Washbrook Commercial Agriculture
Washbrook Commercial Agriculture
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Cambridge University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Modern Asian Studies.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Modern Asian Studies 28, i (i994), pp. 129-164. Printed in Great Britain.
of Agriculturein
The Commercialization
Subsistence
ColonialIndia: Production, and
in the 'Dry South' c. I87o0-930
Reproduction
DAVID WASHBROOK
Universityof Oxford
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
I30 DAVID WASHBROOK
One historical context in which a debate along these lines has been
conducted, in the pages of this journal and elsewhere, is that of 'the
dry' interior of South India. My own 'pessimistic-to-sceptical'
account of its colonial development saw most of the benefits of
expanded cash cropping in cotton and groundnuts passing to a small
group of larger-farmer 'magnates', whom I took to dominate the
markets in credit, commodities and employment. These magnates
were established prior to and, in many ways, independently of the
expansion of commerce, through positions in the revenue and kinship
systems, which enabled them to take up a highly advantageous posi-
tion in the new market context as well. From these positions, they
denied access to market benefits to their smaller clients and used the
forces of commercialization to strengthen their own social and politi-
cal grip on the countryside.4
My account of the 'dry' South was directly challenged by Bruce
Robert who, from a detailed study of one of the 'driest' districts of all
(Bellary district), came to an opposite and very 'optimistic' conclu-
sion. For him, the deepening commercialization of the period pro-
vided the context for a liberation of the small peasantry and for an
increase in their prosperity. He drew attention to a significant
increase in the incidence of landholding, particularly the holding of
small plots of land which were intensively cultivated with high value
cash crops and yielded better returns per acre than the lands of larger
farms. He further argued, from the detailed studies of the Cotton
Committee (1927), that there was no evidence of a monopsonization
of the cotton market, such as would give small producers lower
returns than larger ones. Nor did he see significant restrictions in the
credit market, such as would make small producers the consumption
debtors of large ones. Finally, he took the growth of agricultural
production in the region to be clearly shown by evidence of increasing
cultivated acreage and of capital investment, particularly in carts.5
Needless to say, my own initial reaction to Robert's case, which was
largely based on the same sources that I thought I had consulted, was
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA 1870-1930 I31
one of sheer puzzlement. On certain points, I had no choice but to
concede best to him: I had seriously underestimated the evidence of
deepening market penetration in the region and the way that it had
come to be reflected in the growth of a small-holding agriculture
devoted to cash crop production. At the same time, however, Robert's
translation of this evidence into a story of growing prosperity and
small peasant liberation did not ring true in the light of other
evidence.
Bellary district was distinguished in the Madras Presidency as the
only district with a negative rate of population growth between 1891
and I93I.6 It was at the epicentre of the Southern 'famine risk' zone
and experienced repeated crop failures and dearths-in 1876-78, 1892,
I896-97, I900, 1917, I922-24. Admittedly, after the coming of the
new famine code in I88os, these dearths did not produce deaths on the
same scale as before (between 1876 and 1878 one-quarter of the
population had died).7 Nonetheless, the havoc that they wrought with
crop production was clearly evidenced in the records.8Further, there
was little evidence of increasing productivity to off-set these regular
losses. Bellary (and, in fact, the whole of the Madras Deccan) were
again statistically distinguished in the Presidency for showing no
increases in average crop yields across this period.9 Further, while the
statistics on commercial capital certainly showed 'progress', all the
indices of 'productive' capital-from wells to cattle to ploughs-showed
a common decline.'1 This pointed to a deepening paradox: that while
there had undoubtedly been an expansion of commercialization, it
was to be associated not with a broadening prosperity, but with a
progressive crisis in agricultural production and social reproduction.
The possibility of this crisis was something which, in our different
6
Robert calculated this decline at a rate of o.o6 per cent per annum between I891
and I931. Robert, 'Economic Change', p. 63.
7
MadrasDistrictGazetteer.W. Francis, BellaryDistrict(Madras, 1904), p. 135.
8 For example,the droughtsof I891-92 and 1896-97 reducedcroppedarea by 25
and I8 per cent, respectively, from that of their previous seasons. Bad seasons
between 1917-18 and 1923-24 kept average cropped area 6 per cent lower than in
1916-I7. See Government of India, Agricultural Statisticsof BritishIndia,Quinquennial
Series, 'Madras: Bellary District' (Calcutta and Delhi, various).
9 See Government of Madras, Seasonand CropReports(Madras, annual). In fact,
Bellary's crop yield 'norm' was briefly reduced for a few years in the I9ios, before
being raised back to pre-9goo levels, which the 'seasonal adjustment' factor indicates
it never reached. Bellary's stagnation is marked against the apparent dynamism of
the Southern cotton belt in Coimbatore-Tinnevelly, where, particularly, cotton yields
rose noticeably over the period.
'0 See below, Section V.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
I32 DAVID WASHBROOK
ways, both Robert and I had missed: he from the supposition that
commercial growth must have produced economic growth; I from the
supposition that the absence of economic growth must have been the
result of an incomplete penetration of market forces. Neither of us
considered that the expansion of the market economy, itself, might
have had negative and deleterious effects on the bases of production
and social reproduction. In retrospect, our mutual mistake was to put
too much faith in conventional 'economic' theory and in models of
'the market' as an obvious and automatic source of growth.
But if, in Bellary, the expansion of the market economy was
attended, at least in time, by a crisis of production and reproduction,
why should this have been so; and what might an answer tell us for
the study of other Indian regions, even those where economic growth
did more assuredly take place?
