Ross Chapter17
Ross Chapter17
DIVIDENDS AND
DIVIDEND POLICY
Barrick Gold
Courtesy of
O n May 2, 2012, Barrick Gold, the world’s
largest gold miner, headquartered
Toronto, reported a big first quarter profit of around
in
were known for paying low dividends, Barrick had
increased its dividend by 260 percent in 5 years due
to its superior earnings and operating cash flows.
US $1 billion. As a result, the company decided to Explaining dividends and dividend policy is the focus
hike its dividend by 33 percent to 20 cents US a of this chapter.
share from 15 cents US. While other gold companies
Dividend policy is an important subject in corporate finance, and dividends are a major cash
outlay for many corporations. At first glance, it may seem obvious that a firm would always want
to give as much as possible back to its shareholders by paying dividends. It might seem equally
obvious, however, that a firm can always invest the money for its shareholders instead of paying
it out. The heart of the dividend policy question is just this: Should the firm pay out money to its
shareholders, or should the firm take that money and invest it for its shareholders?
It may seem surprising, but much research and economic logic suggest that dividend policy
doesn’t matter. In fact, it turns out that the dividend policy issue is much like the capital structure
question. The important elements are not difficult to identify, but the interactions between those
elements are complex and no easy answer exists.
Dividend policy is controversial. Many implausible reasons are given for why dividend policy
might be important, and many of the claims made about dividend policy are economically illogi-
cal. Even so, in the real world of corporate finance, determining the most appropriate dividend
policy is considered an important issue. It could be that financial managers who worry about
dividend policy are wasting time, but it could be true that we are missing something important
in our discussions.
In part, all discussions of dividends are plagued by the “two-handed lawyer” problem. Former
U.S. President Harry S. Truman, while discussing the legal implications of a possible presidential
decision, asked his staff to set up a meeting with a lawyer. Supposedly, Truman said, “But I don’t
want one of those two-handed lawyers.” When asked what a two-handed lawyer was, he replied,
“You know, a lawyer who says, ‘On the one hand I recommend you do so and so because of
the following reasons, but on the other hand I recommend that you don’t do it because of these
other reasons.’ ”
Unfortunately, any sensible treatment of dividend policy appears to be written by a two-
handed lawyer (or, in fairness, several two-handed financial economists). On the one hand, there
are many good reasons for corporations to pay high dividends; on the other hand, there are also
many good reasons to pay low dividends or no dividends.
We cover three broad topics that relate to dividends and dividend policy in this chapter. First,
we describe the various kinds of dividends and how dividends are paid. Second, we consider an
idealized case in which dividend policy doesn’t matter. We then discuss the limitations of this
case and present some practical arguments for both high- and low-dividend payouts. Finally, we
conclude the chapter by looking at some strategies that corporations might employ to implement
a dividend policy.
Cash Dividends
regular cash dividend The most common type of dividend is a cash dividend. Commonly, public companies pay regular
Cash payment made by a cash dividends four times a year. As the name suggests, these are cash payments made directly to
firm to its owners in the
shareholders, and they are made in the regular course of business. In other words, management
normal course of business,
usually made four times a sees nothing unusual about the dividend and no reason it won’t be continued.
year. Sometimes firms pay a regular cash dividend and an extra cash dividend. By calling part of the
payment extra, management is indicating it may or may not be repeated in the future. A special divi-
dend is similar, but the name usually indicates that this dividend is viewed as a truly unusual or one-
time event and won’t be repeated. For example, in May 2010, Sears Canada paid a special dividend
of $3.50 per share. The total payout of $368 million was the largest one-time corporate dividend in
history. Finally, a liquidating dividend usually means that some or all of the business has been liqui-
dated, that is, sold off. Debt covenants, discussed in Chapter 7, offer the firm’s creditors protection
against liquidating dividends that could violate their prior claim against assets and cash flows.
However it is labelled, a cash dividend payment reduces corporate cash and retained earnings,
except in the case of a liquidating dividend (where capital may be reduced).
FIGURE 17.1
Distribution of
Internal New
corporate cash flow cash flow financing
Total
cash flow
Stock Cash
repurchases dividends
FIGURE 17.2
FIGURE 17.3
The stock price will fall by the amount of the dividend on the ex date (time 0). If the dividend is $1 per share, the price will be equal to
$10 - $1 = $9 on the ex date:
Before ex date (-1) dividend = 0 Price = $10
Ex-date (0) dividend = $1 Price = $9
If you buy the stock on Monday, June 11, right as the market closes, you’ll get the $1 dividend
because the stock is trading cum dividend. If you wait and buy it right as the market opens on
Tuesday, you won’t get the $1 dividend. What will happen to the value of the stock overnight?
If you think about it, the stock is obviously worth about $1 less on Tuesday morning, so its
price will drop by this amount between close of business on Monday and the Tuesday opening. In
general, we expect the value of a share of stock to go down by about the dividend amount when
the stock goes ex dividend. The key word here is about. Since dividends are taxed, the actual price
drop might be closer to some measure of the after-tax value of the dividend. Determining this
value is complicated because of the different tax rates and tax rules that apply for different buyers.
The series of events described here is illustrated in Figure 17.3.
The amount of the price drop is a matter for empirical investigation. Researchers have argued
that, due to personal taxes, the stock price should drop by less than the dividend.1 For example,
consider the case with no capital gains taxes. On the day before a stock goes ex dividend, share-
holders must decide either to buy the stock immediately and pay tax on the forthcoming dividend,
or to buy the stock tomorrow, thereby missing the dividend. If all investors are in a 30 percent
bracket for dividends and the quarterly dividend is $1, the stock price should fall by $.70 on the
ex-dividend date. If the stock price falls by this amount on the ex-dividend date, then purchasers
receive the same return from either strategy.
