2012AC Gandhi CP
2012AC Gandhi CP
AgEcon Search
h p://ageconsearch.umn.edu
[email protected]
Papers downloaded from AgEcon Search may be used for non-commercial purposes and personal study only.
No other use, including pos ng to another Internet site, is permi ed without permission from the copyright
owner (not AgEcon Search), or as allowed under the provisions of Fair Use, U.S. Copyright Act, Title 17 U.S.C.
No endorsement of AgEcon Search or its fundraising ac vi es by the author(s) of the following work or their
employer(s) is intended or implied.
tt
ti
ti
ti
tt
Determinants of Institutional Performance in
Watershed Management: A Study of the Nature and
Performance of Watershed Development
Institutions in Andhra Pradesh, India
Vasant P. Gandhi
Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad, India
Lin Crase
Latrobe University, Victoria, Australia
Contributed paper prepared for presentation at the 56th AARES Annual Conference,
Fremantle, Western Australia, February7-10, 2012
Copyright 2012 by Vasant P. Gandhi and Lin Crase. All rights reserved. Readers may make
verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that
this copyright notice appears on all such copies.
Determinants of Institutional Performance in Watershed
Management: A Study of the Nature and Performance of Watershed
Development Institutions in Andhra Pradesh, India
Vasant P. Gandhi
Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad, India
Lin Crase
Latrobe University, Victoria, Australia
Abstract
Introduction
2
Figure 1: A: Watershed Development in a “Ridge to Valley” Concept
A. Bench terracing
B. Contour Trenches & Bunds B
C. Gully Controls C
D. Brush wood dams
E. Rock Fill dams. D
F. Check Dams
E
G. Farm Ponds
H. Percolation Tanks F
I. Wells, irrigation Tanks & Other
G H I
Conservation Measures.
3
The history of watershed development in India can be traced to the Famine
Commission of 1880, again the Royal Commission of Agriculture of 1928, which
recognized its importance for India. After independence in 1947, the government
establishment a special centre at Jodhpur in 1952 and in 1959 this was designated
as Central Arid Zone Research Institute (CAZRI). The first large scale government
supported watershed programme was launched in 1962-63, and a mega sized
project named the Drought Prone Area Development Programme (DPAP) was
launched in 1972-73. Then, a special programme for the hot desert areas, the
Desert Development Programme (DDP) was launched in 1977-78. Later the
Integrated Wastelands Development Programme (IWDP) was added. In 1993, the
Government of India constituted a technical committee headed by Dr C.H
Hanumantha Rao to review these programmes. The Committee proposed a revamp,
recommending various measures including sanctioning of works on the basis of the
action plans on watershed basis, and introduction of participatory modes of
implementation, through involvement of beneficiaries of the programme and NGOs.
Based on its recommendations a new set of guidelines came into effect in 1995. The
coverage of various programs since then is outlined in the Table below, and shows
the huge size.
Table 1 : Number of Projects, Area Covered and Funds released for Watershed
Development from 1995-96 to 2007-2008 in India
Name of Number of Area covered in Total funds released by
Programme projects lakh ha. Central Government (Rupees
sanctioned Million)
DPAP 27439 (60.9 %) 130.20 (41.2 %) 28378 (36.7 %)
DDP 15746 (34.9 %) 78.73 (24.9 %) 21032 (27.2 %)
IWDP 1877 (33.9 %) 107.00 (33.9 %) 27976 (36.1 %)
Total 45062 322.93 77386
4
The institutional arrangements for implementation of watershed development
programmes includes higher level entities such as the National and State level
Watershed Programme Implementation and Review Committees, and the state
Department of Rural Development. At the district level, the District Rural
Development Agency (DRDA) earlier and now the District Water Management
Agency (DWMA) is the highest body for headed by a Project Director (PD). The
lower level entities include Multi Disciplinary Teams (MDT), Project Implementing
Agencies (PIA) and Watershed Development Teams (WDTs), and other entities
such as the Panchayat, Watershed Committee, Village Organization, Water User
Groups and Self Help Groups. The examples of two institutional structures seen in
WSD programmes at the district level are given in Figures 2 & 3 below:
Figure 2
Institutional Arrangements -I
Institutional Framework of watershed development prior to 2001
DRDA
MDT
WC WDT PIA
Figure 3
DWMA DRDA
MDT
WC WDT PIA
VO
5
economics offers different approaches to understand the institutions, including
transaction costs and property rights (North 1997, Drobak and Nye 1997). A
principal premise is that economic activities have both transformation costs and
transaction costs. Often, transaction costs are ignored, and when large, substantially
reduce performance. Good institutions is to reduce transaction costs. According to
North (1997), the major challenge is to evolve institutions in which: (1) The
transaction costs are minimized, (2) The incentives favour co-operative solution, in
which cumulative experiences and collective learning are best utilised.