II
Bellary district, of some 5900 square miles,11 was one of the four
'Ceded' districts in the Madras Deccan (and is now in Karnataka
state). In 187I, it had a population density of about 172 to the square
mile, which, following various vicissitudes and recoveries from famine
and disease, stood at 170 in i93 .12 It was one of the 'driest' districts
in South India with only about 2.5 per cent of its cultivation irrigated
at any time before I930.13 Its agriculture was almost entirely
dependent on the rains and was based, first and foremost, on the
production of millet dry grains and pulses, which covered over 70 per
cent of acreage in the I88os and over 65 per cent even in the late
I920S.'4 The district was divided between two contrasting soil types:
heavy black soil, particularly good for cotton production but difficult
to work, predominated in Bellary, Adoni and Alur taluks; poorer
quality red soil, which was much less productive until the coming of
11The district
originally included a number of taluks which, after the Great
Famine, were separated off into the separate Anantapur district. Subsequent to that,
too, taluk boundaries underwent several changes. At various times between 1890 and
1930, the district varied between 5730 and 5975 square miles.
12 Because of the
changes in boundaries, it is easiest to express population changes
in these terms. See Censusof India, i87i, Reporton theCensusof theMadrasPresidency, vol.
i (Madras, 1874), p. 68; 193I, vol. 14, pt 2, p. 2.
13
See Appendix to Bellary District Gazetteer, 1930, p. i6.
14 Food crops occupied between I.4 and 1.6 million acres of Bellary's cultivation,
outside drought years, fairly continuously between 1890 and I930. Seasonand Crop
Reports.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA 1870-1930 I33
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
I34 DAVID WASHBROOK
that 87 per cent of the crop, in the Bellary villages which it surveyed,
was grown on plots of less than 25 acres; and 21 per cent of it on plots
of less than 5 acres.20A very large part of the 200,000+ acre increase
in cotton cultivation between the I89os and late I920S would seem to
have resulted from the activities of small farmers.
However, whether this activity was meaningfully 'induced' by the
buoyancy of cash crop markets may be another matter. The economic
history of the district was extremely bumpy and might best be divided
into four distinctive 'mini-epochs'. The years I890 to about 1904 were
difficult for agriculture. There were droughts in I892, I896-97 and
1900 and cotton prices were little more than steady.21 From about
I904 to the onset of the First World War, Bellary enjoyed something
of a 'golden age' with no serious droughts, cotton prices rising by
about 40 per cent and the new cash crop of groundnut starting to
make its entry.22The Wartime years produced something close to
economic mayhem with rocketing cotton prices, the collapse of the
groundnut market and, from I917-19, crop failure and famine.23 The
decade of the I920s was disappointing: opening in famine, drought
seasons recurred in 1922 and 1924 and, although the weather then
became more stable, cotton prices went into slow decline for several
years before the Great Depression of I930 put them into complete
collapse.24
A model of small farm proliferation 'induced' by rising market
20
Government of India, Indian CentralCottonCommittee.GeneralReporton Eight
Investigationsinto the Finance and Marketingof Cultivators'Cotton (Bombay, I929).
'Madras', p. 51. The Madras investigation, which centred on Bellary district, was
conducted in 1926-27.
21 Cultivated
acreage both opened and closed the decade of the I89os at about 2. I
million acres but plummeted twice between in response to severe droughts. Bellary
cotton prices rose only from Rs 15.5 to Rs 17 per imperial maund. See Agricultural
Statistics,'Madras: Bellary district'.
22
Cropped area rose from 2.2 million acres in 1901-02 to 2.4 million in I914-15.
Cotton acreage rose over the same period from 287,000 to 411,000 acres. Cotton
prices rose from Rs 17.5 to Rs 24. Seasonand CropReports,and Government of India,
Pricesand Wagesin Indiai86i to I9g2 (Calcutta, 1923).
23
Cropped area fell from 2.4 million acres in 1914-15 to 2.2 million in I918-I9.
Cotton prices peaked in I 918 at Rs 76 per maund and then halved again over the next
two years. Cholum/jowar prices rose from Rs 2.25 per maund in 1915-16 to Rs 7.25 in
1918-19 and Rs 6.5 in I919-20. Season and Crop Reportsand Prices and Wages.
24 Cropped area remained static at around 2.2 million acres from
1920-24 and then
rose to 2.45 million acres by the end of the decade. Groundnut acreage increased from
20,000 to 315,000 acres and cotton from 446,000 to 593,000 acres. Cotton prices were
extremely unstable (as was acreage): dropping sharply in the immediate aftermath of
the War; recovering between 1923 and 1925; and then declining slowly until 1929
when they halved, from Rs 24 to Rs 12 per maund, at the onset of the Great
Depression. Seasonand CropReportsand Pricesand Wages.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA 1870-1930 I35
returns must anticipate that the growth of small holdings would have
been fastest during Bellary's 'golden age' between I905 and I9I5, and
slowest during the hard times of the I89os and the problematic 1920S.
In fact, however, the patta data indicate exactly the reverse. Between
I890 and 1901, small pattas proliferated at the amazing rate of about
I640 per annum. Between 1921 and 1929, they increased at the rate of
1345 per annum. But between 1905 and 1915, when market condi-
tions were at their best, they grew at the rate of only 540 a year. In
effect, the proliferation of smallholdings appears to have been more a
response to economic adversity than to market opportunity.25
But why should the Bellary 'peasantry' have responded to adversity
in this way? To answer this question it is necessary to look at the
context from which they came to small farming. The evidence from
the middle of the nineteenth century would seem to suggest that they
came, predominantly, from a background of landless farm labour.
