MacroEcon 2152 Notes
MacroEcon 2152 Notes
For the study of economic growth, it is most helpful to examine movements in Trend GDP ; for
the study of business cycles, it is most helpful to examine movements in deviations from trend in
GDP
Rapid inflation occurs when growth in nominal gdp exceeds growth in real gdp
When we try to measure real gdp and the price level , if we underestiame the growth of real gdp
we will always overestimate the rate of inflation
Significant problems with measuring real GDP and the price level include changes in the quality
of goods over time
Problems with interpreting the unemployment rate as a measure of labour market tightness
include discouraged workers and variations in how intensively the unemployed search for work.
Lecture 2 Notes:
Firms Decisions:
- Firms are going to choose how many workers to hire
- More workers means more output
- More workers means higher wage bills
That is, an increase in z will make both factors of production, K and , more productive, in that,
given factor inputs, higher z implies that more output can be produced.
- If MPN - W = 0
- The last worker produces the exact same as the wage cost
- Want to hire exactly this many workers
- “Slope of the two function must be equal at the optimum”
• MPN is the slope of the production function
• w is the slope of the wage bill
Or
1. Derive production function to get MPL
2. Input #’s to find MPL and set it to W
3. Solve for N
Example :
Y = zK^αN^ 1−α
Assume z = 2, K = 4, α = 1 2 , and w = 0.5
1. Determine the objective function with the profit function - π = zK^αN^1−α − wN
2. Now take the derivative with respect to the choice variable ( N )
- ∂π/∂N = z(1 − α)K^αN^−α − w
3. Set the derivative equal to zero and solve the equation for N
- z(1 − α)K^αN^−α − w = 0
- N = (z(1 − α)K^α/w)^ 1/α
- Sub In the numbers and solve for N = 16
Labour Demand
Consumer Decisions
A representative consumer : Values Consumption (C) and Leisure (L) , also pay taxes (T) and
dividends (π)
The Utility Function - U( c, l) , (c1, ℓ1) is a consumption bundle.
U(c1, ℓ1) > U(c2, ℓ2) ⇒ individual strictly prefers (c1, ℓ1) to (c2, ℓ2).
U(c1, ℓ1) = U(c2, ℓ2) ⇒ individual indifferent between both consumption bundles.
Indifference Curves
- An indifference curve connects a set of points, representing consumption bundles,
among which the consumer is indifferent.
- Monotone: the more, the better =⇒ indifference curves will slope down
- Convex: prefers averages to extremes =⇒ indifference is bowed in toward the origin
- Strictly monotone: More is always better ▶ ∂U(·)/ ∂c > 0 → Marginal utility of
consumption is greater than 0
- Weakly monotone: More is at least as good ▶ ∂U(·)/ ∂c ≥ 0 → Marginal utility of
consumption is greater than 0 or equal to 0
- Strictly convex: Averages are always preferred ▶ U(c1, ℓ1) = U(c2, ℓ2) < U( c1+c2/2 ,
ℓ1+ℓ2/2 )
- Weakly convex: Averages are at least as good ▶ U(c1, ℓ1) = U(c2, ℓ2) ≤ U( c1+c2/2 ,
ℓ1+ℓ2/2 )
The rate at which you would exchange two goods and remain indifferent
The rate at which the consumer is just willing to substitute leisure for consumption goods
The MRSℓ,c is the negative of the slope of the indifference curve at a particular consumption
bundle (c0, ℓ0), Convex: diminishing MRSℓ,c
→ c = wNs + π − T
→ c = w(h − ℓ) + π − T
→ c = −wℓ + wh + π − T
C and L are chosen and the rest are given
The slope of the budget constraint is , and the constraint shifts with the quantity of nonwage
real disposable income, . All points in the shaded area and on the budget constraint can be
purchased by the consumer.
Slope of the budget constraint is -w and the vertical intercept is Wh + profits - Taxes
The vertical intercept is the maximum quantity of consumption attainable for the consumer,
which is what is achieved if the consumer works h hours and consumes no leisure. The
horizontal intercept is the maximum number of hours of leisure that the consumer can take and
still be able to pay the lump-sum tax.
- the budget constraint is somewhat unusual, as it is kinked; the slope of the budget
constraint is over its upper portion, and the constraint is vertical over its lower portion.
- There is a kink in the budget constraint because the consumer cannot consume more
than 24 hours of leisure.
-
The consumption bundle represented by point H, where an indifference curve is tangent to the
budget constraint, is the optimal consumption bundle for the consumer
The optimal consumption bundle is the point representing a consumption–leisure pair that is
on the highest possible indifference curve and is on or inside the consumer’s budget constraint.
If MRS l,c is greater than W then the rate at which the consumer is willing to trade leisure for
consumption is greater than the rate at which the consumer can trade leisure for consumption
in the market.
At Point H (optimal consumption bundle) the rate at which the consumer is willing to trade
leisure for consumption is equal to the rate at which leisure trades for consumption in the
market, and thus the consumer is at his or her optimum.
Changes in profits - taxes
- We hold W constant, In any case, we will think of the increase in as producing a pure
income effect, the effect on a consumers consumption bundle because of a change in
real disposable income, on the consumer’s choices, since prices remain the same (w
remains constant) while disposable income increases.
- if we hold the real wage constant, an increase in income will imply that the
representative consumer will choose more consumption and more leisure
- Though nonwage income increases, wage income falls since the consumer is working
less. The reduction in income from the decrease in wage income will not completely
offset the increase in nonwage income, as consumption has to increase because it is a
normal good.
- More is available at L = H and the slope of budget line remains unchanged
- When either of proifts or taxes changes there is only an income effect
- given that consumption and leisure are normal goods, consumption must increase but
leisure may increase or decrease in response to an increase in the real wage.
Sub effect
- The movement from F to O is a pure substitution effect in that it just captures the
movement along the indifference curve in response to the increase in the real
wage. The real wage increases, so that leisure becomes more expensive relative
to consumption goods, and the consumer substitutes away from the good that
has become more expensive (leisure) to the one that has become relatively
cheaper (consumption). Therefore, the substitution effect of the real wage
increase is for consumption to increase and for leisure to decrease, and so the
substitution effect is for labour supply, , to increase.
- Wage increase , so leisure more expensive since not working when you have a
high wage means you are sacrificing making good money for leisure, so
substitute L for C
Income effect
- as the real wage stays the same as the budget constraint shifts out from JKD to EBD, and
nonwage income increases. Since both goods are normal, consumption increases and
leisure increases in moving from O to H. Thus, when the real wage increases, the
consumer can consume more consumption goods and more leisure, since the budget
constraint has shifted out. On net, then, consumption must increase, since the
substitution and income effects both act to increase consumption. However, there are
opposing substitution and income effects on leisure, so that it is ultimately unclear
whether leisure will rise or fall. Therefore, an increase in the real wage could lead to an
increase or a decrease in labour supply .
- Individuals are wealthier so they chose to increase both leisure and consumption more
Labour Supply
- Consumers wage income is taxed at a constant rate tw(h-l) and the consumers budget
constraint would be c = wage( 1 - taxes) (hours - leisure) + profits.
- theory tells us that an increase in the income tax rate t may cause an increase or a
decrease in the quantity of labour supplied
- So, the statement is saying that for a tax increase to cause people to work fewer hours,
the feeling of "it's not worth it to work" (substitution effect) has to be stronger than the
need to "make up for lost money" (income effect). If the substitution effect is large
enough, the increase in taxes creates a strong disincentive to work, leading people to
reduce their hours. The labour supply curve shifts to the left (decreases)
- the key idea is that what matters for aggregate economic activity is total labour input,
which is determined by three factors: (i) how many hours each individual works, (ii) how
many individuals are working, and (iii) the quality of the labour hours supplied.
- suppose l(w) is a function that tells us how much leisure the consumer wants to
consume, given the real wage w. Then, the labour supply curve is given by Labour
supplied (w) = hours - leisure (wage)
- Assuming that the substitution effect is larger than the income effect of a change in the
real wage, labour supply will increase with an increase in the real wage, and the labour
supply schedule will be upward-sloping, we will typically assume that the substitution
effect of an increase in the real wage dominates the income effect, so that the labour
supply curve is upward-sloping
- we know that, since the quantity of leisure increases when nonwage disposable income
increases, an increase in nonwage disposable income will shift the labour supply curve
to the left.
Perfect Complements
- Goods are perfect complements for the consumer if he or she always wants to consume
these goods in fixed proportions.
- If consumption and leisure are perfect complements, the consumer always wants to
have c/l equal to some constant, or c = (a)(L) → where A is a constant greater than 0
- With perfect complements, the indifference curves of the consumer will be L-shaped,
- Note that perfect complements preferences do not satisfy all the properties for
preferences that we assumed in general. More is not always preferred to less, as the
consumer is not better off with more of one good unless he or she has more of the other
good as well. However, the consumer does have a preference for diversity, but of a very
dramatic sort. That is, as we move downward along the indifference curve, the slope
does not become flatter smoothly, but goes instantly from vertical to
horizontal
- The optimal consumption bundle for the consumer will always
be along the line c = (a)(l)
- With the budget constraint, C = (a(wh + profits - taxes)/ a + w)
and L = (wh + profits - taxes) / (a + w )
- Leisure and consumption therefore increase with nonwage
disposable income, , and we can also show that consumption and
leisure both increase when the real wage, w, increases.
- Further, if a increases, so that the consumer prefers more consumption relative to
leisure, then it seems obvious the consumer will choose more of C and less of l at the
optimum.
where:
• f (x1, x2) is the objective function
• x1 + 4x2 = 16 is the constraint
• x1, x2 are the choice variables
Chapter 4
Indifference curves: If two consumption bundles lie on the same indifference curve , they have
the same utility.
Since indifference curve A lies above indifference curve B , and we know more is preferred to
less, consumption bundles on A are strictly preferred to consumption bundles on B .
Slope of the budget constraint is -w and the vertical intercept is Wh + profits - Taxes
The vertical intercept is the maximum quantity of consumption attainable for the consumer,
which is what is achieved if the consumer works h hours and consumes no leisure. The
horizontal intercept is the maximum number of hours of leisure that the consumer can take and
still be able to pay the lump-sum tax.
Lecture 5 :
Competitive Equilibrium
- Find situation where the behaviour of all these agents is consistent
- Given market prices:
- • All individual agents make optimal decisions
▶ Firms
▶ Consumers
- • All markets clear
- • Government budget is balanced
Also slope of PPF (-) = The marginal rate of transformation; The rate at which one good (e.g.,
leisure) can be converted into another (e.g., consumption)
Profit = Y - Wn → Y - W(h - l)
Chapter 5 notes
- A public good is a commodity or service that every member of a society can use without
reducing its availability to all others. ( National Defense)
- We will show how increases in government spending increase aggregate output and
crowd out private consumption expenditures, and how increases in productivity can lead
to increases in aggregate output and the standard of living. Finally, we will consider a
version of the model where the economic outcome is not socially efficient in an
economy with unregulated private markets, because of the incentive effects of income
taxation, and we also consider a simple model of how the government should determine
government spending.
- The government's behavior : It wants to purchase a given quantity of consumption
goods, G, and finances these purchases by taxing the representative consumer.
- Government spending uses up resources, and we will model this by assuming that
government spending simply involves taking goods from the private sector.
- An exogenous variable is determined outside the model, while an endogenous variable
is determined by the model itself.
- Government spending is exogenous in our model, as we are assuming that government
spending is independent of what happens in the rest of the economy. The government
must abide by the government budget constraint, which we write as G = T , government
purchases are equal to taxes
- In a static model government spending equals taxes and there is no surplus or deficit
2. The representative firm chooses Nd (labour demand) to maximize profits, with
Y=zf(K,Nd) maximized output and π = Y - wNd maximized profits. The firm treats z (total
factor productivity), K (the capital stock), and w (the real wage) as given. That is, the
representative firm optimizes given total factor productivity, its capital stock, and the
market real wage. In equilibrium, the profits that the representative firm earns must be
equal to the dividend income that is received by the consumer.
- In simple terms, the firm is trying to make the most profit possible by deciding how
many workers to hire (labor demand). To do this, it looks at:
1. Total Factor Productivity (z): How efficiently it can turn inputs like labor and capital into
output.
2. Capital Stock (K): The equipment, buildings, and other assets it already owns.
3. Real Wage (w): The cost of hiring each worker.
The firm wants to produce as much as it can with what it has, while paying workers a wage that
lets it stay profitable. In a balanced market (equilibrium), all profits the firm makes go to the
consumers (or shareholders) as dividends, which becomes extra income for them. So, the firm's
goal to maximize profits aligns with consumers receiving income from those profits.
3. The market for labour clears, that is, Ns = Nd . The amount of labour that the representative
firm wants to hire is equal to the amount of labour the representative consumer wants to
supply.
4. The government budget constraint is satisfied—that is, The taxes paid by consumers are
equal to the exogenous quantity of government spending.
- Y = C + G
- In a closed economy there is no exports or imports (NX) and this is a one period
economy so there is no investments (I)
- The Production Possibility Frontier is a graphical tool that shows us the combination of
consumption bundles that it is possible to consume in the economy.
- The ppf is the relationship in the output as a function of leisure graph shifted down by
the amount G, since consumption is output minus government spending in equilibrium.
- In simple terms, the PPF (Production Possibility Frontier) shows the balance or tradeoff
between how much people in the economy can consume (buy and use goods) and how
much leisure time they can have (time not working). In short, only points on DB make
sense because they ensure both the government and individuals have enough goods
available.
- The negative of the slope of the PPF is the Marginal product of labour but it is also the
Marginal rate of transformation which means , The rate at which one good (e.g., leisure)
can be converted into another (e.g., consumption).
- MRT = MPn = - slope of the ppf
- Namely, the representative firm chooses the labour input to maximize profits in
equilibrium by setting MPn = w
- Maximized profits for the firm are π = zF(k , h - l) - w(h - l) (total revenue minus the cost
of hiring labour).
-
In other words, the marginal rate of substitution of leisure for consumption is equal to the
marginal rate of transformation, which is equal to the marginal product of labour.
That is, because the consumer and the firm face the same market real wage in equilibrium, the
rate at which the consumer is just willing to trade leisure for consumption is the same as the
rate at which leisure can be converted into consumption goods by using the production
technology.
Indeed, since an increase in government spending must necessarily increase taxes by the same
amount, which will reduce the consumer’s disposable income. It should not be surprising, then,
that the effects of an increase in government spending essentially involve a negative income
effect on consumption and leisure.
an increase in G from G1 to G2 shifts the PPF from PPF1 to PPF2 , where the shift down is by
the same amount, for each quantity of leisure, l. This shift leaves the slope of the PPF
unchanged for each l. The effect of shifting the PPF downward by a constant amount is very
similar to shifting the budget constraint for the consumer through a reduction in his or her
nonwage disposable income
There are negative income effects on consumption and leisure, so that both C and l fall, and
employment rises, while output (equal to C + G ) increases.
Why do consumption and leisure decrease? This is because consumption and leisure are normal
goods. Given the normal goods assumption, a negative income effect from the downward shift
in the PPF must reduce consumption and leisure.
Since leisure falls, then employment , which is N2 = h - L2 must rise. This also makes output
increase.
there is a negative income effect on leisure and therefore a positive effect on labour supply, a
larger government reduces private consumption through a negative income effect produced by
the higher taxes required to finance higher government spending. As the representative
consumer pays higher taxes, his or her disposable income falls, and in equilibrium he or she
spends less on consumption goods and works harder to support a larger government.
Thus, since minus the slope of the PPF at the equilibrium point is equal to the equilibrium real
wage, the real wage falls because of the increase in government spending. The real wage must
fall, as we know that equilibrium employment rises, and the representative firm would hire
more labour only in response to a reduction in the market real wage.
- No savings
- Closed Economy: No foreign trade or capital flows
- Government spending is not valued
Optimality
the Pareto optimum is located at point B, where an indifference curve is just tangent to the PPF
The Pareto optimum is the point that a social planner would choose, where the representative
consumer is as well off as possible given the technology for producing consumption goods by
using labour as an input.
the Pareto optimum has the property that MRT = MPn = MRS
A key result of this chapter is that, for this model, the competitive equilibrium is identical to the
Pareto optimum.
First welfare theorem - states that, under certain conditions, a competitive equilibrium is
Pareto-optimal.
Second welfare theorem - states that, under certain conditions, a Pareto optimum is a
competitive equilibrium.
In simple terms, the competitive market outcome is as good as what a wise, all-knowing
planner would have chosen for society. This is because, in a well-functioning market, people’s
self-interested actions lead to an outcome where resources are allocated efficiently without
anyone needing to control or plan it directly.
Chapter 9 :
- In intertemporal choice, a key variable of interest is the real interest rate, which in the
model is the interest rate at which consumers and the government can borrow and lend.
- The real interest rate determines the relative price of consumption in the future in terms
of consumption in the present.
- An important principle in the response of consumption to changes in income is
consumption smoothing. That is, there are natural forces that cause consumers to want
to have a smooth consumption path over time, as opposed to a choppy one.
Consumption-smoothing behavior is implied by particular properties of indifference
curves.
- As well, consumption-smoothing behavior has important implications for how
consumers will respond in the aggregate to changes in government policies or other
features of their external environment that affect their income streams.
- the Ricardian equivalence theorem establishes conditions under which the timing of
taxation does not matter for aggregate economic activity.
- A key implication of the Ricardian equivalence theorem is that a tax cut is not a free
lunch. A tax cut may not matter at all, or it may involve a redistribution of wealth within
the current population or across generations.
- By saving, a consumer gives up consumption in exchange for assets in the present, in
order to consume more in the future. Alternatively, a consumer can dissave by
borrowing in the present to gain more current consumption, thereby sacrificing future
consumption when the loan is repaid. Borrowing (or dissaving) is thus negative savings.
- In this model, we will denote the first period as the current period and the second period
as the future period
We will further suppose that consumers do not make a work–leisure decision in either period
but simply receive exogenous income
y is consumers real income in current period and y’ be consumers real income in second period
Each consumer pays lump-sum taxes, t, in the current period and t’ in the future period.
Consumers savings = s
So the consumers budget constraint is c+s = y -t , consumption plus savings in the current period
must equal disposable income in the current period
Note that we assume that the consumer starts the current period with no assets.
if s > 0 then the consumer will be a lender on the credit market, and if s < 0 the consumer will
be a borrower.
Assume that the financial asset being traded is bonds, If a consumer lends, he or she buys
bonds; if he or she borrows, they are selling bonds.
In the future period, the consumer has disposable income y’ - t’ and receives the interest and
principal on his or her savings, which totals (1 +r)s
Consumption in the future period is y’ - t’ + (1 +r)s. This is because we assume they consume all
their money in the second period. No money given to descendants
the endowment point, which is the consumption bundle the consumer gets if he or she simply
consumes disposable income in the current period and in the future period. consumption is
equal to disposable income in each period.
Consumers preferences :
- Monotone : More is always preferred to less. More current consumption or more future
consumption always makes the consumer better off.
- The consumer likes diversity in his or consumption bundle, averages are preferred to
extremes. Consumption smoothing
- Consumption and leisure are normal goods; This implies that if there is a parallel shift to
the right in the consumer’s budget constraint, current consumption and future
consumption will both increase. This is related to the consumer’s desire to smooth
consumption over time. If there is a parallel shift to the right in the consumer’s budget
constraint, it is because lifetime wealth, we, has increased. Given the consumer’s desire
to smooth consumption over time, any increase in lifetime wealth will imply that the
consumer will choose more consumption in the present and in the future.
Consumer optimization
- the marginal rate of substitution of current consumption for future consumption which
is minus the slope of the indifference curve is equal to the relative price of current
consumption in terms of future consumption ( which is minus the slope of the
consumer’s lifetime budget constraint).
- Here, the consumer optimizes by choosing the consumption bundle on his or her
lifetime budget constraint where the rate at which he or she is willing to trade off
current consumption for future consumption is the same as the rate at which he or she
can trade current consumption for future consumption in the market (by saving).
- The consumer is a lender if the savings is positive , this is if y-t ( disposable income) is
greater than consumption
- The consumer is a borrower if the savings is negative , this is if y-t(disposable income) is
less than consumption
- responds to a change in the real interest rate, which will change the slope of the budget
constraint.
- An increase in the real interest rate holding others constant makes the budget
constraint steeper
- Further, under the assumption that the consumer never has to pay a tax larger than his
or her income, so that y’-t’ > 0 , an increase in r will decrease lifetime wealth, we
- and since y > t there will be an increase in we(1 +r) when r increases. Therefore, we
know that an increase in r will cause the budget constraint to pivot,
- We also know that the budget constraint must pivot around the endowment point E,
since it must always be possible for the consumer to consume his or her disposable
income in each period, no matter what the real interest rate is.
- that is, an increase in r causes future consumption to become cheaper relative to
current consumption. A higher interest rate implies that the return on savings is higher,
so that more future consumption goods can be obtained for a given sacrifice of current
consumption goods.
- Current consumption is more expensive with an increase to the interest rate
- The slope of the budget constraint becomes -(1+ r2)
Households smooth their consumption over time , even if their income is volatile they can
smooth their consumption by either borrowing or saving
Consumption smoothing is the tendency of consumers to seek a consumption path over time
that is smoother than income.
Durable Goods: long term goods that are not entirely consumed in the year that they are
purchased
The permanent income hypothesis : only permanent income should matter for consumption
The property of diminishing marginal rate of substitution follows from the property of the
indifference curve that bowed in toward the origin
Government :
The aggregate tax amount collected = T and for the future period → T’
The Ricardian Equivalence Theorem states that changes in the timing of taxes will not affect the
equilibrium real interest rate or the consumption of individuals.
The Ricardian Equivalence Theorem states that if current and future government spending are
held constant, a change in current taxes with an equal and opposite change in the present value
of future taxes leaves the equilibrium real interest rate and the consumptions of individuals
unchanged.
If future income increases and current income decreases and lifetime wealth is unchanged than
a consumer will reduce its current savings
The timing of taxes changes the position of the endowment point, but not the shape or position
of the budget constraint
The phenomenon that some consumers pay a higher interest rate when they borrow than the
interest rate they receive when they lend is best described as an example of credit market
imperfections.
In a simple model of credit imperfections, when consumers borrow and lend at different
interest rates, the budget line is kinked because the consumer lends at a lower rate than they
borrow.
Asymmetric information means some market participants have more information than others.
If there are fewer bad borrowers in the population when there is asymmetric information, the
interest rate spread declines.If there are more bad borrowers in the population when there is
asymmetric information , the interest rate spread grows
If the value of collateral falls for a consumer , current consumption must fall. If the value of
collateral rises for a consumer , current consumption must rise
If consumers use their house as collateral for lending and the value of housing in general falls
then lending and aggregate consumption decreases
For a consumer not bound by the collateral constraint, a reduction in the price of the collateral
leads to a decrease in current and future consumption.
In a pay as you go system it benefits everyone if the population growth rate is higher than the
real interest rate. The rate of return on private savings is r , The rate of return of the pension
system is n.
Consumers benefit from the pay as you go system , With sufficiently high population growth,
many young contribute to the benefits of the old.
- in practice the interest rates at which consumers and firms can lend are lower than the
interest rates at which they can borrow, consumers and firms cannot always borrow up
to the quantity they would like at market interest rates, and borrowers are sometimes
required to post collateral against a loan.
Assymetric information
- During a financial crisis, the quality of information in credit markets declines, with
important implications for market interest rates, the quantity of lending, and aggregate
economic activity.
- In the model, a bank borrows from its depositors in the current period, and each
depositor is an ultimate lender in the economy, with a depositor receiving a real interest
rate on his or her deposits, which are held with the bank until the future period. The
bank takes all of its deposits in the current period (which in the model are consumption
goods), and makes loans to borrowers.
- To make things simple, suppose that a fraction a of the borrowers in the economy are
good borrowers who have positive income in the future period, while a fraction of
borrowers are bad, in that they receive zero income in the future period and therefore
will default on any loan that is extended to them.
Can banks still be profitable ? Yes , if they If they pick an interest rate so that
▶ Their profits from good borrowers exceed losses from bad borrowers
Borrowers pay interest rate rb and banks pays lenders interest rate rL
To make a profit the interest rate to borrowers has to be higher than the interest rate they pay
to lenders.
In equilibrium, each bank must earn zero profits, since negative profits would imply that banks
would want to shut down and positive profits would imply that banks would want to expand
indefinitely. Therefore to have 0 profits the borrowing interest rate must be :
Rb = (1 + rL / a) - 1
As more people are unable to pay a → 0 , interest rate for all borrowers increase
As a result:
For a consumer who is a borrower, consumption in the current period and borrowing must
decrease as bad borrowers grows ( a declines) .
- Why some borrowers receive income in the future and some do not
- Investing in themselves or others , or just partying
- Some are lucky/unlucky
Actual risk
• How banks make loans and diversify risk across many borrowers
Limited Commitment
We = = y − t + (y ′ − t ′/ + pH 1 + r)
The bank will now only lend the borrower the price of the collateral asset
As -s(1 + rb) is the loan payment for the consumer in the future period, and pH is the value of
the collateral in the future period
- Consider a firm in the two-period investment model the produces output according to: Y = zKαN β and Y ′
= z ′ (K′ ) α (N ′ ) β The current-period total factor productivity z = 1, and the future-period total factor
productivity z ′ = 1. Other variables follow the same notation, with a prime (′) indicating the future period.
Initial capital K = 50, capital depreciates at rate d = 0.05, wages are w = 0.75 and w ′ = 0.85, and the real
interest rate is r = 0.06. Parameters α = 0.3 and β = 0.6.
- The consumer will make a work–leisure decision in each of the current and future
periods, and he or she will make a consumption–savings decision in the current period.
- The consumer’s current budget constraint is then C + S = w(h−l)+π−T.
- so that the consumer’s future budget constraint is C′=w′(h−l′)+π′−T′+(1+r)Sp
- lifetime budget constraint for the representative consumer :
C+(C′/1+r)=w(h−l)+π−T+(w′(h−l′)+π′−T′/1+r) .
- It is straightforward to describe the consumer’s optimizing decision in terms of three
marginal conditions we studied :
- 1. MRSl,c = w , the current real wage, w, is the relative price of leisure in terms of
consumption goods.
- 2. Similarly, in the future the consumer makes another work–leisure decision, and he or
she optimizes by setting , MRSl’,c’ = w’ at the optimum, the marginal rate of substitution
of future leisure for future consumption must be equal to the future real wage.
- 3. MRSc,c’ = 1 +r , when the consumer is optimizing the marginal rate of substitution of
current consumption for future consumption equals the relative price of current
consumption in terms of future consumption.
- How does an increase in the interest rate affect the supply of current labour?
- the price of current leisure in terms of future leisure increases
- Intertemporal substitution of leisure: less leisure today and more tomorrow
- Shifts labor supply curve to the right increasing labor supply
- How does an increase in lifetime wealth affect the supply of current labour?
- Shifts labor supply curve to the left decreasing labor supply
- Higher profits today increases the amount of leisure demanded today
- The labour supply curve slopes upward, as we are assuming that the substitution effect
of an increase in the real wage dominates the income effect, and recall that the position
of the labour supply curve depends on the real interest rate, r.
- Thus, with the increase in the real interest rate, the current labour supply curve shifts to
the right, the current equilibrium real wage falls from w1 to w2, and current
employment increases from N1 to N2.
- If the real interest rate is higher, the representative consumer will choose to supply
more labour, resulting in an increase in employment and output.
- With the increase in total factor productivity , forms get more profits and want to hire
more labor
- Labor demand curve shifts to the right
- General equilibrium effects: wage increases, consumers supply more labor ( assuming
sub effect dominates)
- Therefore the higher productivity increases current output supply and shifts the current
output supply curve to the right
- Output supply is how much gets produced by firms
- Output demand is what output is used for ( consumption, investment , government
expenditure)
The marginal propensity to consumer is the amount that current consumption increases when
income increases by $1. Usually between 0 and 1. MPC + MPS = 1 , MPS is the marginal
propensity to save. MPC is the derivative of consumption w.r.t income.
- A decrease in the present value of taxes shifts the output demand curve to the right
- An increase government spending shifts the output demand curve to the right
- An increase in the future total factor productivity z ′ shifts the output demand curve to
the right
- A decrease in the current capital stock K shifts the output demand curve to the right
- When drawn against the real interest rate, the output demand curve shifts to the right
when . current capital stock decreases.
Show how the firm’s investment decision is structured, and determine how changes in the
environment faced by the firm affect investment.
- which will involve equating the marginal cost of investment with the marginal benefit of
investment. We will let MC(I) denote the marginal cost of investment for the firm,
where MC(I) = 1
- The marginal benefit from investment, denoted by MB(I), is what one extra unit of
investment in the current period adds to the present value of profits, V
- First, an additional unit of current investment adds one unit to the future capital stock,
K′. This implies that the firm will produce more output in the future, and the additional
output produced is equal to the firm’s future marginal product of capital, MP′K.
- Second, each unit of current investment implies that there will be an additional 1−d
units of capital remaining at the end of the future period (after depreciation in the
future period), which can be liquidated. Thus, one unit of additional investment in the
current period implies an additional MP′K+1−d units of future profits,π′.
- The firm will invest until the marginal benefit from investment is equal to the marginal
cost—that is, MB(I) = MC(I) , MP ‘ K = r + d
- If the real interest rate decreases the demand for investment increases
- the optimal investment schedule will shift because of any factor that changes the future
net marginal product of capital. The optimal investment schedule shifts to the right if
future total factor productivity, z′, increases. Which means demand for investment
goods increases. This is because if firms thing future total productivity is going to
increase then they will invest in more capital now. Higher investment in the current
period leads to higher future productive capacity so that the firm can take advantage of
high future total factor productivity. The optimal investment schedule shifts to the left
if the current capital stock, K, is higher. That is, if K is larger, there is more of this initial
capital left after depreciation in the current period to use in future production.
Therefore, higher K implies that the future marginal product of capital, MP′K, will
decrease for each level of investment, and the optimal investment schedule will then
shift to the left.
- So if future productivity is to decrease then the optimal investment schedule will shift to
left. If the current capital stock is lower then the optimal investment schedule will shift
to the right.
- we assume that consumers consume a constant fraction of income in each period; that
is, C = (1 - s)Y , s is the savings rate
- The slope of the per-worker production function is the marginal product of capital, .
Economic history
- Before the Industrial Revolution (1800’s), standards of living differed little over time and
across countries
- Since the Industrial Revolution, a set of countries experienced a large amount of
economic development
-