Concept Questions
1
The original argument was advanced and tested for the United States by E. Elton and M. Gruber, “Marginal Stockholder
Tax Rates and the Clientele Effect,” Review of Economics and Statistics 52 (February 1970). Canadian evidence (discussed
briefly later in this chapter) is from J. Lakonishok and T. Vermaelen, “Tax Reform and Ex-Dividend Day Behavior,” Jour-
nal of Finance 38 (September 1983) pp. 1157–80, and L. D. Booth and D. J. Johnston, “The Ex-Dividend Day Behavior of
Canadian Stock Prices: Tax Changes and Clientele Effects,” Journal of Finance 39 (June 1984), pp. 457–76.
2
The same results would occur after an issue of bonds, though the arguments would be less easily presented.
pointed when informed that the firm’s management is adopting the alternative dividend policy
(dividends of $110 and $89 in the two dates, respectively)? Not necessarily, because the investor
could easily reinvest the $10 of unneeded funds received on Date 1 by buying more Wharton
stock. At 10 percent, this investment grows to $11 at Date 2. Thus, the investor would receive the
desired net cash flow of $110 - 10 = $100 at Date 1 and $89 + 11 = $100 at Date 2.
Conversely, imagine Investor Z, preferring $110 of cash flow at Date 1 and $89 of cash flow at
Date 2, finds that management pays dividends of $100 at both Dates 1 and 2. This investor can sim-
ply sell $10 worth of stock to boost his or her total cash at Date 1 to $110. Because this investment
returns 10 percent, Investor Z gives up $11 at Date 2 ($10 × 1.1), leaving him with $100 - 11 = $89.
Our two investors are able to transform the corporation’s dividend policy into a different policy
homemade dividends by buying or selling on their own. The result is that investors are able to create homemade divi-
Idea that individual investors dends. This means dissatisfied shareholders can alter the firm’s dividend policy to suit themselves.
can undo corporate dividend
As a result, there is no particular advantage to any one dividend policy that the firm might choose.
policy by reinvesting
dividends or selling shares Many corporations actually assist their shareholders in creating homemade dividend policies
of stock. by offering automatic dividend reinvestment plans (ADPs or DRIPs). As the name suggests, with
such a plan, shareholders have the option of automatically reinvesting some or all of their cash
dividends in shares of stock.
Under a new issue dividend reinvestment plan, investors buy new stock issued by the firm.
They may receive a small discount on the stock, usually under 5 percent, or be able to buy without
a broker’s commission. This makes dividend reinvestment very attractive to investors who do not
need cash flow from dividends. Since the discount or lower commission compares favourably
with issue costs for new stock discussed in Chapter 15, dividend reinvestment plans are popular
with large companies like BCE that periodically seek new common stock.3
Investment dealers also use financial engineering to create homemade dividends (or homemade
stripped common shares capital gains). Called stripped common shares, these vehicles entitle holders to receive either all
Common stock on which the dividends from one or a group of well-known companies or an installment receipt that pack-
dividends and capital gains
ages any capital gain in the form of a call option. The option gives the investor the right to buy the
are repackaged and sold
separately. underlying shares at a fixed price and so it is valuable if the shares appreciate beyond that price.
A TEST Our discussion to this point can be summarized by considering the following true/
false test questions:
1. True or false: Dividends are irrelevant.
2. True or false: Dividend policy is irrelevant.
The first statement is surely false, and the reason follows from common sense. Clearly, investors
prefer higher dividends to lower dividends at any single date if the dividend level is held constant
at every other date. To be more precise regarding the first question, if the dividend per share at
a given date is raised while the dividend per share at each other date is held constant, the stock
price rises. The reason is that the present value of the future dividends must go up if this occurs.
This action can be accomplished by management decisions that improve productivity, increase
tax savings, strengthen product marketing, or otherwise improve cash flow.
The second statement is true, at least in the simple case we have been examining. Dividend
policy by itself cannot raise the dividend at one date while keeping it the same at all other dates.
Rather, dividend policy merely establishes the trade-off between dividends at one date and divi-
dends at another date. Once we allow for time value, the present value of the dividend stream is
unchanged. Thus, in this simple world, dividend policy does not matter, because managers choos-
ing either to raise or to lower the current dividend do not affect the current value of their firm.
However, we have ignored several real-world factors that might lead us to change our minds; we
pursue some of these in subsequent sections.
Concept Questions
3
Reinvested dividends are still taxable.
Taxes
The logic we used to establish that dividend policy does not affect firm value ignored the real-
world complication of taxes. In Canada, both dividends and capital gains are taxed at effective
rates less than the marginal tax rates.
For dividends, we showed in Chapter 2 that individual investors face a lower tax rate due to
the dividend tax credit. Capital gains in the hands of individuals are taxed at 50 percent of the
marginal tax rate. Since taxation only occurs when capital gains are realized, capital gains are very
lightly taxed in Canada. On balance, capital gains are subject to lower taxes than dividends.
A firm that adopts a low-dividend payout reinvests the money instead of paying it out. This
reinvestment increases the value of the firm and of the equity. All other things being equal, the net
effect is that the capital gains portion of the return is higher in the future. So, the fact that capital
gains are taxed favourably may lead us to prefer this approach.
This tax disadvantage of dividends doesn’t necessarily lead to a policy of paying no dividends.
Suppose a firm has some excess cash after selecting all positive NPV projects. The firm might
consider the following alternatives to a dividend:
1. Select additional capital budgeting projects. Because the firm has taken all the available posi-
tive NPV projects already, it must invest its excess cash in negative NPV projects. This is
clearly a policy at variance with the principles of corporate finance and represents an exam-
ple of the agency costs of equity introduced in Chapter 1. Still, research suggests that some
companies are guilty of doing this.4 It is frequently argued that managers who adopt nega-
tive NPV projects are ripe for takeover, leveraged buyouts, and proxy fights.
2. Repurchase shares. A firm may rid itself of excess cash by repurchasing shares of stock. In
both the United States and Canada, investors can treat profits on repurchased stock in pub-
lic companies as capital gains and pay somewhat lower taxes than they would if the cash
were distributed as a dividend.
