Pricing With Market Power
Pricing With Market Power
Third Edition
Chapter 10
Pricing with Market Power
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Managerial Problem
Sale Prices
• Heinz dominates the ketchup market in the United States, Canada, and the United
Kingdom. When Heinz goes on sale, switchers purchase Heinz rather than other brand.
• How can Heinz’s managers design a pattern of sales that maximizes Heinz’s profit?
Under what conditions does it pay for Heinz to have a policy of periodic sales?
Solution Approach
• We need to examine how monopolies and other noncompetitive firms set prices. These
firms can earn a higher profit setting different prices for the same good or service
depending on consumer’s willingness to pay (nonuniform pricing).
Empirical Methods
• We will review the characteristics and conditions for each of these types of nonuniform
pricing.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Learning Objectives (1 of 2)
10.1 Conditions for Price Discrimination
List the conditions necessary to price discriminate
10.2 Perfect Price Discrimination
Show how perfect price discrimination extracts all surplus
from consumers
10.3 Group Price Discrimination
Describe how a firm sets different prices for various
consumer groups to raise its profit
10.4 Nonlinear Price Discrimination
Demonstrate how a firm can increase its profit by charging
prices based on the quantities consumers buy
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Learning Objectives (2 of 2)
10.5 Two-Part Pricing
Illustrate how a firm may raise its profit by charging an
access fee and a per-unit price
10.6 Bundling
Determine when a firm can increase its profit by selling
related products in a bundle
10.7 Peak-Load Pricing
Explain why firms charge higher prices in periods of peak
demand
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.1 Conditions for Price Discrimination (1 of 6)
• Price discrimination occurs when a firm charges different prices for a good.
– Common Confusion: It can’t pay for a firm to charge some consumers a
different price than others.
– However, many (but not all) firms can profit by price discriminating.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.1 Conditions for Price Discrimination (2 of 6)
Price discrimination increases profit above the uniform pricing level through two
channels:
• Channel 1: Higher Prices for Some
– Price discrimination can extract additional C S from consumers who place
a high value on the good.
– In panel a of Table 10.1, the theater sells the same number of seats but
makes more money from the college students. Students pay $20, seniors
pay $10, and the theater captures all C S from both groups.
• Channel 2: Attract New Customers
– Price discrimination can simultaneously sell to new customers who would
not be willing to pay the profit-maximizing uniform price.
– In panel b of Table 10.1, the theater increases profit by selling five more
tickets to seniors. Students pay $20 as before, seniors pay $10, and
neither group enjoys any C S.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 10.1
Theater Profits Based on the Pricing Method Used
Pricing Profit from 10 College Students Profit from 20 Senior Citizens Total Profit
Pricing Profit from 10 College Students Profit from 5 Senior Citizens Total Profit
*The theater price discriminates by charging college students $20 and senior citizens $10.
Notes: College students go to the theater if they are charged no more than $20. Senior citizens are
willing to pay up to $10. The theater’s marginal cost for an extra customer is zero.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.1 Conditions for Price Discrimination (3 of 6)
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.1 Conditions for Price Discrimination (4 of 6)
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.1 Conditions for Price Discrimination (5 of 6)
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.1 Conditions for Price Discrimination (6 of 6)
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.2 Perfect Price Discrimination (1 of 3)
How a Firm Perfectly Price Discriminates
• A firm with market power that can prevent resale and has full information
about its customers’ willingness to pay price discriminates by selling each
unit at its reservation price—the maximum amount any consumer would pay
for it.
• The maximum price for any unit of output is given by the height of the demand
curve at that output level.
• Perfectly Price Discrimination: Price = M R
– A perfectly price-discriminating firm’s marginal revenue is the same as its
price. So, the firm’s marginal revenue curve is the same as its demand
curve.
– In Figure 10.1, the monopoly sells 4 units at prices equal to
Each consumer pays its reservation
price, the demand curve is the M R curve. The firm’s revenue is $18 and if
fixed cost is zero, its profit equals
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 10.1
Perfect Price Discrimination
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.2 Perfect Price Discrimination (2 of 3)
Perfect Price Discrimination is Efficient But Harms Some
Consumers
• Perfect price discrimination is efficient: It maximizes the sum of
consumer surplus and producer surplus.
• But, all the surplus goes to the firm, consumer surplus is zero.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 10.2
Competitive, Single-Price, and Perfect Price Discrimination Outcomes
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.2 Perfect Price Discrimination (3 of 3)
• Firms can still increase profits significantly with imperfect individual price
discrimination:
– Charge individual-specific prices to different consumers, which may or
may not be the consumers’ reservation prices.
• Transaction Costs and Price Discrimination
– It is often too difficult or costly to gather information about each
customer’s reservation price for each unit of the product (high transaction
costs).
– However, recent advances in computer technologies have lowered these
transaction costs.
– Hotels, car and truck rental companies, cruise lines, airlines, and other
firms are increasingly using individual price discrimination.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.3 Group Price Discrimination (1 of 8)
• Group price discrimination occurs when potential customers are divided into
two or more groups with different prices for each group (single price within a
group).
• The two conditions for group price discrimination are:
– Consumer groups may differ by age, location, or in other ways.
– A firm must have market power, be able to identify groups with different
reservation prices and prevent resale.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.3 Group Price Discrimination (2 of 8)
A Graphical Approach for Group Price Discrimination
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 10.3
Group Pricing of the Tesla S Car
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.3 Group Price Discrimination (3 of 8)
Group Price Discrimination: Using Calculus
• Profit:
– Total profit is the sum of the American and European profits In each
country, profit is revenue minus cost (both depend on the Q sold in each country).
– To maximize profit: differentiate the monopoly’s profit function with respect to each
quantity, holding the other quantity fixed, and set derivatives equal to zero.
• American Market:
–
– The monopoly sets M R = M C in this market,
so
• European Market:
–
– The monopoly sets M R = M C in this market,
so
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.3 Group Price Discrimination (4 of 8)
Prices and Elasticities
• We know
• We also know from Chapter 9 that
• So,
• Implication:
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.3 Group Price Discrimination (6 of 8)
Managerial Implication:
Discounts
• To make sure that price
discrimination pays,
managers should only give
discounts to those
consumers who are willing
to incur a cost, such as
their time, to obtain the
discount.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.3 Group Price Discrimination (7 of 8)
Managerial Implication: Discounts
• Consumers willing to spend extra time to obtain a discount are typically more
price sensitive than others.
• Skilled managers use a variety of methods to induce customers to self-identify
as being price sensitive by incurring a cost.
– Coupons—firms divide customers into two groups, charging coupon
clippers less than nonclippers.
– Airline Tickets—airline customers indicate whether they are likely to be
business travelers or vacationers. Airlines offer high-price tickets with no
strings attached and low-price fares with restrictions.
– Reverse Auctions—Priceline.com and others use a name-your-own-price
or “reverse” auction to identify price-sensitive customers.
– Rebates—Why do many firms offer a rebate of, say, $5 instead of
reducing the price on their product by $5? The reason is that a consumer
must incur an extra, time-consuming step to receive the rebate.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.3 Group Price Discrimination (8 of 8)
Effects of Group Price Discrimination on Total Surplus
• Group price discrimination results in inefficient production and consumption.
However, how T S compares to other results?
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.4 Nonlinear Price Discrimination (1 of 2)
• Many firms, with market power
and no resale, are unable to
determine high reservation prices.
However, such firms know a
typical customer’s demand curve
is downward sloping.
• Such a firm can price discriminate
by letting the price each customer
pays vary with the number of
units the customer buys
(nonlinear price discrimination).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.4 Nonlinear Price Discrimination (2 of 2)
• Block Pricing Versus Single Price
– A firm charges one price per unit for the first block purchased and
a different price per unit for subsequent blocks. Used by utility
firms.
– In panel a of Figure 10.4, the firm charges a price of $70 on any
quantity between 1 and 20—first block—and $50 for the second
block. In panel b, the firm can set only a single price of $30. When
block pricing, C S is lower, T S is higher and deadweight loss is
lower. The firm and society are better off but consumers lose.
– Common Confusion: Quantity discounts help consumers.
However, Changing from uniform monopoly pricing to nonlinear
price discrimination often reduces consumer surplus, as in Figure
10.4.
– The more block prices that a firm can set, the closer the firm gets
to perfect price discrimination.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 10.4
Block Pricing
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.5 Two-Part Pricing (1 of 2)
• With two-part pricing the firm charges each consumer a lump-sum access
fee for the right to buy as many units of the good as the consumer wants at a
per-unit price.
– A consumer’s overall expenditure for amount q consists of an access fee,
A, and a per-unit price, p. So, expenditure is E = A + p q.
– To do it, a firm must have market power, know how individual demand
curves vary across its customers and prevent resale.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 10.5
Two-Part Pricing with Identical Consumers
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.5 Two-Part Pricing (2 of 2)
Two-Part Pricing with Differing Consumers
• Two-part pricing is more complex if consumers have different demand curves.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 10.6
Two-Part Pricing with Different Consumers
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.6 Bundling (1 of 7)
Bundling Characteristics
• Firms with market power often pursue a pricing strategy called bundling.
– Bundling consists of selling multiple goods or services for a single price.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.6 Bundling (2 of 7)
Pure Bundling
• M S Office is currently a pure bundle. Main components, Word and
Excel, are only sold as part of the bundle.
• Whether it pays for Microsoft to sell a bundle or sell the programs
separately depends on how reservation prices for the components
vary across customers.
• Bundling increases profits if reservation prices are negatively
correlated, and it reduces profits if they are positively correlated.
• We assume the marginal cost of producing an extra copy of either
type of software is essentially zero; fixed cost is negligible so that the
firm’s revenue equals its profit; the firm must charge all customers the
same price—it cannot price discriminate.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.6 Bundling (3 of 7)
Profitable pure bundling example
• Table 10.2 shows the reservation prices for two customers and two products.
– The reservation prices are negatively correlated: The customer who has
the higher reservation price for one product has the lower reservation
price for the other product.
– If the firm sells the two products separately, it maximizes its profit by
charging $90 for the word processor and selling it to both consumers, and
selling the spreadsheet program for $50 to both consumers. The firm’s
total profit from selling the programs separately is $280 ($180 + $100).
– If the firm sells the two products in a bundle, it maximizes its profit by
charging 160, selling to both customers, and earning $320. Pure bundling
is more profitable.
– Pure bundling is more profitable because the firm captures more of the
consumers’ potential C S—their reservation prices.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 10.2
Negatively Correlated Reservation Prices
Processor
Alisha $120 $50 $170
Bob $90 $70 $160
Profit-maximizing price $90 $50 $160
Units sold 2 2 2
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.6 Bundling (4 of 7)
Nonprofitable pure bundling example
• Table 10.3 shows the reservation prices for two customers and two products.
– The reservation prices are positively correlated: A higher reservation
price for one product is associated with a higher reservation price for the
other product.
– If the programs are sold separately, the firm charges $90 for the word
processor, sells to both consumers and earns $180. However, it makes
more charging $90 for the spreadsheet program and selling it only to
Carol. The firm’s total profit if it prices separately is $270 ($180 + $90).
– If the firm uses pure bundling, it maximizes its profit by charging $130 for
the bundle, selling to both customers, and making $260.
– Because the firm earns more selling the programs separately, $270, than
when it bundles them, $260, pure bundling is not profitable in this
example. As long as reservation prices are positively correlated, pure
bundling cannot increase the profit.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 10.3
Positively Correlated Reservation Prices
Processor
Carol $100 $90 $190
Dmitri $90 $40 $130
Profit-maximizing price $90 $90 $130
Units sold 2 1 2
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.6 Bundling (5 of 7)
Mixed Bundling
• Consumers are allowed to buy the pure bundle or any of its components separately.
• Table 10.4 shows the reservation prices of four potential customers for two products.