1. Clear Objectives: Good institutions show clear objectives and clarity of purpose.
6
1. Technical Rationality: Efficient conversion of inputs into outputs, technology and
operational procedures, experts, soundness in the selection of technologies and
structures, their location, their specifications and their construction.
4. Social Rationality: Consider the social or people setting, seeking the acceptance
and cooperation of the different social groups, participation, distribution of the
support and benefits
8. Government Rationality: A mega mover and supporter, the kind, quantum, speed
and nature of government support, the guidelines, budgets as well as structures,
procedures of the government, knowledge, guidance, commitment/ drive of
government functionaries.
7
Figure 4: A Depiction of the Conceptual Framework
Economic &
Environmental Organizational Local Organization,
Rationality & Financial WC, VO, UG, SHG,
Rationality Leadership, Coordination,
Clear Objectives Compliance Financial Discipline
Clarity of Purpose To Rules,
Procedures
Good Interaction
Appropriate Bringing Formal &
Scale Informal Together
Scale, Size, Scope
Adaptiveness
Adaptation & Flexibility
to Settings & Changes
Social & People, Castes/Tribes, Land
Political Groups, Customs, Beliefs,
Technical NRM Methods, Locations, Rationality Power Centers, Leaders,
Rationality Specifications, Quality, Involvement/ Participation,
New Crops, Varieties, Distribution of Benefits
Technologies, Enterprises
8
Measuring Performance of Watershed Institutions
2. Equity: Achieving and improving equity in the resource availability and benefits
Data
Data for the empirical study was collected from several rainfed districts of the
state of Andhra Pradesh through the above mentioned ACIAR supported research
project. This is the largest state in the southern plateau region of India and is over 50
percent rainfed. It provides a good setting for watershed development work and has
substantial incidence of poverty. Watershed development is given high priority and
Andhra Pradesh has the highest number of watershed projects among the states in
the country (over 9000) at different stages of implementation. WSD projects have
been taken up under various development programmes/ guidelines including the
Drought Prone Area Programme (DPAP), the Desert Development Programme
(DDP), and the Andhra Pradesh Rural Livelihoods Project (APRLP), recently brought
together under the Integrated Watershed Management Programme (IWMP)
guidelines. Andhra Pradesh is at the forefront of strengthening of institutional and
participatory processes in watershed development and the focus on improving
livelihoods especially of the poor.
9
association with the Department of Rural Development, Andhra Pradesh, to cover
different agro-ecological conditions including rainfall, water and topography, social
conditions, different programmes/ norms/ administrative structures such as DDP,
DPAP, APRLP, Hariyali, with and without involvement of NGOs, VOs, SHGs, varying
age/ maturity (nearing completion or recently completed), and varying outcomes, as
broadly known.
10
questions it also sought the assessment of the beneficiaries on the eight different
rationalities using a five-point rating scale. Similarly, it sought their assessment on
the implementation of the five different institutional features. The performance of
the institutions was recorded in terms of parameters such as change in the depth of
water table, change in irrigated area and changes in the cropping pattern. It was
also assessed in terms of the perceived overall success of the institution on a five
point rating scale, as well as performance on the objectives of overcoming scarcity,
equity, environment and financial soundness through response on sets of questions
on a five point rating scale. Data was collected during 2010-11. The analysis of the
data on selected aspects is presented here.
Sample Profile
The profile of the respondents on selected features is described below. The Table
shows the responses on the reliance on the WSD institution. It indicates that for 77
per cent of the sample the reliance is substantial, and very substantial for another 16
percent. Thus, the WSD institution is important for almost all the respondents. The
table also indicates that the sample is quite evenly distributed across upper, middle
and lower reaches. With respect to land owned, about 50 percent own less than 5
acres of land and only about 11 per cent have more than 10 acres of land. About 20
per cent of the sample is landless. A majority of the villages surveyed are located
between 5-20 km from the nearest town.
11
Acres Percent
>0 - 2 13.7
2-4 21.7
4-5 14.3
5-8 11.6
8-10 7.9
Over 10 10.9
Total 79.7
Landless 20.3
Total 100.0
Distance of Village to Nearest Town
Kms Percent
Up to 5 11.1
5-10 39.7
10-20 32.3
20-30 11.8
Over 30 5.2
Total 100.0
12
Village Pond 4 3.00 5.00 3.7500 .95743
13
Involvement in Watershed Development Institutions
The Table below indicates that there was considerable variation in the activity level
of different groups and structures in relation to the watershed development
institution. The Table indicates that 53 percent report the general body was active to
very active and 44 percent report that it was passive. However, the leader or head of
the institution was reported active by 90 percent of the respondents. The landless
were reported passive by 51 per cent and the women were reported active by 44
percent. The involvement and activity level would have a bearing on the
performance.
Assessment on Rationalities
Different questions were asked to make an assessment about the status of different
rationalities. The table below shows a few of the questions asked on technical,
environmental, economic, and social rationalities and the responses obtained from
14
the beneficiaries. On technical rationality, the Table shows that technical experts
and considerations were reported to be involved in most cases for NRM activities but
not so far EP activities. With respect to the maintenance of structures substantial
number only partially agree that this was good and on the high capability of experts
many only partially agree.
With respect to environmental rationality, whereas this was reported to have been
taken into consideration in most cases for NRM activities, environment was not
reported as considered for a large number of PE and EP activities. On economic
rationality, most beneficiaries agree that the NRM structures were well selected for
economic benefits, but a vast number indicated that market demand and profitability
were not considered and good marketing arrangements were not created. With
respect to social rationality, most beneficiaries agree that mobilization and
involvement of various social groups was actively done, but many indicate that the
interest and benefits of small and marginal farmers and the landless were not taken
into consideration. On all these counts there appears to be considerable variations.
15
3. Good marketing arrangements existed/
were created for the produce from WSD
activities. 0.2 2.3 5.8 18.9 72.8
Social Rationality
1. Mobilization and involvement of various
social groups was actively done in deciding
about the WSD activities. 20.1 50 17.5 11.8 0.6
2. Interests and benefits to small and marginal
farmers were actively considered in
deciding about WSD activities. 25.8 34.6 27.3 7.7 4.7
3. Interests and benefits to landless
households were actively considered in
deciding about WSD activities. 7.5 23.6 40.8 22.3 5.8
The table below gives the responses of the beneficiaries on selected questions
pertaining to political, organizational, financial and government rationalities. On
political rationality, most beneficiaries indicate that the participation of all village
leaders was invited at the start of the project, but a large number indicate that the
institutions did not have strong politically able leadership, and they were not able to
balance the demands of various power groups, and settle major disputes. On
organizational rationality, most beneficiateis indicate that good local institutions were
created for WSD activities, but in a large number indicate that user groups were not
created for NRM activities, and many indicate that there was lack of regular
meetings, and also deficiencies in the coordination and management of activities.
On financial rationality, around 60 per cent of beneficiaries indicate that the funds
were efficiently handled and there was no dispute about the management of funds
but the rest indicate some difficulty with respect to this, and a majority indicate that
the financial position of the institution is not very sound. On government rationality,
whereas about 20 to 30 per cent benefiaries indicate that there was substantial
government help and it was speedy, the rest indicate difficulty with respect to this,
and majority indicate that the government could not help in resolving disputes and
problems. There is, however, substantial variation in these responses.
16
groups, and settle all major disputes
Organizational Rationality
1. Good local institutions/organizations
were created/ designated clearly to lead,
plan and implement WSD activities 15.8 54.8 18.4 9.3 1.7
2. Active User Groups (UGs) were created
for NRM activities 18.5 22 18 17.8 23.7
3. There were regular meetings for all WSD
activities (NRM, PE and EP) 28.2 38.1 20 8.2 5.4
4. Planning, implementation and delivery of
the WSD activities (NRM, PE and EP)
was very well coordinated and managed. 11.9 47.9 28.3 9.7 2.2
Financial Rationality
1. The funds were very efficiently handled
for the intended purpose and
beneficiaries 28.1 40.5 27.7 3.7 0.0
2. There was no dispute about the
management of funds 15.7 45.4 25.7 10.9 2.2
3. The financial position of the WSD
institutions is extremely sound/ surplus 9.6 17.5 22.6 27 23.2
Government Rationality
1. The government officials helped in
mobilizing village people and creating
the local organizations for WSD 8.7 33 33 14.9 10.3
2. The local organization and government
officials received speedy support and
cooperation from the higher officials. 2.6 20.5 37.1 34.8 5
3. The government officials helped in
resolving any disputes and problems. 0.2 10.2 14.1 20 55.4
The table below provides responses on a few of the questions regarding the
presence of institutional features, which are derived from the concepts of new
institutional economics. On the clarity of objectives, a majority indicate that the
objectives of the WSD institution were cleared to everyone, but a signficiant number
indicate that there were deviations from the objectives in various WSD activities. On
the presence of good interaction, a majority indicate that there was a good
interaction between WSD institution and the villagers, but many indicate deficiency
in good leadership to facilitate the interaction and also deficiency in the interaction
between the WSD institution and higher level institutions such as the government.
17
level issues were not properly addressed by higher level authorities. With respect to
compliance, most beneficiaries indicate that the institution used its powers to bring
compliance, but a large percentage only partially agree, and in a majority of cases,
no external monitoring or enforcement was indicated.
18
3. There was external monitoring and
enforcement of the rules, procedures
and funds handling/ utilization 5 13.9 40.5 33.1 7.4
Assessment of Performance
The table below gives responses on a few of the questions asked to assess
performance on these different counts. The responses indicate that in a majority of
cases, structures for conservation of natural resources have been created and water
conservation has improved, but there are deficiencies regarding maintenance and
protection of the structures, and in most cases, there is inadequate monitoring of
water use. With respect to equity, most agree that there is a fair distribution
between small and large farmers, but in many cases, not so across farmers and the
landless, and often there is no monitoring for equality in the distribution of benefits.
On the environmental front, most indicate that soil erosion has reduced and there is
no flooding or water logging. However, in many cases, there has been a depletion of
the groundwater and that institutions have hardly monitored or controlled the
environmental harm. With respect to finance, most beneficiaries indicate that the
institutions got sufficient funds from the government, but in a majority of cases,
contributions could not be raised from the beneficiaries, the financial disciplines was
not monitored by the government, and the institutions was not financially sound.
With respect to the overall success, about 47 per cent consider the institutions to be
successful, but 43 per cent consider the performance only satisfactory and only 9
per cent consider their institutions highly successful. There is a large amount of
variation in the responses regarding various parameters of success, indicating
considerable variation in performance.
19
2. Water conservation has improved 35.5 55.7 8.6 0.2 0.0
3. The structures were well maintained &
protected 13.5 51.4 26.4 7.7 1.0
4. Water use of villagers was monitored and
controlled 2.3 16.7 38.4 33.9 8.7
Equity
1. The benefits were equally distributed between
small and large farmers 16.4 42.8 24.0 15.1 1.7
2. The benefits were equally distributed between
farmers and the landless 5.6 29.9 27.1 22.7 14.7
3. The benefits of were equally distributed
between different social groups 11.7 44.6 22.6 16.3 4.8
4. Distribution of benefits was monitored/
controlled for equality 8.9 37.9 34.2 14.9 4.1
Environment
1. Soil erosion reduced in the village 14.2 47.8 34.3 2.6 1.1
2. There was no flooding or water logging in the
village 43.8 31.2 20.0 4.1 0.9
3. There was no great depletion of ground water
in the village 4.8 48.4 32.0 14.0 0.7
4. The institution monitored and controlled
environmental harm/ depletion 1.1 13.7 25.9 43.3 15.9
Finance
1. The institution got sufficient funds from the
government 14.4 65.1 16.1 4.4 0.0
2. The institution could raise contributions from
the beneficiaries 6.7 14.5 17.6 26.3 34.9
3. Financial discipline was monitored by the
government 9.2 21.4 34.7 30.6 4.1
4. The institution was financially sound/ surplus 10.9 17.9 17.5 28.9 24.8
Overall Assessment of Success
Highly Succe Satisfac Somewh Very
Success ssful tory at poor poor
ful
Rating percent 8.7 46.5 43.4 1.3 0.2
20
responses have been aggregated to provide an aggregate assessment. Dummy
variables have been included for the districts.