3. Acquire other companies. To avoid the payment of dividends, a firm might use excess cash to
acquire another company. This strategy has the advantage of acquiring profitable assets.
However, a firm often incurs heavy costs when it embarks on an acquisition program. In ad-
dition, acquisitions are invariably made above the market price. Premiums of 20 to 80 per-
cent are not uncommon. Because of this, a number of researchers have argued that mergers
are not generally profitable to the acquiring company, even when firms are merged for a
valid business purpose.5 Therefore, a company making an acquisition merely to avoid a divi-
dend is unlikely to succeed.
4. Purchase financial assets. The strategy of purchasing financial assets in lieu of a dividend
payment can be illustrated with the following example.
Suppose the Regional Electric Company has $1,000 of extra cash. It can retain the cash and invest
it in Treasury bills yielding 8 percent, or it can pay the cash to shareholders as a dividend. Share-
holders can also invest in Treasury bills with the same yield. Suppose, realistically, that the tax
rate is 44 percent on ordinary income like interest on Treasury bills for both the company and
individual investors and the individual tax rate on dividends is 30 percent. What is the amount of
cash that investors have after five years under each policy?
Dividends paid now:
If dividends are paid now, shareholders will receive $1,000 before taxes, or $1,000 × (1 - .30) =
4
M. C. Jensen, “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flows, Corporate Finance and Takeovers,” American Economic Review, May
1986, pp. 323–29.
5
The original hypothesis comes from R. Roll, “The Hubris Hypothesis of Corporate Takeovers,” Journal of Business
(1986). Chapter 23 presents some Canadian examples.
$700 after taxes. This is the amount they invest. If the rate on T-bills is 8 percent, before taxes, then
the after-tax return is 8% × (1 - .44) = 4.48% per year. Thus, in five years, the shareholders have:
$700 × (1 + 0.0448)5 = $871.49
Company retains cash:
If Regional Electric Company retains the cash, invests in Treasury bills, and pays out the proceeds
five years from now, then $1,000 will be invested today. However, since the corporate tax rate is
44 percent, the after-tax return from the T-bills will be 8% × (1 - .44) = 4.48% per year. In five
years, the investment will be worth:
$1,000 × (1 + 0.0448)5 = $1,244.99
If this amount is then paid out as a dividend, after taxes the shareholders receive:
$1,244.99 × (1 - .30) = $871.49
In this case, dividends are the same after taxes whether the firm pays them now or later after
investing in Treasury bills. The reason is that the firm invests exactly as profitably as the share-
holders do on an after-tax basis.
This example shows that for a firm with extra cash, the dividend payout decision depends on
personal and corporate tax rates. All other things the same, when personal tax rates are higher
than corporate tax rates, a firm has an incentive to reduce dividend payouts. This would have
occurred if we changed our example to have the firm invest in preferred stock instead of T-bills.
(Recall from Chapter 8 that corporations enjoy a 100 percent exclusion of dividends from tax-
able income.) However, if personal tax rates on dividends are lower than corporate tax rates (for
investors in lower tax brackets or tax-exempt investors), a firm has an incentive to pay out any
excess cash in dividends.
These examples show that dividend policy is not always irrelevant when we consider personal
and corporate taxes. To continue the discussion, we go back to the different tax treatment of divi-
dends and capital gains.
6
Under current tax law, if the shareholder in Firm G does not sell the shares for a gain, it will be an unrealized capital
gain, which is not taxed.
example). Research suggests stocks that paid dividends had higher pre-tax returns prior to 1972.
From 1972 to 1977, the same study detected no difference in pre-tax returns.7
In 1985, the lifetime exemption on capital gains was introduced. Recent research found that
investors anticipated this tax break for capital gains and bid up the prices of stocks with low divi-
dend yields. Firms responded by lowering their dividend payouts. This all ended in 1994 when the
federal budget ended the capital gains exemption.8 In 2000, the federal budget lowered the taxable
portion of capital gains from 75 to 50 percent. In November 2005, the government of Canada ini-
tiated changes with the goal of making dividend-paying stocks more attractive relative to income
trusts by increasing the gross-up and the dividend tax credit.9 We suspect that from the viewpoint
of individual investors, higher dividends require larger pre-tax returns.
Another way of measuring the effective tax rates on dividends and capital gains in Canada is to
look at ex-dividend day price drops. We showed earlier that, ignoring taxes, a stock price should
drop by the amount of the dividend when it goes ex dividend. This is because the price drop
offsets what investors lose by waiting to buy the stock until it goes ex dividend. If dividends are
taxed and capital gains are tax free, the price drop should be lower, equal to the after-tax value of
the dividend. However, if gains are taxed too, the price drop needs to be adjusted for the gains tax.
An investor who waits for the stock to go ex dividend buys at a lower price and hence has a larger
capital gain when the stock is sold later.
All this allowed researchers to infer tax rates from ex-dividend day behaviour. One study con-
cludes that marginal investors who set prices are taxed more heavily on dividends than on capital
gains.10 This supports our argument: Individual investors likely look for higher pre-tax returns on
dividend paying stocks.
Flotation Costs
In our example illustrating that dividend policy doesn’t matter, we saw that the firm could sell
some new stock if necessary to pay a dividend. As we mentioned in Chapter 15, selling new stock
can be very expensive. If we include flotation costs in our argument, then we find that the value of
the stock decreases if we sell new stock.
More generally, imagine two firms that are identical in every way except that one pays out a
greater percentage of its cash flow in the form of dividends. Since the other firm plows back more,
its equity grows faster. If these two firms are to remain identical, the one with the higher payout
has to sell some stock periodically to catch up. Since this is expensive, a firm might be inclined to
have a low payout.
Dividend Restrictions
In some cases, a corporation may face restrictions on its ability to pay dividends. For example,
as we discussed in Chapter 7, a common feature of a bond indenture is a covenant prohibiting
dividend payments above some level.
Concept Questions
7
I. G. Morgan, “Dividends and Stock Price Behaviour in Canada,” Journal of Business Administration 12 (Fall 1989).
8
B. Amoako-adu, M. Rashid, and M. Stebbins, “Capital Gains Tax and Equity Values: Empirical Test of Stock Price Re-
action to the Introduction and Reduction of Capital Gains Tax Exemption, Journal of Banking and Finance 16 (1992),
pp. 275–87; F. Adjaoud and D. Zeghal, “Taxation and Dividend Policy in Canada: New Evidence,” FINECO (2nd Se-
mester) 1993, pp. 141–54.
9
We discuss these tax changes in detail in Chapter 2.
10
L. Booth and D. Johnston, “Ex-Dividend Day Behavior.” Their research also showed that interlisted stocks, traded on
exchanges in both the United States and Canada, tended to be priced by U.S. investors and not be affected by Canadian
tax changes. J. Lakonishok and T. Vermaelen, “Tax Reforms and Ex-Dividend Day Behavior,” Journal of Finance, Sep-
tember 1983, pp. 1157–58, gives a competing explanation in terms of tax arbitrage by short-term traders.
Uncertainty Resolution
We have just pointed out that investors with substantial current consumption needs prefer high
current dividends. In another classic treatment, the late Professor Myron Gordon argued that a
high-dividend policy also benefits shareholders because it resolves uncertainty.12
According to Gordon, investors price a security by forecasting and discounting future divi-
dends. Gordon then argues that forecasts of dividends to be received in the distant future have
greater uncertainty than do forecasts of near-term dividends. Because investors dislike uncer-
tainty, the stock price should be low for those companies that pay small dividends now in order
to remit higher dividends later.
Gordon’s argument is essentially a “bird-in-hand” story. A $1 dividend in a shareholder’s
pocket is somehow worth more than that same $1 in a bank account held by the corporation. By
now, you should see the problem with this argument. A shareholder can create a bird in hand very
easily just by selling some stock.
11
Benjamin Graham & David Dodd (2008) Security Analysis: Sixth Edition, Foreword by Warren Buffett, McGraw-Hill
Professional.
12
M. Gordon, The Investment, Financing and Valuation of the Corporation (Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, 1961).
TAX-EXEMPT INVESTORS We have pointed out both the tax advantages and disadvan-
tages of a low-dividend payout. Of course, this discussion is irrelevant to those in zero tax brack-
ets. This group includes some of the largest investors in the economy, such as pension funds,
endowment funds, and trust funds.
There are some legal reasons for large institutions to favour high-dividend yields: First, insti-
tutions such as pension funds and trust funds are often set up to manage money for the benefit
of others. The managers of such institutions have a fiduciary responsibility to invest the money
prudently. It has been considered imprudent in courts of law to buy stock in companies with no
established dividend record.
Second, institutions such as university endowment funds and trust funds are frequently
prohibited from spending any of the principal. Such institutions might, therefore, prefer high-
dividend yield stocks so they have some ability to spend. Like widows and orphans, this group
thus prefers current income. Unlike widows and orphans, in terms of the amount of stock owned,
this group is very large and its market share is expanding rapidly.
Conclusion
Overall, individual investors (for whatever reason) may have a desire for current income and may
thus be willing to pay the dividend tax. In addition, some very large investors such as corporations
and tax-free institutions may have a very strong preference for high-dividend payouts.
Concept Questions
13
For preferred stock, we assume the issuer has elected to pay the refundable withholding tax on preferred dividends.
BMO Capital Markets noted that “aside from the National Bank, none of the other five Canadian
banks have cut their dividend since the Great Depression.”14
Generally, the stock price reacts to the dividend change. The reaction can be attributed to
changes in the amount of future dividends, not necessarily a change in dividend payout pol-
information content effect icy. This signal is called the information content effect of the dividend. The fact that dividend
The market’s reaction to a changes convey information about the firm to the market makes it difficult to interpret the effect
change in corporate dividend
of dividend policy of the firm.
payout.
TA BL E 1 7.1
Largest TSX companies by market capitalization and dividends for April 13, 2012
Rank Company Market cap ($ billion) Dividend Yield (%)
1 Royal Bank of Canada 80.6 4.1
2 Toronto-Dominion Bank 74.2 3.5
3 Bank of Nova Scotia 61.5 4.1
4 Suncor Energy 47.5 1.4
5 Barrick Gold Corp. 41.5 1.4
6 Imperial Oil Ltd. 37.0 1.1
7 Bank of Montreal 36.9 4.9
8 Potash Corp. of Saskatchewan Inc. 36.7 1.3
9 Canadian Natural Resources Ltd. 35.1 1.3
10 Canadian National Railway Co 34.6 1.9
11 GoldCorp Inc. 33.8 1.3
12 BCE Inc. 30.7 5.5
13 Enbridge Inc. 30.2 2.9
14 Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce 30.0 4.8
15 TransCanada Corp. 29.9 4.1
14
National Post, February 2, 2009
To see if you understand the clientele effect, consider the following statement: “In spite of the
theoretical argument that dividend policy is irrelevant or that firms should not pay dividends,
many investors like high dividends. Because of this fact, a firm can boost its share price by having
a higher dividend payout ratio.” True or false?
The answer is false if clienteles exist. As long as enough high-dividend firms satisfy the divi-
dend-loving investors, a firm won’t be able to boost its share price by paying high dividends.
Concept Questions
1. How does the market react to unexpected dividend changes? What does this tell us about
dividends? About dividend policy?
2. What is a dividend clientele? All things considered, would you expect a risky firm with
significant but highly uncertain growth prospects to have a low- or high-dividend payout?
TA BL E 17 .2
In the next section, we discuss a particular dividend policy strategy. In doing so, we emphasize the
real-world features of dividend policy. We also analyze an alternative to cash dividends, a stock
repurchase.
the firm has 50 cents in debt for every $1.50 in value. The firm’s capital structure is thus 1/3 debt
and 2/3 equity.
The first step in implementing a residual dividend policy is to determine the amount of funds
that can be generated without selling new equity. If the firm reinvests the entire $1,000 and pays
no dividend, equity increases by $1,000. To keep the debt/equity ratio at .50, the firm must borrow
an additional $500. The total amount of funds that can be generated without selling new equity is
thus $1,000 + 500 = $1,500.
The second step is to decide whether or not a dividend will be paid. To do this, we compare the
total amount that can be generated without selling new equity ($1,500 in this case) with planned
capital spending. If funds needed exceed funds available, no dividend is paid. In addition, the
firm will have to sell new equity to raise the needed finance or else (more likely) postpone some
planned capital spending.
If funds needed are less than funds generated, a dividend will be paid. The amount of the
dividend is the residual, that is, that portion of the earnings not needed to finance new projects.
For example, suppose we have $900 in planned capital spending. To maintain the firm’s capital
structure, this $900 must be financed 2/3 equity and 1/3 debt. So, the firm actually borrows 1/3
× $900 = $300. The firm spends 2/3 × $900 = $600 of the $1,000 in equity available. There is a
$1,000 - 600 = $400 residual, so the dividend is $400.
In sum, the firm has after-tax earnings of $1,000. Dividends paid are $400. Retained earnings
are $600, and new borrowing totals $300. The firm’s debt/equity ratio is unchanged at .50.
The relationship between physical investment and dividend payout is presented for six differ-
ent levels of investment in Table 17.3 and illustrated in Figure 17.4. The first three rows of the table
can be discussed together, because in each case no dividends are paid.
FIGURE 17.4
TA BL E 1 7.3
In row 1, for example, note that new investment is $3,000. Additional debt of $1,000 and equity
of $2,000 must be raised to keep the debt/equity ratio constant. Since this latter figure is greater
than the $1,000 of earnings, all earnings are retained. Additional stock to be raised is also $1,000.
In this example, since new stock is issued, dividends are not simultaneously paid out.
In rows 2 and 3, investment drops. Additional debt needed goes down as well since it is equal
to 1/3 of investment. Because the amount of new equity needed is still greater than or equal to
$1,000, all earnings are retained and no dividends are paid.
We finally find a situation in row 4 where a dividend is paid. Here, total investment is $1,000.
To keep our debt/equity ratio constant, 1/3 of this investment, or $333, is financed by debt. The
remaining 2/3 or $667, comes from internal funds, implying that the residual is $1,000 - 667 =
$333. The dividend is equal to this $333 residual.
In this case, note that no additional stock is issued. Since the needed investment is even lower
in rows 5 and 6, new debt is reduced further, retained earnings drop, and dividends increase.
Again, no additional stock is issued.
Given our discussion, we expect those firms with many investment opportunities to pay a
small percentage of their earnings as dividends and other firms with fewer opportunities to pay
a high percentage of their earnings as dividends. Young, fast-growing firms commonly employ
a low payout ratio, whereas older, slower-growing firms in more mature industries use a higher
ratio. This pattern is consistent with firms’ practice in the U.S. and Canada.17
We see this pattern somewhat in Table 17.4 where the Bank of Montreal is a slower-growing
firm with a high payout; Canadian Tire is a faster-growing firm with a pattern of low payouts.
Bank of Montreal had a steady payout in most of the years, but the payout increased to 91 percent
on one occasion in 2009. This illustrates that firms will sometimes accept a significantly differ-
ent payout ratio in order to avoid dividend cuts. In the case of Bank of Montreal, the change was
driven by a drop in EPS in 2009 (due to the financial crisis in the U.S.).
TA BL E 17 .4
Dividend Stability
The key point of the residual dividend approach is that dividends are paid only after all profit-
able investment opportunities are exhausted. Of course, a strict residual approach might lead to
a very unstable dividend policy. If investment opportunities in one period are quite high, divi-
dends would be low or zero. Conversely, dividends might be high in the next period if investment
opportunities are considered less promising.
17
Current research shows that in many other countries where shareholders have weaker legal rights, dividends are not
linked to firm growth. Rather, they are seen as a way of prying wealth loose from the hands of controlling shareholders:
R. LaPorta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Schleifer, and R.W. Vishny, “Agency Problems and Dividend Policies Around the
World,” Journal of Finance 2000.
Consider the case of Big Department Stores Inc., a retailer whose annual earnings are forecasted
to be equal from year to year but whose quarterly earnings change throughout the year. They are
low in each year’s first quarter because of the post-Christmas business slump. Although earnings
increase only slightly in the second and third quarters, they advance greatly in the fourth quarter as
a result of the Christmas season. A graph of this firm’s earnings is presented in Figure 17.5.
FIGURE 17.5
667
EPS
333
Time
–333
(quarters)
1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4
Year 1 Year 2 Year 3
The firm can choose between at least two types of dividend policies. First, each quarter’s dividend
can be a fixed fraction of that quarter’s earnings. Here, dividends vary throughout the year. This is
a cyclical dividend policy. Second, each quarter’s dividend can be a fixed fraction of yearly earn-
ings, implying that all dividend payments would be equal. This is a stable dividend policy. These
two types of dividend policies are displayed in Figure 17.6.
FIGURE 17.6
EPS
Cyclical
dividends
Corporate executives generally agree that a stable policy is in the interest of the firm and its share-
holders. Dividend stability complements investor objectives of information content, income,
and reduction in uncertainty. Institutional investors often follow “prudence” tests that restrict
investment in firms that do not pay regular dividends. For all these reasons a stable dividend
policy is common. For example, looking back at Table 17.4, the dividends paid by these large
Canadian firms are much less volatile through time than their earnings.
The dividend policy might also depend on the class of shares. For example, in case of dual class
shares the different classes of shareholders have different voting rights and dividend payments.
TA BL E 17 .5
Source: Adapted from Table 2 of Baker, H.K., Dutta, S., And Saadi, S. (2008), “How Managers Of Financial Versus Non-Financial Firms View Dividends: The
Canadian Evidence”, Global Finance Journal, 19, pp. 171–186.
Table 17.6 is drawn from the same survey, but here the responses address the top five reasons
for Canadian financial firms paying dividends Not surprisingly given the responses in Table 17.5
and our earlier discussion, the highest priority is maintaining a consistent dividend policy. The
next several items are also consistent with our previous analysis. Financial managers are very
concerned about earnings stability and future earnings levels in making dividend decisions, and
they consider the availability of good investment opportunities. Survey respondents also believed
that firm should disclose to investors its reasons for changing the cash dividend.
In contrast to our discussion in the earlier part of this chapter on taxes and flotation costs, the
Canadian. financial managers in this survey did not think that personal taxes paid on dividends
by shareholders are very important.
TA BL E 1 7.6
Source: Adapted from Table 3 and Table 4 of Baker, H.K., Dutta, S., and Saadi, S. (2008), “How Managers of Financial versus Non-Financial Firms View Dividends:
The Canadian Evidence”, Global Finance Journal, 19, pp. 171–186.
Concept Questions
FIGURE 17.7
0.6
% of Firms
Figure 5 of Mitchell, Chris,
Share Repurchases
“Essays on Capital Gains, Dividends
Household Consumption and
Corporate Payout Policy”
0.4
(2012). Electronic Thesis and
Dissertation Repository. Paper
687. ir.lib.uwo.ca/etd/687
Repurchase data covering the
years 1987–2000 provided by 0.2
McNally, William J. and Brian
F. Smith. “Long-Run Returns
Following Open Market Share
Repurchases.” 2007. Journal
of Banking and Finance. Vol. 0.0
31, Issue 3, 703–717. 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
There are 100,000 shares outstanding. The total market value of the equity is $1 million, so the
stock sells for $10 per share. Earnings per share (EPS) were $49,000/100,000 = $.49, and the
price/earnings ratio (P/E) is $10/$.49 = 20.4.
One option the company is considering is a $300,000/100,000 = $3 per share extra cash divi-
dend. Alternatively, the company is thinking of using the money to repurchase $300,000/$10 =
30,000 shares of stock.
If commissions, taxes, and other imperfections are ignored in our example, the shareholders
shouldn’t care which option is chosen. Does this seem surprising? It shouldn’t, really. What is hap-
pening here is that the firm is paying out $300,000 in cash. The new statement of financial position
is represented below.
Market Value Statement of Financial Position
(after paying out excess cash as dividends)
Excess cash $ 0 $ 0 Debt
Other assets 700,000 700,000 Equity
Total $ 700,000 $ 700,000
If the cash is paid out as a dividend, there are still 100,000 shares outstanding, so each is worth $7.
The fact that the per-share value fell from $10 to $7 isn’t a cause for concern. Consider a share-
holder who owns 100 shares. At $10 per share before the dividend, the total value is $1,000.
After the $3 dividend, this same shareholder has 100 shares worth $7 each, for a total of $700,
plus 100 × $3 = $300 in cash, for a combined total of $1,000. This just illustrates what we saw
earlier: A cash dividend doesn’t affect a shareholder’s wealth if there are no imperfections. In this
case, the stock price simply fell by $3 when the stock went ex dividend.
Also, since total earnings and the number of shares outstanding haven’t changed, EPS is still
49 cents. The price/earnings ratio (P/E), however, falls to $7/.49 = 14.3. Why we are looking at
accounting earnings and P/E ratios will be apparent just below.
Alternatively, if the company repurchases 30,000 shares, there will be 70,000 left outstanding.
The statement of financial position looks the same.
Market Value Statement of Financial Position
(after paying out excess cash as stock repurchase)
Excess cash $ 0 $ 0 Debt
Other assets 700,000 700,000 Equity
Total $ 700,000 $ 700,000
The company is worth $700,000 again, so each remaining share is worth $700,000/70,000 = $10
each. Our shareholder with 100 shares is obviously unaffected. For example, if the shareholder
were so inclined, he or she could sell 30 shares and end up with $300 in cash and $700 in stock,
just as if the firm pays the cash dividend. This is another example of a homemade dividend.
In this second case, EPS goes up since total earnings are the same while the number of shares
goes down. The new EPS will be $49,000/70,000 = $.70 per share. However, the important thing
to notice is that the P/E ratio is $10/$.70 = 14.3, just as it was following the dividend.
This example illustrates the important point that, if there are no imperfections, a cash dividend
and a share repurchase are essentially the same thing. This is just another illustration of dividend
policy irrelevance when there are no taxes or other imperfections.
Concept Questions
1. Why might a stock repurchase make more sense than an extra cash dividend?
2. Why don’t all firms use stock repurchases instead of cash dividends?
dividend is to increase the number of shares that each owner holds. Since there are more shares
outstanding, each is simply worth less.
A stock dividend is commonly expressed as a percentage; for example, a 20 percent stock
dividend means that a shareholder receives one new share for every five currently owned (a 20
percent increase). Since every shareholder owns 20 percent more stock, the total number of shares
outstanding rises by 20 percent. As we see in a moment, the result would be that each share of
stock is worth about 20 percent less.
stock split A stock split is essentially the same thing as a stock dividend, except that a split is expressed
An increase in a firm’s shares as a ratio instead of a percentage. When a split is declared, each share is split to create additional
outstanding without any
shares. For example, Coca-Cola stock split two-for-one in 2012 and each old share was split into
change in owner’s equity.
two new shares.
The amount of the stock dividend is transferred from retained earnings to common stock. Since
1000 new shares are issued, the common stock account is increased by $66,000 (1000 shares at
$66 each). Total owners’ equity is unaffected by the stock dividend because no cash has come in
or out, so retained earnings is reduced by the entire $66,000. The net effect of these machinations
is that Peterson’s equity accounts now look like this:
Common stock (11,000 shares outstanding) $276,000
Retained earnings 224,000
Total owners’ equity $500,000
Reverse Splits
reverse split A less frequently encountered financial maneuver is the reverse split. In a one-for-three reverse
Procedure where a firm’s split, each investor exchanges three old shares for one new share. As mentioned previously with
number of shares
reference to stock splits and stock dividends, a case can be made that a reverse split changes noth-
outstanding is reduced.
ing substantial about the company.
Given real-world imperfections, three related reasons are cited for reverse splits. First, trans-
action costs to shareholders may be less after the reverse split. Second, the liquidity and market-
ability of a company’s stock might be improved when its price is raised to the popular trading
range. Third, stocks selling below a certain level are not considered respectable, meaning that
investors underestimate these firms’ earnings, cash flow, growth, and stability. Some financial
analysts argue that a reverse split can achieve instant respectability. As with stock splits, none of
these reasons is particularly compelling, especially the third one.
There are two other reasons for reverse splits. First, stock exchanges have minimum price per
share requirements. A reverse split may bring the stock price up to such a minimum. Second,
companies sometimes perform reverse splits and, at the same time, buy out any shareholders who
end up with less than a certain number of shares. This second tactic can be abusive if used to force
out minority shareholders.
In the aftermath of the tech bubble, a number of technology firms made the decision to under-
take reverse splits. More recently, in 2009, Domtar Corporation, the Montreal-based largest inte-
grated producer of uncoated free sheet paper in North America, underwent a reverse stock split at
a 1-for-12 ratio. Domtar management cited two reasons for undertaking a reverse split—to return
the company’s share price to a level similar to that of other widely owned companies and to attract
a broader range of institutional investors.
Concept Questions
Key Terms
clientele effect (page 502) repurchase (page 508)
date of payment (page 492) residual dividend approach (page 503)
date of record (page 492) reverse split (page 512)
declaration date (page 492) stock dividend (page 510)
distribution (page 491) stock split (page 511)
dividend (page 491) stripped common shares (page 495)
ex-dividend date (page 492) target payout ratio (page 507)
homemade dividends (page 495) trading range (page 512)
information content effect (page 502)
regular cash dividend (page 491)
a. If Okanagan stock currently sells for $30 per share and a 10 percent stock dividend is declared, how many new shares will
be distributed? Show how the equity accounts would change.
b. If Okanagan declared a 25 percent stock dividend, how would the accounts change?
3. Stock Splits (LO3) For the company in Problem 2, show how the equity accounts will change if:
a. Okanagan declares a four-for-one stock split. How many shares are outstanding now?
b. Okanagan declares a one-for-five reverse stock split. How many shares are outstanding now?
4. Stock Splits and Stock Dividends (LO3) Mill Creek Corporation (MCC) currently has 425,000 shares of stock outstanding that
sell for $80 per share. Assuming no market imperfections or tax effects exist, what will the share price be after:
a. MCC has a five-for-three stock split?
b. MCC has a 15 percent stock dividend?
c. MCC has a 42.5 percent stock dividend?
d. MCC has a four-for-seven reverse stock split?
Determine the new number of shares outstanding in parts (a) through (d).
55. Regular Dividends (LO1) The statement of financial position for Knox Corp. is shown here in market value terms. There are
9,000 shares of stock outstanding.
Market Value Statement of Financial Position
Cash $ 43,700 Equity $353,700
Fixed assets 310,000
Total $ 353,700 Total $353,700
The company has declared a dividend of $1.40 per share. The stock goes ex dividend tomorrow. Ignoring any tax effects, what is
the stock selling for today? What will it sell for tomorrow? What will the statement of financial position look like after the
dividends are paid?
6. Share Repurchase (LO4) In the previous problem, suppose Knox has announced it is going to repurchase $12,600 worth of
stock. What effect will this transaction have on the equity of the firm? How many shares will be outstanding? What will the price
per share be after the repurchase? Ignoring tax effects, show how the share repurchase is effectively the same as a cash dividend.
7. Stock Dividends (LO3) The market value statement of financial position for McKinley Manufacturing is shown here. McKinley
has declared a 25 percent stock dividend. The stock goes ex dividend tomorrow (the chronology for a stock dividend is similar to
that for a cash dividend). There are 14,000 shares of stock outstanding. What will the ex-dividend price be?
Market Value Statement of Financial Position
Cash $ 86,000 Debt $145,000
Fixed assets 630,000 Equity 571,000
Total $ 716,000 Total $716,000
8. Stock Dividends (LO3) The company with the common equity accounts shown here has declared a 15 percent stock dividend
when the market value of its stock is $43 per share. What effects on the equity accounts will the distribution of the stock
dividend have?
Common stock ($1 par value) $ 385,000
Capital surplus 846,000
Retained earnings 3,720,000
Total owners’ equity $ 4,951,000
9. Stock Splits (LO3) In the previous problem, suppose the company instead decides on a four-for-one stock split. The firm’s 75-
cent per share cash dividend on the new (post-split) shares represents an increase of 10 percent over last year’s dividend on the
presplit stock. What effect does this have on the equity accounts? What was last year’s dividend per share?
10. Residual Dividend Policy (LO2) Crawford Inc., a litter recycling company, uses a residual dividend policy. A debt-equity ratio
of 1.0 is considered optimal. Earnings for the period just ended were $1,400, and a dividend of $420 was declared. How much in
new debt was borrowed? What were total capital outlays?
11. Residual Dividend Policy (LO2) Rutland Corporation has declared an annual dividend of $0.50 per share. For the year just
ended, earnings were $8 per share.
a. What is Rutland’s payout ratio?
b. Suppose Rutland has seven million shares outstanding. Borrowing for the coming year is planned at $14 million. What are
planned investment outlays assuming a residual dividend policy? What target capital structure is implicit in these
calculations?
12. Residual Dividend Policy (LO2) Summerland Corporation follows a strict residual dividend policy. Its debt-equity ratio is 1.5.
a. If earnings for the year are $145,000, what is the maximum amount of capital spending possible with no new equity?
b. If planned investment outlays for the coming year are $790,000, will Summerland pay a dividend? If so, how much?
c. Does Summerland maintain a constant dividend payout? Why or why not?
13. Residual Dividend Policy (LO2) Penticton Rock (PR) Inc. predicts that earnings in the coming year will be $54 million. There
are 19 million shares, and PR maintains a debt-equity ratio of 1.2.
a. Calculate the maximum investment funds available without issuing new equity and the increase in borrowing that goes
along with it.
b. Suppose the firm uses a residual dividend policy. Planned capital expenditures total $74 million. Based on this information,
what will the dividend per share be?
c. In part (b), how much borrowing will take place? What is the addition to retained earnings?
d. Suppose PR plans no capital outlays for the coming year. What will the dividend be under a residual policy? What will new
borrowing be?
Intermediate 14. Homemade Dividends (LO2) You own 1000 shares of stock in Armstrong Corporation. You will receive a $1.85 per share
(Questions dividend in one year. In two years, Armstrong will pay a liquidating dividend of $58 per share. The required return on
14–16)
Armstrong stock is 15 percent. What is the current share price of your stock (ignoring taxes)? If you would rather have equal
dividends in each of the next two years, show how you can accomplish this by creating homemade dividends. Hint: Dividends
will be in the form of an annuity.
15. Homemade Dividends (LO2) In the previous problem, suppose you want only $750 total in dividends the first year. What will
your homemade dividend be in two years?
16. Stock Repurchase (LO4) Salmon Arm Corporation is evaluating an extra dividend versus a share repurchase. In either case,
$11,000 would be spent. Current earnings are $1.40 per share, and the stock currently sells for $58 per share. There are
2,000 shares outstanding. Ignore taxes and other imperfections in answering the first two questions.
a. Evaluate the two alternatives in terms of the effect on the price per share of the stock and shareholder wealth.
b. What will be the effect on Salmon Arm’s EPS and PE ratio under the two different scenarios?
c. In the real world, which of these actions would you recommend? Why?
Challenge 17. Expected Return, Dividends, and Taxes (LO2) The Sicamous Company and the Revelstoke Company are two firms whose
(Questions business risk is the same but that have different dividend policies. Sicamous pays no dividend, whereas Revelstoke has an
17–20)
expected dividend yield of 4 percent. Suppose the capital gains tax rate is zero, whereas the income tax rate is 35 percent.
Sicamous has an expected earnings growth rate of 15 percent annually, and its stock price is expected to grow at this same rate. If
the after-tax expected returns on the two stocks are equal (because they are in the same risk class), what is the pre-tax required
return on Revelstoke’s stock?
18. Dividends and Taxes (LO2) As discussed in the text, in the absence of market imperfections and tax effects, we would expect
the share price to decline by the amount of the dividend payment when the stock goes ex dividend. Once we consider the role of
taxes, however, this is not necessarily true. One model has been proposed that incorporates tax effects into determining the ex-
dividend price:19
(P0 - PX)/D = (1 - TP)/(1 - TG)
where P0 is the price just before the stock goes ex, PX is the ex-dividend share price, D is the amount of the dividend per share, TP
is the relevant marginal personal tax rate on dividends, and TG is the effective marginal tax rate on capital gains.
a. If TP = TG = 0, how much will the share price fall when the stock goes ex?
b. If TP = 15 percent and TG = 0, how much will the share price fall?
c. If TP = 15 percent and TG = 30 percent, how much will the share price fall?
d. Suppose the only owners of stock are corporations. Recall that corporations get at least a 100 percent exemption from
taxation on the dividend income they receive, but they do not get such an exemption on capital gains. If the corporation’s
income and capital gains tax rates are both 35 percent, what does this model predict the ex-dividend share price will be?
e. What does this problem tell you about real-world tax considerations and the dividend policy of the firm?
19
N. Elton and M. Gruber, “Marginal Stockholder Tax Rates and the Clientele Effect,” Review of Economics and Statis-
tics 52 (February 1970).
19. Dividends versus Reinvestment (LO2) Nelson Business Machine Co. (NBM) has $3 million of extra cash after taxes have been
paid. NBM has two choices to make use of this cash. One alternative is to invest the cash in financial assets. The resulting
investment income will be paid out as a special dividend at the end of three years. In this case, the firm can invest in Treasury
bills yielding 3 percent or a 5 percent preferred stock. CRA regulations allow the company to exclude from taxable income 100
percent of the dividends received from investing in another company’s stock. Another alternative is to pay out the cash now as
dividends. This would allow the shareholders to invest on their own in Treasury bills with the same yield, or in preferred stock.
The corporate tax rate is 40 percent. Assume the investor has a 40 percent personal income tax rate, which is applied to interest
income. The personal dividend tax rate is 20 percent on common stock dividends after applying the dividend tax credit. Should
the cash be paid today or in three years? Which of the two options generates the highest after-tax income for the shareholders?
20. Dividends versus Reinvestment (LO2) After completing its capital spending for the year, Banff Manufacturing has $1,000 extra
cash. Banff ’s managers must choose between investing the cash in Canada bonds that yield 6 percent or paying the cash out to
investors who would invest in the bonds themselves.
a. If the corporate tax rate is 35 percent, what personal tax rate after applying the dividend tax credit would make the invest-
ors equally willing to receive the dividend or to let Banff invest the money?
b. Is the answer to (a) reasonable? Why or why not?
c. Suppose the only investment choice is a preferred stock that yields 9 percent. The corporate dividend exclusion of 100
percent applies. What personal tax rate will make the shareholders indifferent to the outcome of Banff’s dividend decision?
d. Is this a compelling argument for a low dividend-payout ratio? Why or why not?
M IN I CA S E