– Aaron, a writer, places high value on the word processing program but has
relatively little use for a spreadsheet. Dorothy, an accountant, has the opposite
pattern of preferences. Brigitte and Charles have intermediate reservation prices
that are negatively correlated.
– If the firm prices each program separately, it maximizes its profit by charging $90
for each product and selling each to three customers. It earns $540 in total.
– If the firm engages in pure bundling, it can charge $150 for the bundle, sell to all
four consumers, and earns $600 total.
– If the firm does mixed bundling, it can charge $160 for the bundle to two
consumers and $120 for each product separately to the other two consumers. It
earns $640 in total.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 10.4
Reservation Prices and Mixed Bundling
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.6 Bundling (6 of 7)
Requirement Tie-In Sales
• Requirement tie-in sales is another form of bundling: Requires customers who buy one
product from a firm to make all concurrent and subsequent purchases of a related
product from that firm.
• This requirement allows the firm to identify heavier users and charge them more per
unit.
• Example
– If a printer manufacturer can require that consumers buy their ink cartridges only
from the manufacturer, then that firm can capture most of the consumers’ surplus.
– Heavy users of the printer, who presumably have a less elastic demand for it, pay
the firm more than light users because of the high cost of the ink cartridges.
– Unfortunately for such a printer manufacturer, the Magnuson-Moss Warranty
Improvement Act of 1975 forbids any manufacturer from using such tie-in
provisions as a condition of warranty.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.6 Bundling (7 of 7)
Managerial Implication: Ties that Bind
• Managers can increase profit by promoting consumer loyalty. Despite the
Magnuson-Moss Act, such loyalty can be induced through warranty provisions.
• Printer firms such as Hewlett-Packard (H P) write their warranties and promote
ads to strongly encourage consumers to use only their cartridges and not to
refill them.
• Are these warranty restrictions and advertising claims sufficient to induce most
consumers to buy cartridges only from H P? Apparently so.
– In 2018, H P prices for a Deskjet 1112 printer and a tri-color ink cartridge
were $29.99 and $37.99, respectively.
– If most customers bought inexpensive cartridges or refills from other
firms, H P would not sell its printer at a rock-bottom price.
– H P demonstrates that the benefits of requirement tie-in sales can be
achieved through careful wording of warranties and advertising.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.7 Peak-Load Pricing (1 of 3)
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.7 Peak-Load Pricing (2 of 3)
• Peak-load pricing: Charging higher prices during periods of peak demand
than in other periods
• Firms commonly use peak-load pricing when they face a production capacity
constraint.
– During the low season, is the demand. The hotel maximizes profit
where The hotel has excess capacity.
– During the high season, is the demand. The firm maximizes profit
where in the vertical section. The price is no excess
capacity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 10.7
Peak-Load Pricing
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
10.7 Peak-Load Pricing (3 of 3)
Dynamic Pricing
• Under dynamic pricing or surge pricing, sellers frequently change prices
based on current market conditions.
• Dynamic pricing is based on the same principle as traditional peak-load pricing
—charging more in times of high demand.
• The difference is that instead of committing to a set pattern of pricing, a seller
using dynamic pricing changes its price at any time, quickly responding to
changing market conditions in “real time.
– Uber’s website indicates that during high-demand situations (bad weather,
rush hours, or special events), “fares may increase to help ensure those
who need a ride can get one.” The Uber mobile app reports a surge
multiplier when surge pricing is in effect.
– Some highway toll authorities use dynamic pricing for special express
lanes. They vary the toll to ensure that the express lane remains
uncongested.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Managerial Solution
Sale Prices
• How can Heinz’s managers design a pattern of sales that maximizes Heinz’s
profit? Under what conditions does it pay for Heinz to have a policy of periodic
sales?
Solution
• By putting Heinz on sale periodically, Heinz’s managers can price discriminate.
• Every n days, the typical consumer buys either Heinz or generic ketchup.
Switchers are price sensitive, always know when Heinz is on sale and buy it.
Loyal customers do not distort their shopping patterns solely to buy Heinz on
sale.
• If there are more switchers than loyal customers, then having sales is more
profitable than selling at a uniform price to only loyal customers.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved