal Revenue (MR)= Marginal Cost (MC)1 at
that level of output. As can be calculated from the Table, the MC of 8th unit
is more than its MR. Hence the firm gets negative profit from 8th unit and
thus is advised not to produce it.
1 2 3 4 5 6
1 20 15 5 5.0 -
2 40 29 11 5.5 6
3 60 42 18 6.0 7
4 80 52 28 7.0 10
5 100 65 35 7.0 7
6 120 81 39 6.5 4
7 140 101 39 5.6 0
8 160 125 35 4.4 -4
/ = / = ………= /
Where = marginal utility from good one,
= marginal cost of good one and so on,
/ = / = ……… /
It is easy to see that if the above equation was not satisfied, the decision
makers could add to his utility/profit by reshuffling his resources/input e.g. if
/ > / the consumer would add to his utility by buying more
of good one and less of good two. Table 2.2 summarizes this principle for
different sellers.
= = =8
One may ask how much money today would be equivalent to ` 100 a year
from now if the rate of interest is 5%. This involves determining the present
value of ` 100 to be received after one year. Applying the formula –
100
=
1.05
we obtain ` 95.24,
The same analysis can be extended to any number of periods. A sum of ` 100
two years from now is worth:
100
=
1.05
= `90.70 today.
In general, the present value of a sum to be received at any future date can be
found by the following formula:
=
(1 + )
35
Introduction to PV = present value, Rn = amount to be received in future, i = rate of interest, T
Managerial Economics n = number of years lapsing between the receipt of R. O
If the receipts are made available over a number of years, the formula
becomes:
= + ++ + ….+
1+ (1 + ) (1 + ) (1 + )
=
(1 + )
The present value of an annuity can be thought of as the sum of the present
values of each of several amounts. Consider an annuity of three ` 100
payments at the end of each of the next three years at 10 percent interest. The
present value of each payment is
1
= 100
1.10
1
= 100
1.10
1
= 100
1.10
1 1 1
= 100 + 100 + 100
1.10 (1.10) (1.10)
OR
1 1 1
= 100 + +
1.10 (1.10) (1.10)
36
The present value of this annuity is The Firm: Stakeholders,
Objectives and Decision
PV = 100 (0.9091 + 0.8264 + 0.7513) = 100 (2.4868) = 248.68 Issues
Although this approach works, it clearly would be cumbersome for annuities
of more than a few periods. For example, consider using this method to find
the present value of a monthly payment for forty years if the monthly interest
rate is 1 per cent. That would require evaluating the present value of each of
amounts of 480 months (40×12 = 480) In general, the formula for the present
value of an annuity of A rupees per period for n periods and a discount rate of is
1 1 1
= = + ⋯+
(1 + ) (1 + ) (1 + )
38
ii) The production of the goods require more of one factor than the other. The Firm: Stakeholders,
For example, the production of guns may require more capital than Objectives and Decision
Issues
that of butter. Hence, as more and more of capital is used in the
manufacture of guns, the opportunity cost of guns is likely to increase.
Let us assume that an economy is at point A where it uses all its resources in
the production of butter. Starting from A, the production of 1 unit of guns
requires that AC units of butter be given up. The production of a second unit
of guns requires that additional CD units of butter be given up. A third
requires that DE be given up, and so on. Since DE>CD>AC, and so on, it
means that for every additional unit of guns more and more units of butter
will have to be sacrificed, or in other words, the opportunity cost keeps on
increasing.
The opportunity cost of the first few units of guns would initially be low and
those resources, which are more efficient in the production of guns move
from, butter production to gun production. As more and more units of guns
are produced, however, it becomes necessary to move into gun production,
even for those factors, which are more efficient in the production of butter.
As this happens, the opportunity cost of guns gets larger and larger. Thus,
due to increasing opportunity costs the PPC is concave.