The Table below provides the results on the relationship of overall success to new
institutional economics based institutional features. Each feature has been assessed
through a set of questions, of which the responses have been aggregated. Results
indicates a strong association with the features of good interaction and adaptiveness
at 99 percent level of significance. The relationship with scale is also strong at 90
percent level. The relationship with compliance and with clear objectives is not
significant. The results validate the relevance of new institutional economics in
determining the performance of institutions. In particular it shows that good
interaction, adaptiveness, and scale are very important institutional features for good
performance of watershed institutions.
21
ClObj 1 -0.01437 0.054897 -0.26 0.7935
GoodInt 1 0.262728 0.059559 4.41 <.0001
Adpt 1 0.208558 0.06714 3.11 0.0019
Scale 1 0.121771 0.067606 1.8 0.0717
Comp 1 0.075421 0.0713 1.06 0.2902
DummyAnantapur 1 -0.03377 0.076867 -0.44 0.6605
DummyNalgonda 1 -0.08406 0.078856 -1.07 0.2864
_Sigma 1 0.677771 0.022187 30.55 <.0001
n=540
It has been indicated above that the performance of watershed institutions has four
important dimensions. These are performance in overcoming scarcity, achieving
equity, addressing the environment, and financial soundness. Assessment has
been made on a 5 point rating scale through sets of pertinent questions regarding
the performance of the institutions on each of these performance measures, which
have been aggregated. The Table below provides the results on the relationship
between scarcity and the different rationalities. The results indicate a positive, strong
and statistically significant relationship with technical rationality, economic rationality
and organizational rationality. The relationship with political rationality is found to be
negative and significant. The results indicate that on technical, economic and
organizational rationality within institutions are critical for performance on
overcoming scarcity. Over-emphasis on political rationality may have a negative
impact on the institutional performance on scarcity.
The Table below indicates the relationship between the performance on equity and
the different rationalities. The results indicate a strong and statistically significant
relationship with social, environmental, organizational and financial rationalities. The
results indicate that for achievement of equitable outcomes, the institutional focus on
social, environmental, organizational, and finacial rationalities are particularly
22
important. Technical rationality is negative and mildly significant indicating a mild
inverse relationship.
23
The Table below provides results on the relationship between financial soundness
and performance with the different rationalities. The results indicate a strong
association with financial rationality as may be expected. It also indicates a strong
relationship with environmental, economic, social political and organizational
rationalities. The results indicate that institutional focus on these rationalities are
very important for financial soundness and performance. The technical rationality
shows a negative association which may indicate that technical rationality may
involve large expenditures which may weaken the financial position of the institution.
The study has applied new institutional economics and management theories of
governance to understand the performance of watershed institutions. A framework
has been developed and empirically explored through a large sample of watershed
development institutions and beneficiaries in Andhra Pradesh, India. The results
indicate the substantial importance of the institutional features of good interaction,
adaptiveness and appropriate scale for the performance of watershed institutions.
The results also show that the addressing of critical rationalities particularly
technical, organizational and financial is extremely important for the performance of
24
these institutions. The results are somewhat mix with respect to social,
environmental, and economic rationalities. Social and environmental rationalities
are found to be very important for achieving equity; environmental and government
rationalities important for performance on the environment; and financial, economic
and social rationalities for the performance on financial soundness. Strong
emphasis on political rationality seems to diminish performance on many fronts.
The results show that the good design of watershed development institutions is very
important for successful outcomes of livelihoods and environment. It is important
that the structure and processes of these institutions strongly provides for technical
rationality in the implementation through the deployment of experts, good technology
and guidance. It is also important that community mobilization for formation of strong
local organizations to implement watershed development is given substantial
emphasis. Through setting proper procedures and monitoring, it is also of great
importance to ensure financial rationality in the implementing organizations. Overall
the institutions must ensure good interaction to bring the formal and informal
together for planning and implementation. This is strongly related with performance.
Adaptiveness in the rules and procedures, and appropriate scale of operation is also
found to be very important to bring good performance. These features need to be
clearly incorporated in the government guidelines and the institutional structures and
systems involved in watershed development programs to improve their impact on
productivity, livelihoods and poverty alleviation.
References
25
7. Gandhi, Vasant P and N.V. Namboodiri. (2002), “Water Resource Management
in India: Institutions and Development”, in Brennan, Donna (ed) in Brennan,
Donna (ed) Water Policy Reform: Lessons from Asia and Australia, Australian
Centre for International Agricultural Research (ACIAR), Canberra.
8. Gandhi, Vasant P., Crase, Lin, and Roy, Ashutosh (2009), “Institutional
Analysis of the Performance of Water Institutions in Three Major States of
India,” in Lin Crase and Vasant P. Gandhi (eds.), Reforming Institutions in
Water Resource Management: Policy and Performance for Sustainable
Development, London: Earthscan.
9. Gandhi, Vasant P.,& Namboodri, N.V. (2009); “Water Resource Development
and Institutions in India: Overview and Profile” in Lin Crase and Vasant P.
Gandhi ,Edited, “Reforming Institutions in Water Resource Management:
Policy and Performance for Sustainable Development”, Earthscan: London,
2009.
10. Groth, Lars (1999), Future Organizational Design: The Scope for IT-Based
Enterprise, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester.
11. Herath, Gamini (2002). “Issues in Irrigation and Water Management in
Developing Countries with Special Reference to Institutions”, in Brennan,
Donna (ed) op.cited.
12. ICAR. (2009). Handbook of Agriculture. New Delhi:.Indian Council of
Agricultural Research (ICAR)
13. Kerr, J. (2007). Watershed Management: Lessons from Common Property
Theory. International Journal of the Commons , 1 (1), 89-109.
14. North, Douglass, C. (1990). “Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic
Performance”, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge UK.
15. North, Douglass, C. (1997). “Prologue”, in John K. Drobak, and John, V.C. Nye,
(Eds), The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, Academic Press,
California.
16. Nystrom, Paul C. and Starbuck, William H. (Ed), (1981). “Handbook of
Organizational Design”, Oxford University Press.
17. Olson, Mancur and Kahkonen, Satu, 2000. “Introduction: The Broader View” in
A New Institutional Approach to Economic Development, Kahkonen, S. and
Olson, M. (Eds.); Oxford University Press, 1-36.
18. Ostrom,Elinor (1992). Crafting Institutions for Self-Governing Irrigation
Systems, ICS Press, San Francisco.
19. Pagan P., (2009) “Laws, Customs and Rules: Identifying the Characteristics of
Successful Water Management Institutions”, in Crase, Lin and Gandhi, Vasant
P. Ed. Reforming Institutions in Water Resource Management: Policy and
Performance for Sustainable Development, London: Earthscan
26
20. Report of the Technical Committee on Drought prone Areas Programme and
Desert Development Programme ,April 1994 (Hanumantha Rao Committee
Report)
21. Report of the Technical Committee on Watershed Programmes in India
Department of Land Resources Ministry of Rural Development Government of
India, January 2006 (From Hariyali to Neeranchal).
22. Saleth, Maria R. (1996). Water Institutions in India: Economics, Law and Policy,
Commonwealth Publishers, New Delhi.
23. Shiferaw, B., Kebede, T., & Reddy, V. R. (2008). Community Watershed
Management In Semi-Arid India: The State of Collective Action and its Effects
on Natural Resources and Rural Livelihoods. CAPRi. Washington DC: IFPRI.
24. Vaidyanathan, A., (1999); “Water resource management: institutions and
irrigation development in India”; New Delhi, Oxford University Press.
25. Williamson, Oliver E. (2000). “Economic Institutions and Development: A View
from the Bottom” in A New Institutional Approach to Economic Development,
Kahkonen, S. and Olson, M. (Eds.); Oxford University Press, 92-118.
26. World Bank. (2007). Watershed Management Approaches, Policies and
Operations:Lessons For Scaling-Up. In Kerr, J. (2007). Watershed
Management: Lessons from Common Property Theory.
27. World Water Vision (2000), (Cosgrove, William J. and Frank R. Rijsberman),
Making Water Everybody’s Business, World Water Council.
27