Unit 11
Unit 11
11.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you should be able to:
describe the characteristics of pure/perfect competition and pure
monopoly;
identify the equilibrium conditions for a firm and the industry in a
perfectly competitive situation;
examine price-output decisions under pure monopoly; and
analyze the relevance of pure/perfect competition and pure monopoly.
11.1 INTRODUCTION
In the preceding unit, you have been introduced to the concept of market
structure and the impact it has on the competitive behaviour of firms. You
must have noted that the number and size of the firms is an important
determinant of the structure of the industry and/or market.
In this unit, we shall analyze the behaviour of a firm under two different
market structures, namely, pure/perfect competition and monopoly. The
crucial parameter is the size of the constituent firms in relation to the total 245
Pricing Decisions industry’s output. Throughout this unit, we go by the assumption that the
firms are guided by profit maximization.
4. Both buyers and sellers in the market have perfect knowledge about the
conditions in which they are operating. Buyers know the prices being
charged by different competing sellers and sellers know the prices that
different buyers are offering.
1
Note that you will never pay more than maximum amount. 247
Pricing Decisions from producers to the consumers; i.e. consumers become better off when
there is increased competition. An illustration of this can be gauged from the
conduct of the automobile industry in India since it was deregulated in 1991.
The consumers have benefited from competition in the sector and one can
definitely assert that producer margins (or surplus) have declined to the
benefit of the consumers.
Activity 1
b) What in your opinion is the market structure of grocery stores and why?
25 – 0.5 P = 10 + 1.0 P
or P = 10
Q = 10 + 1.0 (10)
= 20
Figure 11.1 shows that when the market price is at P1, demand and marginal
revenue facing the firm are D1 and MR1. The optimal output for the firm to
produce is at point A, where Marginal Cost (MC) = P1, and the firm will
produce Q1 units of output. At Q1 level of output, the Average Total Cost
(ATC) is less than the price and the firm makes an economic profit.
Suppose the market price falls to P2, price equals MC at point C. Because at
this level of output (Q2) average total cost is greater than price, total cost is
greater than total revenue, and the firm suffers losses. The amount of loss is
the loss per unit (CR) times the number of units produced (Q2).
2
If p=10 and q=1, TR =10; if p = 10 and q=2, TR = 20; MR is thus 10 and so on. MR will always = 10
and therefore will be the same as price as long as price is constant. 249
Pricing Decisions Figure 11.1: Profit Maximizing Equilibrium in the Short Run
At price level P2, demand is D2 = MR2, there is no way that the firm can earn
a profit. This is because at every output level average total cost exceeds price
(ATC > P). The firm will continue to produce only if it loses less by producing
than by closing its operations entirely. When the firm produced zero output,
total revenue would also be zero and the total cost would be the total fixed
cost. The loss would thus be equal to total fixed cost. If the firm produces at
MC = MR2 (point C), total revenue is greater than total variable cost, because
P2 > AVC at Q2 units of output. The firm will be in a position to cover all its
variable costs and still has CD times (as in graph 11.1) the number of units
produced (Q2) left over to pay part of its fixed cost. This way the firm suffers
a smaller loss when it continues production than it shut down its operations.
In the long run, the firm attempts to maximize profits in the same manner as
in the short run, except that there are no fixed costs. All costs are variable in
the long run. Here again the firm takes the market price as given and this
market price is the firm’s marginal revenue. The firm would increase output
as long as the marginal revenue from each additional unit is greater than the
marginal cost of that unit. It would decrease output when marginal cost
exceeds marginal revenue. This way the firm maximizes profit by equating
marginal cost and marginal revenue (MR = MC; as discussed above).
The firm’s long run average cost (LAC) and marginal cost (LMC) curves are
shown in Figure 11.2. The firm faces a perfectly elastic demand indicating
the equilibrium price (Rs. 17) which is the same as marginal revenue (i.e., D
251
Pricing Decisions = MR = P). You may observe that as long as price is greater than LAC, the
firm can make a profit. Therefore, any output ranging from 20 – 290 units
yields some economic profit to the firm. In figure 11.2, B and B1 are the
breakeven points, at which price equals LAC, economic profit is zero, and the
firm can earn only a normal profit.
The firm, however, earns the maximum profit at output level 240 units (point
S). At this point marginal revenue equals LMC and the firm would ideally
select the plant size to produce 240 units of output. Note that in this situation
the firm would not produce 140 units of output at point M, which is the
minimum point of LAC. At this point marginal revenue exceeds marginal
cost, so the firm can gain by producing more output. As shown in figure 11.2,
at point S total revenue (price times quantity) at 240 units of output is equal
to Rs. 4080 (= Rs. 17 * 240), which is the area of the rectangle OTSV. The
total cost (average cost times quantity) is equal to Rs. 2,880 (= Rs. 12 * 240)
which is the area of the rectangle OURV. The total profit is Rs. 1,200 = (Rs.
17 – Rs. 12) * 240, which is the area of the rectangle UTSR.
Thus, the firm would operate at a scale such that long run marginal cost
equals price. This would be the most profitable situation for an individual firm
(illustrated in figure 11.2). Therefore, if the price is Rs. 17.00 per unit, the
firm will produce 240 units of output, generating a profit of Rs. 1,200.00.
This profit is variously known as above normal, super normal or economic
profit. The crucial question that one needs to ask is whether this is a
sustainable situation in a perfectly competitive market i.e. whether a firm in a
perfectly competitive industry can continue to make positive economic profits
even in the long run? The answer is unambiguously no.
This result derives from the assumption that in a perfectly competitive market
there are no barriers to entry. Recall that in a market economy, profit is a
signal that guides investment and therefore resource allocation decisions. In
this case, the situation will change with other prospective entrants in the
industry. The economic force that attracts new firms to enter into or drives
out of an industry is the existence of economic profits or economic losses
respectively. Economic profits attract new firms into the industry whose entry
increases industry supply. As a result, the prices would fall and the firms in the
industry adjust their output levels in order to remain at profit maximization
level. This process continues until all economic profits are eliminated. There
is no longer any attraction for new firms to enter since they can only earn
normal profits. By observing figure 11.2 you should try to work out the price
that will prevail in this market in the long run when all firms are earning
normal profit.
252
Analogous to economic profit which serves as a signal to attract investment, Pricing Under Perfect
Competition and Pure
economic losses drive some existing firms out of the industry. The industry Monopoly
supply declines due to exit of these firms which pushes the market prices up.
As the prices have risen, all the firms in the industry adjust their output levels
in order to remain at a profit maximization level. Firms continue to exit until
economic losses are eliminated and economic profit becomes zero, that is,
firms earn only a normal rate of profit.
Activity 2
Though perfect competition and monopoly are the two extreme cases of market
structure, they both have one thing in common – they do not have to compete
with other individual participants in the market. Sellers in perfect competition
are so small that they can ignore each other. At the other extreme, the
monopolist is the only seller in the market and has no competitors. The market
or industry demand curve and that of the individual firm are the same under
monopoly since the industry consists of only one firm.
The firm would enjoy such super normal profits even in the long run because it
254 is very difficult for new firms to enter in a monopolized market.
The determination of profit maximizing equilibrium output and price under Pricing Under Perfect
Competition and Pure
monopoly is shown in figure 11.3. DD and MR are the downward sloping
Monopoly
demand (or average revenue curve) and marginal revenue curves respectively
of the monopoly firm. AC and MC are its average cost and marginal cost
curves. At point E, MC intersects MR from below. Corresponding to E, the
profit maximizing equilibrium output is OQ. At OQ output, the price is OP =
QR; and average cost is OC = QK. The monopoly profits are equal to price
minus average cost multiplied by output i.e., (OP – OC) * OQ = PC *CK =
PCKR. The rectangle area PCKR represents the super normal profits of the
monopoly firm.
Monopoly Power
The above analysis shows that whereas under perfect competition, price is
equal to marginal cost and profits are normal in the long run; under
monopoly, price is greater than marginal cost and profits are above normal
even in the long run.
Therefore, the monopolist has power to charge a price which is higher than
marginal cost and earn super normal profits. The extent of monopoly power
of a firm can be calculated in terms of how much price is greater than
marginal cost. Recall that a perfectly competitive firm sets P = MC. Thus the
greater the difference, the greater is the monopoly power. Economist A.P.
Lerner devised such an index to measure the degree of monopoly power and
which has come to be known as the Lerner index. According to this index,
the monopoly power of a firm is —
µ = (P – MC)/P
Where
P = Price of the firm’s product
MC = Firm’s marginal cost
µ = (P – MC)/P
µ = (P – MR)/P = 1 – (MR/P)
But (MR/P) = (1-1/e)
µ = 1 – (1 – 1/e)
µ = 1/e
First, their size and capital intensity often puts particular strain on private
capital markets in satisfying their investment needs. In India, in the 1990s
strain was felt instead on the public coffers, and this was a major factor
behind the move towards disinvestment and privatization. Hence, while for
example automobile or chemicals manufacture are also characterized by huge
scale economies, governments have rarely seen it as their role to regulate
companies in these industries. The question for policy makers is what to do
about natural monopolies like power and water supply. Left to themselves,
they will charge monopoly prices and restrict output. The absence of any
competitive threat will also probably leave such organizations wasteful,
inefficient and sluggish. Since all costs can be passed on to the consumers,
256
there will be little incentive for managers to keep them under control. Pricing Under Perfect
Competition and Pure
Experience from, for example, the railways suggests that it will not be long
Monopoly
before the absence of competitive pressures may damage the motives for
innovation and change, so crucial in such capital-intensive sectors. Thus in
some cases a regulator is appointed who must fix the natural monopolist’s
price. In India, privatization of power and telecommunications has been
accompanied by the creation of a regulator, while there is no such institution for
cement, automobile or chemical industry.
The above discussion can also be illustrated with the help of Figure 11.4.
Assume a perfectly competitive industry. We know that price would be Pc
and quantity supplied Qc.
The consumer’s surplus will be the area Pc AD. Now consider output and
price of the profit maximizing monopolist. As indicated in the figure, price
would be Pm and quantity would be Qm. Notice that the monopolist will
charge a higher price and produce a lower quantity as expected. The
consumer surplus is reduced to PmAB. The rectangle Pc Pm BC that was
part of consumer surplus under competition is now economic profit for the
monopolist. This economic profit represents income redistribution from
consumers to producers. Further, there is also a deadweight loss to society
represented by the area BCD that represents loss of consumer surplus that
accrued under competition, but is lost to society because of lower production
levels under monopoly.
If we now consider the reverse case i.e. a monopoly being broken to foster
competition, the result will be transfer of income from producers to
consumers and elimination of deadweight loss. Herein lies the economic 257
Pricing Decisions basis for regulation of monopoly firms. It is to generate the outcomes of
competitive markets and pass these benefits to consumers in the form of
lower prices. If competition exists in markets then arguably, that is the best
regulation. If it does not, and the industry is envisaged to play a social role,
regulation of monopoly becomes an important policy objective.
Activity 3
Perfect competition and monopoly are the two extreme market conditions
which we rarely come across in the real world of business. Then the question
arises as to why study them? It is useful to think of perfect competition and
pure monopoly as extremes with other market structures placed in between.
There are many industries that have most of the characteristics of perfect
competition or monopoly. The two extreme models therefore serve as
benchmarks and provide guidance in making decisions.
Softdrink P pricing decision was clearly crucial to the life of the firm. The
primary background necessary for understanding the pricing decision is a
good understanding of the law of demand – i.e. as price goes up, demand
goes down – and some understanding of the amount by which a price
increase effects a quantity decrease – i.e. the price elasticity of demand. We
258
will start by examining the polar cases of pricing under perfect competition Pricing Under Perfect
Competition and Pure
and pricing under monopoly, and then move on to examining Softdrink P and
Monopoly
C company's situation.
This reasoning, along with the ease of entry for new fish seller, if there is a
profit to be made (which prevents collusion among fish seller already in the
market), ensures that the price being charged is equal to the cost of supplying
an additional fish, or the marginal cost. A fish seller will be a price-taker,
setting her/his price identically to her/his competitors’ prices. A firm is a
monopoly if it has exclusive control over the supply of a product or service.
Therefore, a monopolist, in her/his pricing decisions, cannot consider the
pricing decision of rival firms. So, what does s/he consider?
The smart monopolist considers the incremental effect of his decision, i.e.
what is the revenue to be received from selling one additional unit of a
product and what are the costs of selling one additional unit of a product.
Certainly, if the costs of selling one additional unit of a product exceed the
revenues, the monopolist would certainly not want to sell that additional
product. The law of demand says that s/he could raise the price of her/his
product and thus sell less. Alternatively, if the revenues of selling an
additional unit of a product exceed the costs of selling that unit, the
monopolist should want to sell more units. The law of demand says that s/he
could sell more by lowering his price.
Thus, by setting the price correctly, the monopolist can sell the exact number
of units such that the costs of selling one additional unit exactly equals the
revenues of selling the additional unit, which, by the above reasoning, is the
only optimal price. However, there is an additional complication: the costs of
selling one additional unit do not include any part of the salary of the CEO or
the rental costs of the plant, both must be paid whether or not the additional
unit is sold. Thus, in the long run, if a monopolist cannot cover his overhead
by pricing in the optimal manner, he should shut down.
259
Pricing Decisions The situation involving soft drink P and soft drink C clearly differs from
either of the above scenarios, but what can we learn from both the cases?
First, P clearly saw that C was pricing the six-ounce bottles at 5 cents. By
pricing the 12- ounce bottles at 5 cent also, P made the bet that C would not
cut its price. C did not see the need to cut price because its product was
different from P and it did not fear losing many of its customers. Whether the
gain in revenues resulting from increased demand would offset the loss in
revenue from the lower price depends on the price elasticity of demand. The
price elasticity of demand faced by soft drink P company depends on soft
drink C response to the price cut and the consumer’s responses. As we saw
above, P made the assumption that C would not cut price. P counted on a
highly elastic consumer response, that is the percentage change in quantity
purchased by the consumer due to the lower price, and therefore profits
would accrue to P.
What other concerns you think played a part in the soft drink P company's
decision?
The perfectly competitive firm maximizes profit at a point where price equals
marginal cost. The firm can make an economic profit or loss in the short run,
depending on market price. If the price drops below average variable cost, the
firm should shut down. Or even if the firm is making a profit in the short run,
it may wish to change its plant size or capacity in the long run in order to earn
more profit.
In the real world, few market structures meet the restrictive assumptions for
perfect competition or monopoly. Still, these two models are useful because
many industries have the characteristics of perfect competition or monopoly.
260
Moreover, the perfectly competitive model serves as a benchmark for Pricing Under Perfect
Competition and Pure
evaluating the performance of actual markets and provides guidance for
Monopoly
public policy.
3. Suppose a small locality has a single grocery store selling multiple products.
a. Is it a monopoly?
261
Pricing Decisions
FURTHER READINGS
Mote, V. L., Paul, S., & Gupta, G. S. (2016). Managerial Economics:
Concepts and Cases, Tata McGraw-Hill, New Delhi.
262