If the PPC curve were to be a straight line, the opportunity cost of guns
would always be constant. This would mean equal (and not increasing
amounts) of butter would have to be forgone to produce an additional unit of
guns. The assumption of constant opportunity costs is very unrealistic. It
implies that all the factors of production are equally efficient either in the
production of butter or in the production of guns.
For many of the choice society make opportunity costs tend to increase as we
choose more and more of an item. Such a phenomenon about choice is so
common, in fact, that it has acquired a name: the principle of increasing
marginal opportunity cost. This principle states that in order to get more of
something, one must give up ever-increasing quantities of something else. In
other words, initially the opportunity costs of an activity are low, but they
increase the more we concentrate on that activity.
Producers are led by the profit motive to produce those goods and services
which the consumers want. They try to do this at the minimum possible cost
in order to maximize their profits. Moreover, if there is competition among a
number of producers, they will each try to keep the price of their product low
in order to attract the consumers. The goods produced are made available in
the market by traders. They also act in their own self-interest. However, in a
self-regulating economy, there is rarely any shortage of goods and services. 39
Introduction to Decisions to save and invest are also taken by the individual economic units. T
Managerial Economics For example, households save some of their income and deposit part of it in O
the banks, or invest it in shares and debentures and so on. The producers
borrow from the banking system and also issue shares and debentures to
finance their investments. In turn, they reinvest a part of their profits.
All the economic functions have been carried out by individuals acting in
isolation. There is no government or centralized authority to determine who
should produce what and in what quantity, and where it should be made
available. Yet in a self-regulating economy there is seldom a shortage of
goods and services. Practically everything you want to buy is available in the
market. Thus according to Adam Smith, the economic system is guided by
the “invisible hand”. In a more technical way we can say that the basic
economic problems in a society are solved by the operation of market forces.
5. Use the following interest rates for government bonds for the risk-free
discount rate and answer the following:
b) What is the present value of a firm with a 5 years life span that
earns the following stream of expected profit at the year-end?
FURTHER READINGS
Dean, J. (1951). Managerial Economics. PrenticeHall.
Mote, V.L., Paul, S., & Gupta, G.S. (2016). Mangerial Economics Concepts
and Cases, Tata McGraw-Hill, New Delhi.
Koutsoyiannis, A. (2018). Modern Microeconomics (2nd Ed.). Macmillan
Publishers India Pvt. Ltd. 41
Introduction to
Managerial Economics
UNIT 3 BASIC CONCEPTS & TECHNIQUES
Structure
3.0 Objectives
3.1 Introduction
3.2 Opportunity Set
3.3 Variables and Constants
3.4 Derivatives
3.5 Partial Derivatives
3.6 Optimization Concept
3.7 Regression Analysis
3.8 Specifying the Regression Equation
3.9 Estimating the Regression Equation
3.10 Decision Under Risk
3.11 Uncertainty Analysis and Decision Making
3.12 Role of Managerial Economist
3.13 Let Us Sum Up
3.14 Terminal Questions
3.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you should be able to:
identify a wide range of techniques used in managerial economics;
apply the techniques to understand the meaning of the results; and
identify the strengths and weaknesses of the different methods.
3.1 INTRODUCTION
The manager needs various techniques to assist and help him in making
decisions that will ultimately maximize the value of the firm. These
techniques and tools are quantitative in nature. The introduction of some
commonly used tools used in managerial decision making becomes
imperative.
In this unit we are going to discuss some basic techniques which would be
helpful in understanding the concept of managerial economics, in turn
helping us to apply these techniques as and when required.
O
X
If the consumer spends all his income on X, he can buy 20 units of X with no
Y (B). or if he spends all on good Y, then he buys 25 units of Y and no X
(A). All other alternatives of spending Rs. 100 will lie on the line AB. Hence
the area OAB constitutes the consumer's opportunity set.
44
Figure 3.5: Cubic Function Basic Concepts &
Techniques
1. Demand (Linear)
Figure 3.6
Figure 3.7
45
Introduction to 3. Production (Short run) (Cubic)
Managerial Economics
Figure 3.8
Figure 3.9
46
Basic Concepts &
3.4 DERIVATIVES Techniques
In case of ‘averages’
∗ =
∗ =
∗ =
∗ >1
47
Introduction to
Managerial Economics ∗ <1
∗ =1 .
Examples:
(i) If = ( ; )
Then =2
And = 2 =2
/ / /
(ii) If =√ = ( ) =
/
/ /
Then = = / =
/
/ /
And = = / =
48
(iii) If = 4x + 3xy + 5y Basic Concepts &
Techniques
Then =8 +3
Then = 3 + 10
The second order partial derivatives indicate that the function has been
differentiated partially twice with respect to a given variable, all other
variables being held constant. These are shown (in case of function Z=f(x,y))
by or and . Thus shows the rate of change of first order partial
derivatives fx with respect to x and y held constant.
Conditions
=0 =0
Y=y(x)
(assumed)
Some economic uses f these conditions are discussed below. Given a firm’s
demand function, P=45 – 0.5Q and the average function, AC=Q -8Q + 57 +
2/Q, we have to find the level of output Q which
a) Maximizes total revenue and,
b) Maximizes profit.
Solution
a) Since demand function is P=45-0.5Q the total revenue function will be,
TR=PQ = (45-0.5Q) Q=45 – 0.5 Q
To maximize TR, we find the derivative and set it to 0 (the first order or
necessary condition)
Now, = 45 − 2 (0.5)
= 45 − = 0
∴ = 45
Since = 45 −
∴ = −1
50
which is negative. Hence total revenue is maximized when output is 45 Basic Concepts &
Techniques
units.
b) From profit function
= −
=( )×
= (Q − 8Q + 57 + 2/Q) Q = Q − 8Q − 57Q + 2
= (45 − 0.5 )
= 45 − 0.5Q
After substituting TR and TC, we get
= 45 − 0.5Q − Q + 8Q − 57Q − 2
∴ = 45 − − 3Q − 16Q − 57
= −3Q + 15Q − 12
Now set =0
= −3Q + 15Q − 12 = 0
dividing by -3
Q + 5Q + 4 = 0
or (Q-4) (Q-1)=0
=4 1
There are many situations where the objective function has to be maximized
or minimized subject to certain constraints present in the problem. Thus a
consumer may be maximizing utility subject to the income constraint.
The techniques used to analyze such problems are based on that used for
unconstrained problems. The constrained problem is converted into
unconstrained one with the help of Lagrange Multiplier Technique and then
the latter is solved. In this technique, the objective function and constraint is
combined in one expression (Lag range expression) such that the constrained
maximization or minimization problems are reduced to unconstrained ones.
For example,
Maximize = − + 8x + 20
Subject to ≤ 2
(function of single independent variable)
Thus both test give x=4 as the above of the variable. This is the value at
which the objective function attains unconstrained maximum. However, the
problem has a constraint x=2. Thus we have to consider the function only up
to value of x=2 (graph) starting from x = −2. The maximum value of the
function is then 32 which occurs when x=2. Thus the constrained maximum
of the function = −( − 4) + 36 with constraint x=2 would occur at x=2
and not x=4.
= −2( − 4) + = 0
= ( − 2) = 0
52
The last equation gives x=2. Hence the constrained maximum occurs at x=2. Basic Concepts &
Techniques
The problem with two independent variables can also be solved with
Lagrangian technique. To find out whether the optimized value is maximum
or minimum however, requires second derivative test as well as use of some
more determinants not to be discussed here
Activity 1
i) = 10 − 0.4
ii) = 15 − 2 + 4P
iii) = 100 + 0.8
3. Maximize = 10 − 2y
Subject to x+y=12
Answers:
This equation can be used to compute the total cost of producing various
levels of output. If, for example, the manager wishes to produce 30 units of
output, the total cost can be calculated as
Thus, in order for the cost function to be useful for decision making, the
manager must know the numerical value of the parameters.
The values of the parameters are often obtained by using a technique called
regression analysis. It determines the mathematical relation between a
dependent variable and one or more explanatory variables.
Y=a+bX
Intercept parameter: The parameter that gives the value of Y at the point
where the regression line crosses the Y-axis.
Slope parameter: The slope of the regression line, b = ∆Y/∆X, or the change
in Y associated with a one-unit change in X.
The figure shows the true relation between sales and advertising
expenditures. If a firm chooses to spend nothing on A, its sales are expected
to be `100 crores per month. If the firm spends `30 crores on A then it can
expect sales of `250 crores (=100 + 5 × 30). ∆S/∆A = 5, i.e., for every 1 unit
increase on advertising, the firm can expect a 5 unit increase in sales.
Regression involves identifying and calculating specific relationships
between the independent variables and the dependent variable. It involves a
number of stages which are described in another section.
Activity 2
2. In Figure 3.12, what will be the monthly sales of the firm, if the
advertising expenditure is increased from `30 crores to `40 crores per
month?
Q = a + bP + cA
In each case, the ‘a’ term represents the intercept of the-line drawn from the
equation with the vertical axis. The ‘b’ and ‘c’ terms represent the regression
coefficients with respect to own price and advertising respectively. These
show the impact of each of these variables on product demand. Once they
have been estimated it is possible to predict the level of demand for any set of
values of the independent variables simply by substituting them into the
equation.
56
The exponential form of the equation has the advantage that it can be Basic Concepts &
Techniques
rewritten to give direct estimates of the respective elasticities of demand for
the independent variables. This is done by taking the log-linear form of the
equation which in this case would be:
Where ‘b’ and ‘c’ are the own price and advertising elasticities of demand
respectively. This is a much easier approach than calculating elasticities
through use of the linear form which involves using the equation:
to calculate the elasticities in each case. In this case values of P and Q need to
be obtained from the data set. Usually average values are substituted in the
above equation to estimate elasticities. This idea will be explored in greater
detail in Block 2.
Which of the two forms of equation is chosen depends upon the expected
relationship between the variables being included. In practice, however, the
actual relationship between them may not be known in advance. In this case,
the decision maker may experiment with both forms of equation in order to
find the one which most closely fits the data.
Activity 3
1. What are the things which the decision maker needs to keep in mind
while collecting and selecting data on the relevant variables?
Assume that data on cost and output have been collected for each of seven
production periods and are reported in Table 3.2. Note that there is a cost of
Rs. 100 associated with an output rate of zero. This represents the fixed cost
of the capital input, which must be paid regardless of the rate of output.
These data are shown as points in Figure 3.1. They suggest a definite upward
trend, but they do not trace out a straight line. The problem is to determine
the line that best represents the overall relationship between Y and X. One
approach would simply be to “eyeball” a line through these data in a way that
the data points were about equally spaced on both sides of the line. The
coefficient ‘a’ would be found by extending that line to the vertical axis and
reading the Y-coordinate at that point. The slope, ‘b’, would be found by
taking any two points on the line, { , } and
{ , } and using the slope formula
−
=
−
Although this approach could be used, the method is quite imprecise and can
be employed only when there is just one independent variable. What if
production cost depends on both the rate of output and the size of the plant?
To plot the data for these three variables (total cost, output, and plant size)
would require a three dimensional diagram; it would be nearly impossible to
eyeball the relationship in this case. The addition of another independent
variable, say average skill levels of the employees, would place the data set in
the fourth dimension, where any graphic approach is hopeless.
There is a better way. Statisticians have demonstrated that the best estimate
of the coefficients of a linear function is to fit the line through the data points
58
so that the sum of squared vertical distances from each point to the line is Basic Concepts &
Techniques
minimized. This technique is called ordinary least-squares regression (OLS).
including excel. Based on the output and cost data in Table 3.1, the least-
squares regression equation will be shown to be
= 87.08 + 12.21X
This equation is plotted in Figure 3.13. Note that the data points fall about
equally on both sides of the line. Consider an output rate of 5. As shown in
Table 3.2, the actual cost associated with this output level is 150. The value
predicted by the regression equation, referred to as , is 148.13. That is, =
87.08 + 12.21(5) =148.13. The deviation of the actual Y value from the
predicted value (i.e., the vertical distance of the point from the line), − is
referred to as the residual or the prediction error.
There are many values that might be selected as estimators of ‘a’ and ‘b’, but
only one of those sets, defines a line that minimizes the sum of squared
deviations [i.e., that minimizes ( − ) ]. The equations for computing
the least-squares estimators and are:
( − )
=
( − )
and
= − ̅
Using the basic cost of output data and the example, the necessary
calculations are shown in Table 3.3. Substituting the appropriate values into
the following equations, the estimates and are computed to be:
( − )( − )
= = 12.21
( − )
= 237.14 = 12.29 ( − ) ( − )( − )
=511.40 =6,245.71
Thus the estimated equation for the total cost function is:
= 87.08 + 12.2
The estimate of the coefficient a is 87.08. This is the vertical intercept of the
regression line. In the context of this example, = 87.08 is an estimate of
fixed cost. Note that this estimate is subject to error because it is known that
the actual fixed cost is ` 100. The value of is an estimate of the change in
total cost for a one-unit change in output (i.e., marginal cost). The value of ,
` 12.21, means that, on an average, a one-unit change in output results in
` 12.21 change in total cost. Thus is an estimate of marginal cost.
Activity 4
1. Suppose, for example, that the estimation process had given the
following figures for the coefficients:
A state of nature is a condition that may exist in the future and that will have
a significant effect on the success of a strategy. For example, the manager
may not be aware of the economic conditions in the future. The possible
states of nature may be normal, recession or boom.
= ( )
= ( − )
61
Introduction to The coefficient of variation is a measure of risk per unit of money of
Managerial Economics return.
These statistics have a direct application in measuring the expected return and
risk associated with any business decision for which a set of outcomes and
their probabilities have been determined. The expected value, standard
deviation, and the coefficient will be referred to as risk-return evaluation
statistics.
Having defined risk and reviewed some of the related terminology, the task
now is to develop quantitative measures of return and risk and to show how
they are applied in decision making. We know that individuals have different
preferences concerning risk taking. It is also important that such preferences
be identified and their effect on decisions evaluated. Rational decision
making requires that the expected return be determined and the risk be
measured, and that there be information about the manager’s preference for
risk. The expected value, the standard deviation, and the coefficient of
variation will be referred to as risk-return evaluation statistics.
Let us take an example where two investments, I and II, are being considered.
Both investments require an initial cash outlay of Rs.100 and have a life of
five years. The return on each depends on the rate of inflation over the five-
year period. Of course, the inflation rate is not known with certainty, but
suppose that the collective judgment of economists is that the probability of
no inflation is 0.20, the probability of moderate inflation is 0.50, and the
probability of rapid inflation is 0.30. The outcomes are defined as the present
value of net profits for the next five years. These outcomes for each state of
nature (i.e., rate of inflation) for each investment are shown in table 3.3.
= 111.36
62
= = 111.36/240 = 0.46 Basic Concepts &
Techniques
= 0.2(150) + 0.5(200) + 0.3(250) = 205
= 0.2(150 − 205) + 0.5(200 − 205) + 0.3(250 − 205) = 0.35
0.35
= = 0.17
205
The expected return for investment I of ` 240 is higher than for Investment II
`.205, but I is a riskier investment because = 111.36 is greater than =
0.35. Also, risk per rupee of expected returns for I ( = 0.46) is higher than’
for ( = 0.17). Which is the better investment? The choice is not clear. It
depends on the investor’s attitude about taking risks. A young entrepreneur
may well prefer I, whereas an older worker investing in a retirement account
where risk ought to be minimized might prefer II. Generally higher returns
are associated with higher risk.
Decision Tree
A decision tree shows two or more branches at each point where a decision or
event (state of nature) leads to the various outcomes. The decision tree
approach can be directly applied to managerial decision-making. A firm
entering a new market may decide to build a small or large plant (managerial
decisions). This has no probabilities. But there may be stochastic elements
(an outcome determined by chance) associated with each decision e.g.,
reaction of a major competitor and the economic condition. The competitor
may react by starting a national, regional, or a new advertising program. The
probability of each occurrence will depend on the size of the plant.
Each vertex or node indicates a decision to be taken by one of the players, the
number within the rectangle indicating whose turn it is to move. There need
not actually be two players, one of the players can be regarded as nature or
chance. The main advantage of using a decision tree is that it helps one to
isolate each chain and follow it through to the very end.
Risk is more common in the real world. A situation with more than one
possible outcome to a decision such that the probability of each of these
outcomes can be measured is a risk situation. For example, tossing of a coin
(i.e. 50-50) or investing in a stock. The greater the number and range of
outcomes, the greater is the risk associated with the decision or action.
Uncertainty is a situation where there is more than one possible outcome to a
decision but the probability of each specific outcome occurring is not known
or even meaningful. This may be due to insufficient information or instability
in the nature of variables. In extremes cases of uncertainty, the outcomes may
itself be not clear. Decision making under uncertainty is necessarily
subjective.
When health trends set in, the fast food restaurant noticed that its burger
sales were dipping in USA. To attract health-conscious customers back it
decided to launch new type of healthier burgers which contained 40% less fat
and 30% less calories. They launched new type of burgers based on several
assumptions such as their customers wanted healthier options and were ready
to pay more for that. It was a very calculated risk taken by the company
based on the ongoing trend of health.
The product which was launched as a game changer in fast food market,
failed to attract the customers and it was discontinued within one year. It was
a major blow to the global fast food giant which was struggling to provide
fast food at its restaurants. There were several explanations given by experts
on why this product could not stabilize. But one thing is clear, what
customers say/want and do are completely different things altogether, so
there is always uncertainty in business environment which cannot be
eliminated.
This case clearly shows that even a well-conceived strategy is risky and can
lead to results estimated to have a small probability of occurrence. Indeed
the failure rate for new products in the United States is a stunning 80 percent.
4. Suppose a seller has two markets to serve. The demand schedules in them
are given in the table. Suppose that he has 1400 units to sell and
maximize profits thereby. What prices will he set in the two markets?
Apply equi-incrementalism principle to get your answer. Could you have
applied equi-marginalism.
66
Market A Market B Basic Concepts &
Techniques
Price ` Quantity Price ` Quantity
50 400 60 600
40 600 50 800
30 900 40 1100
20 1000 34 1400
[Hint: First get total revenue in each market by multiplying price with
quantity.]
5. A firm is producing two products x and y, and has the following profit
function = 64 − 2 + 4 − 4 + 32 − 14 . Find the profit
Maximizing levels of output for each of the two products. (Ans.: x = 40, y
= 24, p = 1650).
6. Maximize = 10 −2
Subject to x + y = 12
7. What are central or basic problems of an economy?
8. Which problems of an economy constitute the subject matter of
microeconomics
Appendix
B. Additional rule: = ( )+ ( )
= +
C. Product rule: = ( )∗ ( )
= ( ) = ( )
( )
D. Quotient rule: = ( )
( ) − ( )
=
E. Chain rule: = [ ( )]
= ∗
G. Exponential rule: =
= 67
Introduction to
Managerial Economics
FURTHER READINGS
Koutsoyiannis, A. (2018). Modern Microeconomics (2nd Ed.). Macmillian
Publishers India
Lewis, W.C., Jain, S.K., & Peterson, H.C. (2005). Managerial Economics (4th
Ed.). Pearson.
68