Although Bellary experienced a slight de-urbanization between I89I
and 193I (the result, mainly, of the removal of an army barracks from
Bellary town), the consequent increase in rural population is too small
to account for many of the new farmers.26In the early I87os, before
the Great Famine, the ratio of pattas to population in the district had
stood at about I:12, indicating (if we take a family to consist of five
people) a large rural population without land. After the Great
Famine, as cultivation came to recover in the i88os, the ratio fell to
I:9 and, by the end of the 1920S, it stood at 1:6, which would suggest
almost nobody without some kind of access to land.27
Evidence on land distribution and farming systems in the middle of
the nineteenth century helps further to clarify the picture. According
to contemporaries, the centre of local production regimes was pro-
vided by a small elite of 'magnate' families who commanded huge
landed resources and who worked them, predominantly, with perma-
nent farm servants and gang labour. It was these magnates who, at
this time (whence my original 'magnate' model was derived), produ-
ced most of the cotton and also controlled local 'grain heaps', whose
storage facilities were vital for fending off periodic droughts and
famines. Such magnates built their houses on top of large grain pits
from which they distributed subsistence wages to employees and grain
loans to clients.28
25 Calculated from 'Statement of the Rent-roll', in LandRevenueReports.
26
From I41,928 to 138,070. Census of India, 189i, vol. XIV, p. 6; 9g3y,Madras, vol. 2,
p. 8.
27Calculated from 'Statement of the Rent-roll', LandRevenueReports.
28 '... the
bigger ryots-those who own wide acres, employ many hands and are as
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
136 DAVID WASHBROOK
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA I870-I930 I37
Given, before the revised ryotwari system of the I85os (which
greatly reduced rates of assessment), the economic impossibility of
cultivating at profit without inam land, the central role played by
'magnates' in the Bellary production regime, and the large number of
'landless' labourers within it, become readily explicable. For a large
section of rural society, working as the farm servant of an inamdar
brought a 'share' of revenue-protected production;33 whereas
independent farm production brought only tax-bills. But there was a
further logic to 'large farm' production in this context as well.
Cotton was, and had long been, the principal cash crop of the
district. In the circumstances of the period, however, the best methods
of producing and marketing it favoured the large producer with
capital and land to spare. To gain the best cotton crops from black-
soil lands, for example, required regular deep ploughing with heavy
metal ploughs drawn by upwards of a dozen bullocks. Only 'magnate'
farmers had the capital for such a form of cultivation. Equally, cotton
production was extremely soil-exhausting and was best pursued
where land could be fallowed for extensive periods: only cropping
regimes where land was not a scarce factor of production could afford
lengthy fallows. Further, poor road transport conditions (before the
construction work completed during the Great Famine of I876-78,
which almost doubled Bellary's road mileage) made it hard for small
farmers to get their crops to market and gave sellers who brought
large quantities of crop to the auction block substantial advantages.34
Farm labourers who were paid in terms of a 'share' of the product
accruing to these advantages-and a sizeable share reckoned, in the
I86os, at a customary one-third of the crop-were plainly better off
than had they tried to cultivate, in a small way, on their own.35
Service on the large magnate farms also gave them entitlements to
share in magnate grain stores, the difference between life and death in
times of famine.
What had changed, by the later nineteenth century, to break up
this magnate-centred organization of production and to convert large
numbers of erstwhile farm labourers into small, independent pro-
ducers?As indicated earlier, the specific timing of the conversion must
raise suspicions about the extent to which it was the result of market
'inducement'. An examination of the precise conditions of production
and marketing for small farmers broadens these suspicions. Admit-
33 For a discussion of the 'share' economy, see B. Stein, 'Politics, Peasants and the
Deconstruction of Feudalism in Medieval India', Journalof PeasantStudies12, 985.
34 See Kelsall, Manual, pp. 262-7.
35 Ibid., p. 262.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
138 DAVID WASHBROOK
tedly, by the later nineteenth century, land revenue charges were now
no longer significant and transport improvements made it possible for
small peasants to sell their crops without great disadvantage.
However (and pace Robert), there is no evidence of any production
advantages in Bellary-type farming to small-scale production
methods and several of the old disadvantages still operated.36As in
other parts of the Deccan studied by the Farm Management Survey of
the 1950s, the celebrated 'inverse farm size:productivity ratio' did not
apply and most of the surveys of Bellary conducted in the 192os and
1930S actually found farm size:productivity ratios to be direct.37The
Cotton Committee (1927), for example, noted the highest cotton
yields to come from the largest cotton fields.38
In the context of production methods, this is not surprising. Cattle
were extremely expensive to buy (Rs 200-400 a pair in the late 1920s)
and to keep (Rs 92 p.a. in the early 1930s).39 Small farmers simply
could not afford to own them-with the result that either they had to
hire them (which raised their costs of production) or, more usually,
they had to skimp on ploughing, weeding and manuring.40Indeed,
lack of cattle also kept them out of the new market in groundnut since
its principal cost of production (nearly 55 per cent, according to the
Imperial Council of Agricultural Research's close study of Bellary
production methods in the early 1930s) came from cattle and
manure.41Commercial farming in Bellary without 'owned-cattle' was
either a very expensive or a very restricted business.
36 Robert
(p. 75) implied that Bellary farming could be drawn under a general
'inverse farm size:productivity' rubric derived from the Farm Management Surveys.
But, as Bharadwaj has shown, the rubric principally operated in conditions of
irrigated agriculture. The surveyed districts with 'dry' production conditions most
similar to Bellary's were Amraoti and Akola districts, further North across the Dec-
can. They possessed no significant inverse ratio. See K. Bharadwaj, ProductionCondi-
tionsin IndianAgriculture(Cambridge, 1972).
37 The
sample sizes in both surveys were too small, and too biased towards larger
producers, to make this evidence conclusive. But it can be said that, in both cases, the
farms with the highest per acre productivities were large. MadrasProvincialBanking
EnquiryCommittee,vol. V (Madras, 1930), pp. 272-350; Imperial Council of Agri-
cultural Research, Reporton the Costof Production of Cropsin the PrincipalSugarcaneand
CottonTractsof India,vol. IV (Delhi, i938-39), pp. I I-200.
38
The Committee noted output of io8 lbs per acre on cotton areas over 50 acres
but just go lbs on those under 5 acres and 85 on those between 5 and 25 acres. Cotton
39 MPBCE, II, p.
Committee,p. 5I. 297; V, pp. 3I0-I2; ICAR, IV, p. 14.
40 MPBCE, V, p. 272, 298; Francis, Bellary District, p. 85.
41The ICAR imputed a rental charge of c. Rs. 3.5 per acre to production costs. If
this is removed, as irrelevant to the circumstances of most groundnut farmers,
charges imputed to bullocks and fertiliser come to about 55 per cent of costs of
production. ICAR, IV, pp. 192-8. On the importance of cattle to groundnut, also see
C. Baker, An IndianRuralEconomy880o-955 (Oxford, 1984), pp. 145-53.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA I870-I930 I39
In fact, not only production but also market conditions make the
'decision' of small farmers to enter cotton production difficult to
understand. During both the i89os and 1920s, when small farming
was expanding at its fastest, cotton prices were not at their best. Their
greatest rise in this period came across the igios when, as we have
seen, small patta formation actually slowed down. Indeed, compared
to the price of grain, cotton prices underwent a relative decline across
the whole of this period. Robert seriously miscalculated the ratio of
increase in cotton and grain prices at about parity (56 per cent and 60
per cent respectively). While cotton prices would seem to have risen
by about this amount, the rise in grain prices was much nearer the
order of I6O per cent (from an average of Rs 1.45 per maund in the
last quinquennium of the I88os to Rs 3.75 per maund in the four years
preceding I930-none of these years being famine years).42In effect,
the grain: cotton price ratio almost halved between the I89os and the
late I920S, making the small peasantry's 'decision' to concentrate on
cotton farming, notionally at the expense of grain production, all the
more wonderful.
Behind this decline in relative cotton prices there lay general prob-
lems in the market for short-staple 'Northerns and Westerns', the
local varieties of Deccani cotton which, as a late I920S commentator
put it, 'have lost much of their former reputation'.43With the growth
of longer-stapled and watered varieties of cotton in other parts of
India and the South, the market for Bellary cotton went into decline
after the First World War. Paradoxically, it was the market conditions
associated with this decline, which Robert reported as particularly
favourable to small producers. He noted, from the Cotton Committee
(I927) report, that, allowing for transport costs, there was little dif-
ference between village and town prices for cotton; that the bulk of the
crop was purchased by itinerant commission agents who bought from
large and small producers alike at comparable rates; that there was no
evidence of'magnate' interventions to corner the crop and gain specu-
lative profits.44
What Robert failed to note, however, were the reasons given for this
by the Cotton Committee itself. In the depressed Bellary market,
virtually the whole of the crop was forward-contracted by the pur-
chasing houses at fixed rates and quotas. As these quotas were easily
42
Robert, 'Economic Change', p. 63; AgriculturalStatistics,'Madras: Bellary dis-
trict' and Seasonand CropReports.
BellaryDistrict(Supplement) (Madras, 1930), p. 68.
43 MadrasDistrictGazetteer,
44Robert, 'Economic Change', p. 74.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
140 DAVID WASHBROOK
TABLE I
Bellary Quinquennial Wage Census
filled (in fact, overfilled since 12 per cent of the crop was left unsold
and unsaleable at the season's end), there was no possibility of any
speculative profit in the market. The 'commonness' of price seen
throughout the market was a commonness of bottom price, induced
by purchasing-house monopsony, not a commonness of top price,
beaten up by fierce competition, as Robert supposed.45
But why, then, should small farmers decide to engage in, especially,
cotton cultivation at just the times when the market for it had gone
flat? A more comprehensible answer comes from a view of the situa-
tion whence they came. As Table i shows, the 'golden age' of Bellary
farming, when small patta formation was minimal, coincided with a
period of significant rises in effective wage rates. By contrast, the
192os, when small patta formation expanded prodigiously, saw wages
first in crisis and then continuously depressed. Small patta formation,
here, would seem to have been a response to instabilities in the wage
sector.
But what was happening in the wage sector to precipitate this
response? There seems little doubt that the 'magnate-centred' produc-
tion regime began to change in the i86os and I87os, partly as a result
of the 'new' ryotwari revenue system but, perhaps mostly, because of
the coming of the railways. During the American Civil War, the
district had responded to boom cotton prices with a very considerable
expansion in production, which showed it firmly engaging in a much
larger scale of market activity.46 With the post-War fall in cotton
prices, cotton acreages fell back but market engagement continued in
the grain trade.
As Michelle McAlpin, among others, has argued, the coming of the
railways can be linked to the very considerable rise in grain prices,
which occurred nearly continuously from the I86os to the late 1920S.
Local spatial limitations on grain markets were broken and grain was
45 Cotton Committee,pp. 11-33.
46 Kelsall, Manual, pp.
318-19.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA 1870-1 930 14I
'freed' to find its best price over wider areas.47 In the case of the
market for millets, this 'best price' proved to be spectacularly high:
millet prices rose faster than those of any other major food-grain-for
long periods, faster than those of any commercial crop and of
manufactured goods. The reasons for this would seem to lie in the
extent to which millets were associated with 'dry' production regimes
subject to constant interruption by the weather. There was likely to
be, at least, a dearth somewhere in the millet zone almost every year
with the result that its 'dearth' prices became spread through the
market hiking up the cost of grain everywhere.
There is evidence that, in the post-American Civil War 'depression'
and the early I870s, 'magnate' farmers were starting to run down
their local grain stores and to take advantage of rising market prices.
Indeed, this was suggested as one reason why the Great Famine of
I876-78 had been so severe in terms of loss of life, particularly for
labourers and small peasants who depended on access to these stores
as their own insurance mechanisms.48 It was noticeable that the
death-toll was heaviest in the most commercially-advanced taluks of
the district (Adoni and Alur where nearly a third of the population
was lost).4' After the Great Famine, the run down of local storage
facilities would seem to have continued and was noted again as a
feature of the 1896-97 famine.50By the I920s, large-scale local storage
of grain was held to be a thing of the past and, in effect, subsistence
relations had been put on a commercial and cash basis. The credit
surveys of the 1920s particularly remarked on how, in comparison to
thirty years before, intra-rural borrowings and lendings, which had
been dominated by transactions in grain, were now run largely
through the medium of cash.5'
Needless to say, the commercialization of grain trading had far-
reaching implications for the employment of labour since it was shares
47 M. McAlpin, 'Railroads, Cultivation Patterns and Foodgrain Availability',
Indian Economicand Social History Review 12, I975.
48 See ParliamentaryPapers,I881, vol. LXXI, pt 2: Reportof theIndianFamineCommis-
sion, i88i, Appendix 3. Also my 'Economic Stratification' and 'Country Politics'; D.
Arnold, 'Famine in Peasant Consciousness and Peasant Action: Madras 1876-78' in
R. Guha (ed.), SubalternStudiesIII (Delhi, I984).
49 Francis, BellaryDistrict,p. 135.
50 See ParliamentaryPapers,1898, vol. XXXII: Reportof theIndianFamineCommission,
i898, Appendix, 'Madras'. Also my 'Economic Stratification' and 'Country Politics';
D. Arnold, 'Famine'.
51 See A. Kolliner, 'The Structure of Rural Credit in the Ceded Districts of the
Madras Presidency', paper presented at Conference of Rural Agrarian History,
University of Pennsylvania, I975, pp. 39-49.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
I42 DAVID WASHBROOK
in, and entitlements to, magnate grain stores that had articulated
magnate-centred relations of production. The most obvious conse-
quence would appear to have been a general disemployment of per-
manent and tied farm servants and a casualization of wage-labour.
Certainly, if the, admittedly impressionistic, data on the situation in
the mid-nineteenth century can be believed, Bellary large farming, by
the I920S, was distinguished by its absence of permanent farm
servants. The Banking Enquiry (1929) and the ICAR survey reported
farms of upwards of oo00acres operating with seldom more than two or
three, and sometimes none.52 And this was not because magnates
were deploying their own family labour instead: the ICAR noted
Bellary (large) farming to operate with the highest ratio of hired to
family labour of any part of British India that it surveyed.53
Further evidence of the casualization of labour comes from the
wage census where the Bellary reporter, at the turn of the twentieth
century, was among the first in South India to claim to discern a
definite shift from payments in grain and by 'custom' to payments in
cash or by price-related grain dole.54 The latter style of payment is
scarcely compatible with permanent farm labour.
Besides the rising value of grain, which magnate farmers no longer
wished to 'share' with their employees, the move towards a casualized
labour force also fitted with other developments in Bellary large farm-
ing. Except for the 'golden age' of the i9ios, the cotton market in
Bellary scarcely recovered the significance which it had had in the
American Civil War era and, in the long term, proved itself much less
profitable than the grain and, later, the groundnut markets. The
corollary to the move of cotton towards small farm production was
that it moved off large farm production. The Banking Enquiry (1929)
and the ICAR report noted that, while large farms still obviously
grew it, they could scarcely be said to specialize in it but produced it
as a limited part of mixes dominated by grain and supported by
groundnut.55 The Cotton Committee (I927) found large-scale (50
52 The
employment of permanent farm servants seemed closely related to the
number of cattle and ploughs kept and amount of wet cultivation undertaken.
MPBCE, V, pp. 301, 330, 332.
53This was rated across all Bellary farming at 5 days of family labour for every 2 I
days hired. But in purely 'dry' farming it was considerably lower-5.2 days of family
labour for 8. I hired. ICAR, IV, pp. I 7, 66-7.
54 G.O. 3628 (Revenue) dated 30 November i909, Tamilnadu Archives.
55The three villages examined by the Banking Enquiry were on excellent cotton
soil and very close to Bellary town. Nonetheless only between 20 and 30 per cent of
their acreages were under cotton. MPBCE, V, pp. 273, 296, 323.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA 1870-I-930 I43
acres +) production to be responsible for only 2 per cent of the total.56
The shift away from cotton and towards grain and groundnut
cultivation, however, had drastic implications for the employment of
labour. Cotton was an extremely labour intensive crop: the ICAR put
labour costs at close to 30 per cent of total production costs.57 Grain
and groundnut, by contrast, were labour extensive crops (the latter
being capital intensive) whose demands for labour were low. The
ICAR recorded labour inputs on Bellary large farms at little more
than 13 work-days per acre per year, the lowest in all the areas of
British India that it examined.58At this level of utilization, permanent
farm servants became a very expensive luxury.
How expensive may be seen from data collected by the Banking
Enquiry (1929), which reckoned the annual cost of a permanent farm
servant as between Rs 75 and Rs 90 a year.59Daily wage rates at the
time were thought to have been about 3 annas for an adult male,
making the actual wage-time paid to permanent farm servants the
equivalent of 399 to 480 days per year.60Moreover, the active agri-
cultural season lasted only about 8 months, making the effective work-
time paid for the equivalent of a 598 to 720 day year.61Even if the
permanent farm servant's work-time included that of his wife and
children (paid casually at half the male rate), the value looks very
questionable.
In effect, then, the case would seem much stronger that the expan-
sion of small farming in Bellary was the corollary to changes in labour
practices on the larger farms, and the break-up of the old magnate-
centred production system, than that it was 'induced' by the prospects
of entrepreneurial profit. Casualized labour had to find alternative
means of subsistence for the times when it was no longer being paid
and, in the absence of alternatives, found it in small farming. That
this was, in no sense, a preferred alternative may be judged from
behaviour during 'the golden age', when a price rise temporarily
revived the cotton market and the demand for labour and when
labourers, immediately, ceased taking up small farms.
56 CottonCommittee, p. 5.I
7 Calculated after 'disallowing' for rent. ICAR, IV, p. 21.
58
Ibid., pp. 66-7.
59MPBCE, V, pp. 324, 332-
60
Of course, local wage rates varied greatly. This figure is based on the 'com-
monest' rate found for male labour in the late i920S. QuinquennialWage Censuses
(I926).
61 The rains came in June or July and the last harvests in the black-soil areas took
place in March.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
144 DAVID WASHBROOK
62
Arnold, 'Famine'; also, my Emergence of ProvincialPolitics,ch. 2.
63
My Emergence of ProvincialPolitics, chs 2, 3; Baker, A Rural Economy,ch. 5; D.
Arnold, PolicePowerand ColonialRule,Madrass859-1947 (Delhi, I987).
64See McAlpin, Subjectto Famine.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA 1870-1930 I45
III
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
146 DAVID WASHBROOK
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA 1870-I930 I47
In various other ways too, cotton suited the needs of small farmers.
It was highly drought resistant and thus promised some returns even
when grain crops failed. It also, as noted before, was highly labour
intensive, which meant that it favoured the one factor of production
which small farmers possessed in greater abundance than large
farmers--unpaid family labour. Indeed, had Kolliner imputed labour
costs to cotton production (as large farm management would require),
the profitability of the crop would have become very seriously redu-
ced. At the ratio of labour costs seen by the ICAR survey, cotton
production with hired labour would then appear to have cost Rs i6-
20 per acre and 'profits' to have dropped to Rs 8-18 (say Rs 12). At a
cost: profit ratio of just about I o.8 cotton would have been the least
profitable of any of the three major crops of the region: the returns to
labour-extensive grain and groundnut production, at Kolliner's
figures, give possibilities of ratios of I: 1.4 and I: I.5, respectively.73
These ratios suggest very clearly why large farmers, for whom land
scarcity was not a significant issue and who farmed for returns on
capital, were withdrawing from cotton production. And also, they
indicate that the principal 'advantage' which small farmers possessed,
and which made cotton production still 'profitable' for them in the
depressed conditions of the I92os cotton market, was cheap family
labour.
IV
price and acreage statistics, to demonstrate 'small farm' cropping choice as including
groundnut is extremely curious. Besides the problem of production conditions, there
is also one of location. Before the mid-g92os, 80 per cent of the cotton and the
groundnut crops were produced in different (black-soil and red-soil) taluks: if farmers
did make price-rational decisions about choosing between them, their farms must
have been spread over dozens of miles! Robert, 'Economic Change', pp. 74-5.
73 The ICAR found a 'business' income of Rs
7 per acre on cotton against produc-
tion costs of Rs 13. Although cotton prices were lower in the mid-I93os than in the
late I920S. ICAR, IV, pp. io6-7. Cholum returned Rs I-14 per acre against costs of
Rs 5-8 per acre. MPBCE, V, pp. 275-333; Kolliner, 'Structure of Credit', p. 15.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
I48 DAVID WASHBROOK
TABLE 2
Distributionof Debtby RevenueValueof Land
Source:DerivedfromRobert,'EconomicChange',p.
69, and 'Statementof the Rebt-roll'in LandRevene
Report1925/26.
Some of these we have seen already-in, for example, the need to hire
cattle. Others, however, come as soon as we consider how small
peasants may have gained access to land and have financed their
cultivation of it. Although Bellary land-values were very low (in the
I920S, the equivalent of 1.5-2 years' gross yields), if land was bought
these still had to be met.74If land was rented, as some 30 per cent of
inam land (although very little ryotwari land) was, there were heavy
additional charges to meet. According to the Banking Enquiry (1929),
the standard rental rate in the villages which it examined was Rs 5 per
acre or five-times the equivalent land revenue charge.75 Even if
'virgin' land were cleared, the necessity of digging out deep-rooted
nath grass with a heavy iron plough and bullock team made its costs
of reclamation by no means negligible.
Then there were the costs of farming itself, which could only be met
off future income at the end of the harvest. Cotton farming had several
unavoidable cash expenditures-for seed and bullocks-and, in addi-
tion, there was the family's subsistence through the growing season,
which casual labour on large farms was likely to meet only in part. In
effect, small farmers needed credit in order to cultivate at all and, as
Table 2 demonstrates, their cultivation was more heavily burdened
with debt, in relation to the revenue-based asset value of their land,
than that of larger farmers.76The figures reflected in this Table come
from the Banking Enquiry (1929), which estimated the general level
of debt on Ceded Districts' farming at Rs 23 per acre.77On this basis
74 Between 1926 and
1930, black-soil land averaged about Rs 53 per acre, which
was down by about 35 per cent on values during the boom years of the First World
War. Government of Madras.StatisticalAtlas of the MadrasPresidency(Madras, 1936), p.
337- 75E.g., MPBCE, V, p. 300.
76 Due to variations in land
fertility, it seems preferable to quote revenue asset
values (which were, albeit loosely, related to fertility) than simple acreages.
77
MPBCE, I, p. 76.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA 1870-I930 I49
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
I50 DAVID WASHBROOK
to close to 20 acres). But perhaps making 'profit' was not the point for,
looked at another way, what the new economic system did permit
small farmers to do was to live on, and by, credit-which was itself a
valuable source of subsistence.
Credit advances represented consumption in the present against
costs in the future. Should crops fail and the small peasant debtor
prove unable to repay his loans, he had at least eaten that loan in the
first place; and his creditor was unlikely to have much recall against
him afterwards. At the land values current in Bellary, it was hardly
worth going through the procedures of repossession, if, indeed, the
land belonged to the debtor and was not rented in the first place. The
best way in which a creditor stood to get anything back from his
defaulting debtor was, in fact, to advance him more credit for the next
season in the hope that its crops might be better.
In the precarious circumstances of the Ceded Districts, being a
'consumption debtor' was by no means a bad option for labourers-
cum-small-farmers to pursue. It enabled them to re-form the connec-
tions of a shared subsistence with significant economic actors, which
the break-up of the old production regime had severed. One thing
which evidence from such people to the banking and credit surveys of
the period makes clear is that, for them, there was no problem of
'indebtedness' as such: rather the problem was expressed as one of
'credit' and of their difficulties in getting hold of it in sufficient quanti-
ties to be able to immerse themselves in the security of'debt'.83
Their need for credit may be seen as another factor pushing them
towards 'independent' farming and cotton production. Land and cash
crops represented some security for loans and the higher the per acre
value of the crops, the higher was the volume of credit likely to be
available to the producer. That the potential profit of these crops
might be absorbed in interest charges, made all the heavier by the
extra costs of production that had to be borrowed in order to produce
them, mattered little when the principal strategy was simply to get
hold of credit adequate for subsistence in the first place. Small
peasants, in effect, reproduced themselves and their cultivation, from
day-to-day and season-to-season, through the credit system.
And, at the end of all this, were they any better off than they had
been under the old production system? It would, perhaps, be easier to
see their situation as 'different' rather than 'better' in any qualitative
sense. As clients and dependants in the old magnate-centred
83
MPBCE, II, p. 297; IV, p. 74. See also, V. V. Sayana, The Agrarian Problems of
Madras Province (Madras, I949), espec. pp. 15I-7.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA 1870-1930 151
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
152 DAVID WASHBROOK
coaster ride between starvation and glut, the Bellary poor now faced a
long death of attrition between a more constant but inadequate sup-
ply of food and murderous diseases.
Further, to sustain even this supply required greater and harder
labour than ever before. Put most simply, with a labour force of the
same size, the district was cultivating 20 per cent more land and 60
per cent more labour-intensive cotton in the late I920o than it had
done in the late I88os. It was also doing so at lower levels of profit (at
least to cotton) and at no increase in piece-related rates of wage. The
process was accomplished, via the casualization of wage labour, in
part by lengthening the working year and, in part, by tapping new
sources of unpaid family labour. One of the 'advantages' of groundnut
cultivation was that its work schedule made demands for labour at
previously slack times of the year, increasing the effective work-load of
agriculture.86The shift of cotton into small farm production, as we
have seen, was principally made possible by the harnessing to it of the
unpaid family labour 'stored' inside the peasant family. In fact, cotton
made especially heavy demands for female and child labour, whose
'nimble fingers' were essential to successful picking.
In spite of the extra burden of work, however, there is precious little
evidence that labourers-cum-small-farmers ever did better than to
achieve a precarious subsistence-and that only with regular 'help'
from the famine department. Their small scale of debt-loaded produc-
tion and casual earnings from wage labour can have left them with
little surplus in good years and, come bad years, their trailing in large
numbers to risk the diseases of the relief camps hardly bespeaks much
in the way of 'progress'. A life that had once been a gamble on the
monsoon became one dependent on the whims of the market-place
and the medical profession; and, over nearly fifty years, the greater
'securities' of the market-place failed to provide it with the means to
ensure even its own regular reproduction.
But if the new regime brought few clear benefits to labourers-cum-
small-peasants, who did gain from it? Most obviously, the purchasing
companies and the ultimate consumers of Bellary cotton, grain and
groundnut obtained these commodities at lower cost-of-production
prices, certainly in terms of labour. But perhaps the greatest benefici-
aries were the local magnate farmers themselves. They increased the
profitability of their farming by sloughing off labour's costs of
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA I870-I930 I53
87
Kolliner, 'Structure of Credit', pp. 24-41,
88Robert, 'Economic Change', p. 68.
89 Cotton
Committee, pp. 24, 29.
Censusof India, 1921, vol. XIV, pt 2, p. 120.
9 Robert, 'Economic Change', pp. 69-70.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
I54 DAVID WASHBROOK
TABLE 3
Distributionof Creditors
by RevenuePayingCategory
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA I870-1930 I55
But yet there may still have been a price to pay for capitalism's new
efficiencies and rationalities. As Christopher Baker has argued, dur-
ing the 1940Sand 195os evidence began to accrue of a general decline
in levels of agricultural productivity and fertility across the whole of
South India.94In many ways, this decline could be associated with the
rapid expansion of cultivation, which had taken place over the
previous seventy-five years. In Bellary, the decline would seem to
have started earlier and to have been marked even by the i920s.
During the first great cotton boom in Bellary, in the I86os, average
per acre outturns were reckoned to be in the region of 375 lbs ofkapas,
making about 93.75 lbs of lint.95This was, admittedly, an impression-
istic figure and can only have related to exceptionally good seasons.
Nonetheless, as a 'best season' possibility, it compared vary favour-
ably with other levels of cotton production found in other parts of the
South at this time. This favourability was also reflected in the fact that
Bellary town was chosen as the site of the first spinning factory in the
South.96
By the I920S, such levels of production (and the spinning factory
which closed down in 1915) were but golden memories. The Season
and Crop Reports had slimmed down Bellary's notional cotton yields
to 50 lbs of lint per acre (200 lbs of kapas). But, when the changing
'seasonal factor' is read against this figure, it appears that in not a
single season of the decade was it actually reached: outturn varied
between 52 and 94 per cent of the norm and averaged 75.8 per cent, or
151.2 Ibs of kapas/37.8 lbs of lint per acre.97Even this figure would
have astounded the Cotton Committee (1927), which claimed to find,
94 Baker, Rural Economy,pp. 227-8, 509-13.
95Kelsall, Manual,p. 262.
96 MadrasDistrictGazetteer,BellaryDistrict(Supplement), p. 68.
97 Seasonand CropReports,annual.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
I56 DAVID WASHBROOK
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA I870-1930 I57
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
158 DAVID WASHBROOK
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA I870--I930 I59
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
i6o DAVID WASHBROOK
VI
But what caused this situation: why should the increasing penetration
of capital into production, in the circumstances of Bellary, have
resulted in ecological devastation and poor peasant exploitation?
Superficially, the history of the market and of a variety of geographi-
cal and ecological factors might seem to supply the answers.
Obviously, the declining market for Deccani short-stapled cotton
seriously reduced the profitability of cotton production, the principal
cash crop. Climatic uncertainties and water shortage made it imposs-
ible, at least under criteria of competitive profitability, for Bellary
farming to respond by taking up the new long-stapled and 'watered'
cottons that now dominated the market.
There was some response in terms of the development of groundnut
as a new major cash crop. However, Bellary's great distance from the
nearest cattle breeding grounds (in Nellore district), and lack of
adequate pasturage, limited the possibilities of this crop. Further,
neither groundnut nor grain demanded the same levels of labour
input as cotton. This left labour as Bellary's most abundant and
progressively cheapening factor of production, which capital came
most naturally to exploit.
Yet it is never satisfactory to treat society simply as the passive
victim of intangible forces of nature and the market. Clearly, different
patterns of human intervention could have brought about different
results. One such pattern can be traced to the activities of the state,
which, through acts of both omission and commission, bore a heavy
responsibility for these consequences. In terms of omission, of course,
the colonial state did remarkably little to find technological solutions
to Bellary's ecological and agronomic problems. As Christopher
Baker has seen, its obsessions with riverine irrigation meant that it left
the 'dry' uplands without adequate support or investment.'22Nor did
its concerns with crop improvements extend beyond crops with export
potential to the millet grains on which most of society lived.
122
Baker, Rural Economy, ch. 5.
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA I870-1930 I6i
In terms of commission, however, the colonial state's responsibili-
ties are even more direct and open up questions on a second pattern of
human intervention-that represented by class relations. In many
ways, it was the actions, intended and unintended, of the early Com-
pany state that set up Bellary's social problems into the twentieth
century. Penal levels of revenue assessment, together with the careless
granting of inam rights which could be confiscated by a small elite,
fundamentally altered the distribution of wealth and power within the
district. As a new and more penetrative age of capitalism dawned in
the second half of the nineteenth century, Bellary entered it with most
of its potential sources of 'capital' (good quality land and supra-
subsistence surpluses) concentrated in the lands of a very small group
of landed magnates. Subsequent state intervention further helped
them to turn their wealth into capital. The new famine codes enabled
them to withdraw from responsibility for the reproduction of their
own labour forces. And more effective administrative and policing
systems helped to guarantee their 'private' rights of property against
the moral and material demands for 'shares' still emanating from
society. The state made the particular capitalist class which domin-
ated Bellary farming.
And having made it, and made it in a way which opened a vast gap
between the resources of the magnate elite, on one side, and the 70+
per cent of indigent labourers-cum-small-farmers, on the other, it
stood back to allow the logic of capital to work itself out. Hardly
surprisingly, that logic saw capital attaching itself to and exploiting
the very indigence of the labourer-cum-small-peasant, whose relative
share in a social product, expanded by the extension of cultivation
and cash-cropping, declined in proportion to capital's own advance.
And profitable though this pattern of exploitation may have been in
the short-term, its effect on the long-term development of the forces of
production was largely negative.
The wide variety of different histories of the market, ecology, state
intervention and class relations in colonial Indian farming, of course,
make it impossible to generalize directly from Bellary's experience to
that of other regions. But if this experience does have something to
tell, it must be of the importance of factors of'distribution' (and hence
of class) in determining the way in which the deepening penetration of
capitalism, from the later nineteenth century, affected the means and
relations of production. Prior distributions of rights and resources,
and the ability or inability to defend them, structured capital's pos-
sibilities of 'progress'. In Bellary, they gave capital a near-rightless
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
i62 DAVID WASHBROOK
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AGRICULTURE IN COLONIAL INDIA I870-1930 163
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
I64 DAVID WASHBROOK
This content downloaded from 14.139.235.3 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 08:52:44 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions