LECTURE
NOTES
ON
MACROECONOMIC
PRINCIPLES
Peter
Ireland
Department
of
Economics
Boston
College
[email protected]
http://www2.bc.edu/peter-ireland/ec132.html
Copyright
(c)
2013
by
Peter
Ireland.
Redistribution
is
permitted
for
educational
and
research
purposes,
so
long
as
no
changes
are
made.
All
copies
must
be
provided
free
of
charge
and
must
include
this
copyright
notice.
Ch
24
Measuring
the
Cost
of
Living
Introduction
In
1931,
the
New
York
Yankees
paid
Babe
Ruth
an
annual
salary
of
$80,000.
In
2010,
the
New
York
Yankees
paid
Alex
Rodriguez
an
annual
salary
of
$33
million.
But
then
again,
in
1931
an
ice
cream
cone
cost
a
nickel
and
a
movie
ticket
cost
a
quarter.
More
generally,
the
cost
of
living
has
risen
greatly
since
then.
This
chapter
focuses
on
the
consumer
price
index
or
the
CPI
as
a
measure
of
the
cost
of
living.
The
inflation
rate
is
the
percentage
rate
of
change
in
the
CPI.
Once
we
understand
how
the
CPI
is
constructed
and
how
it
has
behaved
in
the
US,
we
can
return
to
the
question:
who
was
really
paid
more,
after
adjusting
for
inflation,
Ruth
or
Rodriguez?
Outline
1. The
Consumer
Price
Index
A. How
the
CPI
is
Measured
B. Problems
in
Measuring
the
Cost
of
Living
C. The
GDP
Deflator
and
the
CPI
2. Correcting
Economic
Variables
for
the
Effects
of
Inflation
A. Dollar
Figures
at
Different
Points
in
Time
B. Indexation
C. Real
and
Nominal
Interest
Rates
The
Consumer
Price
Index
The
CPI
is
computed
by
the
Bureau
of
Labor
Statistics
(BLS),
a
division
of
the
Department
of
Labor,
to
measure
the
overall
cost
of
goods
and
services
bought
by
a
typical
consumer.
How
the
CPI
is
Measured
Table
1
highlights
the
5
steps
involved
in
measuring
the
CPI:
1. Survey
consumers
to
determine
the
relevant
“basket
of
goods.”
2. Record
the
price
of
each
good
in
each
year.
3. Compute
the
cost
of
the
basket
in
each
year.
4. Choose
a
base
year
and
compute
the
CPI
for
the
current
year:
Cost of the Basket in the Current Year
CPI = × 100
Cost of the Basket in a Base Year
2
5. Compute
the
inflation
rate
as
the
percentage
change
in
the
CPI
from
one
year
to
the
next:
CPI in Current Year − CPI in Previous Year
Inflation Rate = × 100
CPI in Previous Year
The
example
in
Table
1
assumes,
for
simplicity,
that
the
basket
includes
only
two
goods.
Figure
1
illustrates
in
more
detail
what
is
really
in
the
CPI
basket.
In
addition
to
the
CPI,
the
BLS
also
computes
the
producer
price
index
or
the
PPI,
to
measure
the
cost
of
goods
and
services
bought
by
the
typical
firm.
Problems
in
Measuring
the
Cost
of
Living
Three
problems
prevent
the
CPI
from
being
a
perfect
measure
of
the
cost
of
living:
1. Substitution
bias.
2. The
introduction
of
new
goods.
3. Unmeasured
quality
change.
Substitution
bias
arises
because
in
any
given
year
the
prices
of
some
goods
rise
faster
than
others:
-‐ The
basket
holds
the
quantity
of
each
good
purchased
fixed.
-‐ But,
in
fact,
consumers
tend
to
substitute
less
expensive
goods
for
more
expensive
goods.
Does
substitution
bias
cause
the
CPI
to
overstate
or
understand
the
true
change
in
the
cost
of
living?
To
answer
this
question,
return
to
the
example
from
Table
1:
-‐ There,
the
price
of
hot
dogs
rises
at
a
faster
rate
than
the
price
of
hamburgers.
-‐ The
CPI
holds
the
number
of
hot
dogs
and
the
number
of
hamburgers
fixed.
-‐ But,
in
reality,
consumers
are
likely
to
buy
more
hamburgers
and
fewer
hot
dogs.
-‐ Hence
the
true,
changing
basket
of
goods
is
less
expensive
than
the
fixed
basket
used
in
computing
the
CPI.
-‐ The
CPI
therefore
overstates
the
true
change
in
the
cost
of
living.
When
new
goods
are
introduced,
the
true
cost
of
achieving
a
given
level
of
consumer
satisfaction
falls.
-‐ Before
VCRs
and
DVD
players
were
invented,
if
you
wanted
to
see
a
movie,
you
had
to
either
go
to
a
theater
or
wait
for
it
to
come
on
TV.
-‐ Even
after
those
new
goods
were
introduced,
you
could
still
go
to
the
theater
or
watch
movies
on
TV,
but
you
could
also
rent
or
buy
the
video.
-‐ So
a
given
number
of
dollars
spent
watching
movies
could
yield
a
higher
level
of
consumer
satisfaction.
-‐ In
that
sense,
the
cost
of
living
goes
down
when
new
goods
are
introduced,
but
that
effect
does
not
get
captured
by
the
CPI.
-‐ So
it
again
the
CPI
overtstates
the
true
change
in
the
cost
of
living.
Unmeasured
quality
change:
many
types
of
goods
improve
in
quality
over
time.
3
-‐ A
new
cellphone
purchased
today
is
a
lot
better
than
a
cellphone
purchased
two
or
three
years
ago,
even
if
it
sells
at
a
higher
price.
-‐ The
BLS
tries
to
correct
for
this
quality
change.
-‐ But
to
the
extent
that
it
underestimates
the
extent
of
quality
change,
it
again
overstates
the
true
change
in
the
cost
of
living.
Many
economists
believe
that
the
because
of
the
combined
effects
of
these
three
problems,
the
inflation
rate
based
on
the
CPI
overstates
the
true
increase
in
the
cost
of
living
by
about
0.5
percentage
points
per
year.
These
effects
are
important,
since
for
example,
Social
Security
benefits
get
adjusted
upwards
automatically
in
a
way
that
is
tied
to
the
CPI
inflation
rate.
The
GDP
Deflator
and
the
CPI
Usually,
the
GDP
deflator
and
the
CPI
move
together,
as
shown
in
Figure
2.
One
difference,
however,
arises
because:
-‐ The
GDP
deflator
reflects
the
prices
of
all
goods
produced
domestically.
-‐ Whereas
the
CPI
reflects
the
prices
of
all
goods
consumed
domestically.
So
let’s
ask:
what
happens
when
the
price
of
an
imported
good
rises?
-‐ The
CPI
increases.
-‐ But
the
GDP
deflator
does
not.
-‐ This
effect
is
particularly
important
when
the
price
of
imported
oil
rises.
What
happens
when
the
price
of
a
domestically-‐produced
capital
(investment)
good
rises?
-‐ The
GDP
deflator
increases.
-‐ But
the
CPI
does
not.
A
second
and
more
subtle
difference
arises
because:
-‐ The
GDP
deflator
is
based
on
the
prices
of
goods
as
currently
produced.
-‐ Whereas
the
CPI
is
based
on
the
prices
of
a
fixed
basket
of
goods.
-‐ So
differences
arise
when
the
prices
of
different
goods
are
rising
or
falling
at
different
rates.
Correcting
Economic
Variables
for
the
Effects
of
Inflation
Dollar
Figures
at
Different
Points
in
Time
Let’s
go
back
to
the
question
from
the
beginning:
after
correcting
for
inflation,
who
was
paid
more,
Ruth
($80,000)
in
1931
or
Rodriguez
($33
million)
in
2010?
To
answer
this
question,
ask
first:
how
many
“baskets”
of
goods
could
Ruth
buy
in
1931?
4
$80,000 in 1931
Number of Baskets Bought by Ruth in 1931 =
Cost of Each Basket in 1931
Now
ask,
how
much
would
this
same
number
of
baskets
have
cost
in
2010?
2010 Cost of the Baskets Bought by Ruth in 1931
= Cost of Each Basket in 2010 × Number of Baskets Bought by Ruth in 1931
$80,000 in 1931
= Cost of Each Basket in 2010 ×
Cost of Each Basket in 1931
This
last
formula
can
be
rewritten
as:
2010 Cost of the Baskets Bought by Ruth in 1931
Cost of Each Basket in 2010
= × 100
Cost of Each Basket in a Base Year
Cost of Each Basket in a Base Year 1
× × × $80,000 in 1931
Cost of Each Basket in 1931 100
But
now
it
simplifies
to:
CPI in 2010
2010 Cost of the Baskets Bought by Ruth in 1931 = × $80,000 in 1931
CPI in 1931
This
equation
is
true
more
generally:
CPI This Year
Value in this Year's Dollars = Value in a Past Year's Dollars ×
CPI in the Past Year
It
turns
out
that
CPI
in
1931
=
15.2
CPI
in
2010
=
218
(note:
Mankiw
uses
the
CPI
for
2009,
which
was
214.5).
And
so,
doing
the
math:
218
Value of Ruth' s Salary in 2010 Dollars = $80,000 in 1931 Dollars × = $1,147,368
15.2
Even
after
adjusting
for
inflation,
Rodriguez’s
salary
is
much,
much
higher!
But,
interestingly,
President
Herbert
Hoover’s
1931
salary
was
$75,000.
Let’s
convert
that
into
2010
dollars
in
the
same
way:
218
Value of Hoover' s Salary in 2010 Dollars = $75,000 in 1931 Dollars × = $1,075,658
15.2
5
After
adjusting
for
inflation,
Hoover’s
salary
is
more
than
twice
as
large
as
the
$400,000
earned
in
2010
by
President
Barack
Obama.
Indexation
Indexation
refers
to
the
automatic
correction
by
law
or
contract
of
a
dollar
amount
for
the
effects
of
inflation.
As
noted
above,
Social
Security
benefits
are
indexed,
that
is,
adjusted
every
year
based
on
the
percentage
increase
in
the
CPI.
Union
contracts
often
specify
indexed
wages
that
increase
each
year
based
on
the
inflation
rate.
Such
a
provision
is
often
referred
to
as
a
cost-‐of-‐living
allowance
(COLA).
Real
and
Nominal
Interest
Rates
Since
bank
accounts,
bonds,
automobile
loans,
and
mortgages
all
make
or
require
dollar
payments
at
different
points
in
time,
the
interest
rates
on
these
investments
or
loans
must
also
be
corrected
for
the
effects
of
inflation
to
gauge
their
true
economic
significance.
Suppose,
for
example,
that
you
deposit
$1,000
in
a
bank
account
that
pays
interest
at
a
10%
annual
rate:
-‐ One
year
from
now,
you
will
have
$1,100:
your
original
$1,000
plus
$100
interest.
-‐ But
let’s
say
that
the
inflation
rate
over
the
next
year
is
3%.
-‐ You
have
10%
more
dollars,
but
those
dollars
buy
3%
less.
-‐ Your
“real”
return
is
actually
10%
-‐
3%
=7%.
In
this
example,
the
nominal
interest
rate,
that
is,
the
interest
rate
as
it
is
usually
reported
without
correcting
for
inflation,
is
10%.
But
the
real
interest
rate,
corrected
for
the
effects
of
inflation,
is
7%.
In
general:
Real Interest Rate = Nominal Interest Rate − Inflation Rate
Note
that
the
real
interest
rate
can
even
be
negative:
if
the
nominal
interest
rate
on
your
bank
account
is
10%,
but
the
inflation
rate
turns
about
to
be
12%,
the
real
interest
rate
is
10%-‐12%=-‐2%.
Most
frequently,
prices
rise
over
time,
so
that
the
inflation
rate
is
positive.
But
sometimes,
as
in
the
US
economy
during
the
Great
Depression
of
the
1930s
and
in
Japan
during
the
last
decade,
prices
actually
fall
over
time,
so
that
the
inflation
rate
is
negative.
These
are
periods
of
deflation
as
opposed
to
inflation.
Which
is
bigger:
the
nominal
interest
rate
or
the
real
interest
rate?
6
-‐ Under
inflation,
the
nominal
interest
rate
is
bigger
than
the
real
interest
rate
s ince
the
value
of
dollars
is
falling
over
time.
-‐ Under
deflation,
the
real
interest
rate
is
bigger
than
the
nominal
interest
rate
since
the
value
of
dollars
is
rising
over
time.
Figure
3
shows
the
relationship
between
nominal
and
real
interest
rates
in
the
US:
-‐ During
the
1970s,
nominal
interest
rates
were
high
but
real
interest
rates
were
low.
Why?
Because
inflation
was
high.
-‐ During
the
1980s
and
1990s,
nominal
interest
rates
were
low
but
real
interest
rates
were
high.
Why?
Because
inflation
was
low.
This
is
an
important
lesson
for
personal
finance
and
investing:
when
evaluating
the
payoff
on
an
investment
or
the
interest
rate
on
a
loan,
you
need
to
make
a
judgment
on
what
the
inflation
rate
will
be
over
the
lifetime
of
the
investment
or
loan,
to
convert
the
nominal
interest
rate
into
a
real
interest
rate.