Thanks to visit codestin.com
Credit goes to www.scribd.com

0% found this document useful (0 votes)
16 views8 pages

Finance Model-Sol-Sht-2

The document discusses stochastic models in finance, particularly focusing on random variables, filtration, and self-financing trading strategies. It presents detailed examples of random variables, their partitions, and the corresponding σ-fields, as well as the value and gain processes in a trading context. The document concludes with the implications of self-financing strategies on the value processes and their adaptations to filtration.

Uploaded by

xiangrong li
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
16 views8 pages

Finance Model-Sol-Sht-2

The document discusses stochastic models in finance, particularly focusing on random variables, filtration, and self-financing trading strategies. It presents detailed examples of random variables, their partitions, and the corresponding σ-fields, as well as the value and gain processes in a trading context. The document concludes with the implications of self-financing strategies on the value processes and their adaptations to filtration.

Uploaded by

xiangrong li
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 8

Stochastic Models in Finance

Solutions to Example Sheet 2


1. The random variable X takes values in {1, 2, 3, 4}.
A1 = {ω ∈ Ω : X(ω) = 1} = {ω1 , ω2 }
A2 = {ω ∈ Ω : X(ω) = 2} = {ω3 , ω4 }
A3 = {ω ∈ Ω : X(ω) = 3} = {ω5 , ω6 }
A4 = {ω ∈ Ω : X(ω) = 4} = {ω7 , ω8 }
{A1 , A2 , A3 , A4 } = P is a partition of Ω. So

F(X) ={φ, Ω, {ω1 , ω2 }, {ω3 , ω4 }, {ω5 , ω6 }, {ω7 , ω8 },


{ω1 , ω2 , ω3 , ω4 }, {ω1 , ω2 , ω5 , ω6 }, {ω1 , ω2 , ω7 , ω8 },
{ω3 , ω4 , ω5 , ω6 }, {ω3 , ω4 , ω7 , ω8 }, {ω5 , ω6 , ω7 , ω8 },
{ω1 , ω2 , ω3 , ω4 , ω5 , ω6 }, {ω1 , ω2 , ω3 , ω4 , ω7 , ω8 },
{ω1 , ω2 , ω5 , ω6 , ω7 , ω8 }, {ω3 , ω4 , ω5 , ω6 , ω7 , ω8 }},

2. Note A1 = {ω ∈ Ω : S(0) = 5} = Ω
So F0 = F(S(0)) = {φ, Ω}.
Note A11 = {ω ∈ Ω : S(0, ω) = 5, S(1, ω) = 6} = {ω1 , ω2 }
A12 = {ω ∈ Ω : S(0, ω) = 5, S(1, ω) = 4} = {ω3 , ω4 }
So F1 = {φ, Ω, {ω1 , ω2 }, {ω3 , ω4 }} and the corresponding partition is
P1 = {{ω1 , ω2 }, {ω3 , ω4 }}
Note
A111 = {ω : S(0, ω) = 5, S(1, ω) = 6, S(2, ω) = 7} = {ω1 }
A112 = {ω : S(0, ω) = 5, S(1, ω) = 6, S(2, ω) = 8} = {ω2 }
A123 = {ω : S(0, ω) = 5, S(1, ω) = 4, S(2, ω) = 6} = {ω3 }
A124 = {ω : S(0, ω) = 5, S(1, ω) = 4, S(2, ω) = 2} = {ω4 }

So
F2 ={φ, Ω, {ω1 }, {ω2 }, {ω3 }, {ω4 }, {ω1 , ω2 },
{ω1 , ω3 }, {ω1 , ω4 }, {ω2 , ω3 }, {ω2 , ω4 }, {ω3 , ω4 },
{ω1 , ω2 , ω3 }, {ω1 , ω2 , ω4 }, {ω1 , ω3 , ω4 }, {ω2 , ω3 , ω4 }}
The corresponding minimal partition contained in this σ−field is

P2 = {{ω1 }, {ω2 }, {ω3 }, {ω4 }}

The filtration {F0 , F1 , F2 }, Ft : t = 0, 1, 2 defined above, is generated by the stochastic


price process S(t, ω).

1
Consider Y (t) = S 2 (t) + S(t). So Y (0) = 30

 42 ω = ω1 , ω2
Y (1, ω) =
20 ω = ω3 , ω4

56 ω = ω1






 72 ω = ω2


Y (2, ω) =
42 ω = ω3








6 ω = ω4

It is obvious that
{ω : Y (0) = 30} = Ω ∈ F0 , and {ω : Y (0) = a} = φ ∈ F0 for any a 6= 30. So Y (0) is
measurable with respect to F0 .
{ω : Y (1) = 42} = {ω1 , ω2 } ∈ F1
{ω : Y (1) = 20} = {ω3 , ω4 } ∈ F1 , {ω : Y (1) = a} = φ ∈ F1 for any a 6= 42, 20.
So Y (1) is measurable with respect to F1
{ω : Y (2) = 56} = {ω1 } ∈ F2
{ω : Y (2) = 72} = {ω2 } ∈ F2
{ω : Y (2) = 42} = {ω3 } ∈ F2
{ω : Y (2) = 6} = {ω4 } ∈ F2 , and {ω : Y (2) = a} = φ ∈ F1 for any a 6= 56, 72, 42, 6.
So Y (2) is measurable with respect to F2
2
Therefore, Y (t) is adapted to filtration {Ft }t=0

3. The value process



 H0 (1)B(0) + H1 (1)S(0), t=0
V (t) =
H0 (t)B(t) + H1 (t)S(t), t ≥ 1.

So
V (0) = H0 (1) + 5H1 (1)
V (1, ω) = H0 (1)(1 + r) + 6H1 (1) ω = ω1 , ω2
V (1, ω) = H0 (1)(1 + r) + 4H1 (1) ω = ω3 , ω4
V (2, ω) = H0 (2)(1 + r)2 + 7H1 (2) ω = ω1
V (2, ω) = H0 (2)(1 + r)2 + 8H1 (2) ω = ω2
V (2, ω) = H0 (2)(1 + r)2 + 6H1 (2) ω = ω3
V (2, ω) = H0 (2)(1 + r)2 + 2H1 (2) ω = ω4

2
Gain process

 rH0 (1) + H1 (1). ω = ω1 , ω2
G(1, ω) =
rH0 (1) − H1 (1), ω = ω3 , ω4

rH (1) + H1 (1) + (r2 + r)H0 (2) + H1 (2), ω = ω1



 0

rH0 (1) + H1 (1) + (r2 + r)H0 (2) + 2H1 (2), ω = ω2
G(2, ω) = 2
 rH0 (1) − H1 (1) + (r2 + r)H0 (2) + 2H1 (2),
 ω = ω3
rH0 (1) − H1 (1) + (r + r)H0 (2) − 2H1 (2), ω = ω4

The discounted value process V ∗ (t) = V (t)/B(t).


So V ∗ (0) = H0 (1) + 5H1 (1)
 6
 H0 (1) +
 H1 (1) , ω = ω1 , ω2
∗ 1+r
V (1, ω) =
 H (1) + 4 H (1) ,

ω = ω3 , ω4
0 1
1+r

 7
 H0 (2) + H (2)
2 1
, ω = ω1
(1 + r)




8



 H0 (2) + (1 + r)2 H1 (2) , ω = ω2


V ∗ (2, ω) =
6
H0 (2) + H1 (2) , ω = ω3


(1 + r)2







 H0 (2) + 2
H1 (2) , ω = ω4

(1 + r)2

The discounted gain process


 1 − 5r
 H1 (1) , ω = ω1 , ω2
1+r


G (1, ω) =
 − 1 + 5r H (1) ,

ω = ω3 , ω4
1
1+r

 1 − 5r 1 − 6r
 H 1 (1) + H (2),
2 1
ω = ω1
1 + r (1 + r)




1 − 5r 2 − 6r



 1 + r H1 (1) + (1 + r)2 H1 (2), ω = ω2


G∗ (2, ω) =
1 + 5r 2 − 4r
− H1 (1) + H1 (2), ω = ω3


(1 + r)2



 1+r

 − 1 + 5r H1 (1) − 2 + 4r H1 (2),


ω = ω4

1+r (1 + r)2

3
4. If H is a self-financing trading strategy, then
V (0) + G(t)

t
X t X
X N
= V (0) + H0 (u)(B(u) − B(u − 1)) + Hn (u)(Sn (u) − Sn (u − 1))
u=1 u=1 n=1

t
X t
X X N
t X t X
X N
= V (0) + H0 (u)B(u) − H0 (u)B(u − 1) + Hn (u)Sn (u) − Hn (u)Sn (u − 1)
u=1 u=1 u=1 n=1 n=1 n=1

t
X t
X
= V (0) + V (u) − V (u − 1)
u=1 u=1

= V (t).

On the other hand, if above holds, then

N
X
V (u − 1) = Hn (u)Sn (u − 1) + H0 (u)B(u − 1), n = 2, 3, . . . , T
n=1

Let t = u − 1, then

N
X
V (t) = H0 (t + 1)B(t) + Hu (t + 1)Sn (t), t = 1, 2, . . . , T − 1
n=1

By definition of self-financing, H is a self-financing strategy.

5. If H is a self-financing strategy, then

N
X
V (t) = H0 (t + 1)B(t) + Hn (t + 1)Sn (t)
n=1

So
V ∗ (t) = V (t)/B(t)
N
X Sn (t)
= H0 (t + 1) + Hn (t + 1)
n=1
B(t)
N
X
= H0 (t) + Hn (t + 1)Sn∗ (t)
n=1

4
Similar to question 4, if H is self-financing, then
t
X t X
X N
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
V (0) + G (t) = V (0) + H0 (u)(B (u) − B (u − 1)) + Hn (u)(S ∗ (u) − S ∗ (u − 1))
u=1 u=1 n=1

t
X N
X
∗ ∗
= V (0) + (H0 (u)B (u) + Hu (u)S ∗ (u))
u=1 n=1
t
X N
X
− (H0 (u)B ∗ (u − 1) + Hn (u)S ∗ (u − 1))
u=1 n=1

t
X t
X
∗ ∗
= V (0) + V (u) − V ∗ (u − 1)
u=1 u=1

= V ∗ (t)

On the other hand, if V ∗ (0) + G∗ (t) = V ∗ (t), from above computations, we know

N
X
∗ ∗
V (u − 1) = H0 (u)B (u − 1) + Hn (u)Sn∗ (u − 1) u = 2, 3, . . . , T,
n=1

i.e.
N
X
V ∗ (t) = H0 (t + 1)B ∗ (t) + Hu (t + 1)Sn∗ (t), t = 1, 2, . . . , T − 1.
n=1

Therefore, H is a self-financing trading strategy.

6. Let F = {B1 , B2 , . . . , Bm } be the partition corresponding to the σ−field F. As X is


measurable with respect to F. So on each Bi , X = xi is a constant. So for ω ∈ Bi

E[XY |F](ω) = E[XY |Bi ]


= E[xi Y |Bi ]
= xi E[Y |Bi ]

But XE[Y |F](ω) = xi E[Y |Bi ] if ω ∈ Bi .


Therefore, E[XY |F] = XE[Y |F].
So if X is measurable with respect to F. Then from proposition 1 in Section 2

E[XY ] = E[E[XY |F]]


= E[XE[Y |F]]

follows.

5
7. (a)⇒(b). Assume X is a martingale with respect to the filtration {Ft }. That is to say

E[Zt+s |Ft ] = Zt for all s, t ≥ 0.

Take s = T − t, then

E[ZT |Ft ] = Zt , t = 0, 1, . . . , T − 1.

(b)⇒(c). E[Zt+1 |Ft ] = Zt follows from (b). But as Zt is measurable with respect to
Ft , so
E[Zt |Ft ] = Zt .

So E[Zt+1 |Ft ] = E[Zt |Ft ], i.e.

E[Zt+1 − Zt |F] = 0.

(c)⇒(a). If s = 0, then E[Zt+s |Ft ] = Zt is obvious. Assume s > 0 and (c) holds.
Then
E[Zt+s |Ft ]
=E[Zt+s − Zt+s−1 + Zt+s−1 − Zt+s−2 + . . . + Zt+1 − Zt + Zt |F]
=E[Zt+s − Zt+s−1 |Ft ] + E[Zt+s−1 − Zt+s−2 |Ft ]
+ . . . + E[Zt+1 − Zt |Ft ] + Zt
=E[E(Zt+s − Zt+s−1 |Ft+s−1 )|Ft ]
+E[E(Zt+s − 1 − Zt+s−2 |Ft+s−2 )|Ft ]
+ . . . + E[Zt+1 − Zt |Ft ] + Zt
=Zt .

8.
(NOTE: The following method is a more tedious method to compute martingale
measure. You can use the decomposition method to decompose the multiperiod
model to single period models, then it is easy to find the martingale measure
that way. I strongly recommend to try the latter method.)
Assume Q is a martingale measure. Then
 
B(t)S(t + s)
EQ Ft = S(t) for t, s ≥ 0 t+s≤2
B(t + s)

First if t = 0, F0 = {φ, Ω}. So EQ (·|F0 ) = EQ . From this we obtain


t = 0, s = 1, 8(Q(ω1 ) + Q(ω2 )) + 4(Q(ω3 ) + Q(ω4 )) = 5(1 + r) (1)
2
t = 0, s = 2, 9Q(ω1 ) + 6Q(ω2 ) + 6Q(ω3 ) + Q(ω4 ) = 5(1 + r) (2)

6
Secondly, if t = 1, F1 = {φ, Ω, {ω1 , ω2 }, {ω3 , ω4 }}, so

Q(ω1 )
P {S(2) = 9|{ω1 , ω2 }} =
Q(ω1 ) + Q(ω1 )

Q(ω2 )
P {S(2) = 6|{ω1 ω2 }} =
Q(ω1 ) + Q(ω2 )

Q(ω3 )
P {S(2) = 6|{ω3 ω4 }} =
Q(ω3 ) + Q(ω4 )

Q(ω4 )
P {S(2) = 3|{ω3 ω4 }} =
Q(ω3 ) + Q(ω4 )

So for ω ∈ {ω1 , ω2 }
   
B(1)S(2) 1 9Q(ω1 ) 6Q(ω2 )
S(1, ω) = EQ F1 (ω) = +
B(2) 1 + r Q(ω1 ) + Q(ω2 ) Q(ω1 ) + Q(ω2 )

From this we obtain

9Q(ω1 ) + 6Q(ω2 ) = 8(1 + r)(Q(ω1 ) + Q(ω2 )) (3)

Similarly for ω = {ω3 , ω4 }


   
B(1)S(2) 1 6Q(ω3 ) + 3Q(ω4 )
S(1, ω) = EQ F1 (ω) =
B(2) 1+r Q(ω3 ) + Q(ω4 )

From this we obtain

6Q(ω3 ) + 3Q(ω4 ) = 4(1 + r)(Q(ω3 ) + Q(ω4 )) (4)

From (3), (4) we can easily obtain


2 + 8r
Q(ω1 ) = Q(ω2 ) (5)
1 − 8r
1 + 4r
Q(ω3 ) = Q(ω4 ) (6)
2 − 4r
Substituting (5) and (6) to (1) we have
24 12
Q(ω2 ) + Q(ω4 ) = 5(1 + r) (7)
1 − 8r 2 − 4r
Substituting (5) and (6) to (2) we obtain

24(1 + r) 12(1 + r)
Q(ω2 ) + Q(ω4 ) = 5(1 + r)2
1 − 8r 2 − 4r

7
which is equivalent to (7).
Substituting (5) and (6) to Q(ω1 ) + Q(ω2 ) + Q(ω3 ) + Q(ω4 ) = 1 we obtain

3 3Q(ω4 )
Q(ω2 ) + =1 (8)
1 − 8r 2 − 4r

(1 + 4r)(1 − 8r)
(7) − (8) × 4 leads to Q(ω2 ) = .
12
Subsequently we have
(1 − 2r)(3 − 5r)
Q(ω4 ) =
6
(1 + 4r)(1 + 5r)
Q(ω1 ) =
6
(1 + 4r)(1 − 2r)
Q(ω3 ) =
12
This Q is a martingale measure. As there are no arbitrage opportunities if and only
if there is a risk neutral probability measure. So in this model, there are no arbitrage
opportunities.

DUAN/NKU

You might also like