Thanks to visit codestin.com
Credit goes to www.scribd.com

0% found this document useful (0 votes)
30 views20 pages

Financialized Management

The document critiques financialized corporate governance, emphasizing the conflicts of interest it creates between corporate managers and various stakeholders. It argues that while aligning managerial compensation with financial metrics aims to benefit shareholders, it can lead to inefficiencies, misconduct, and a lack of accountability, ultimately harming broader societal interests. The author calls for improved governance practices to ensure that individuals in control cannot evade responsibility for harmful actions.

Uploaded by

Daniel Healy
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
30 views20 pages

Financialized Management

The document critiques financialized corporate governance, emphasizing the conflicts of interest it creates between corporate managers and various stakeholders. It argues that while aligning managerial compensation with financial metrics aims to benefit shareholders, it can lead to inefficiencies, misconduct, and a lack of accountability, ultimately harming broader societal interests. The author calls for improved governance practices to ensure that individuals in control cannot evade responsibility for harmful actions.

Uploaded by

Daniel Healy
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 20

A Skeptical View of Financialized Corporate Governance

Anat R. Admati
Graduate School of Business, Stanford University

Forthcoming, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2017

The vast bulk of economic activity today involves business corporations. Corporations are
abstract legal entities that combine legal rights and obligations with a significant degree of
flexibility. The legal separation between corporations and their stakeholders, including
shareholders, has been important to the success of the corporate form in organizing long-term,
large-scale production, while limited liability and the tradability of shares help corporations
acquire funds from a broad set of investors.
However, this legal separation exacerbates conflicts of interest between those who control
corporations and others, including shareholders, creditors, employees, suppliers, customers,
public authorities, and the general public. In large corporations, stakeholders vary enormously
in the information and degree of control they have on corporate actions. Contracts and markets
do not generally create efficient outcomes if markets are not competitive, contracts are
incomplete or costly to enforce, or if corporate actions create negative externalities for those
with little information or control. Laws and regulations can help alleviate these frictions, but
their design and enforcement are also costly and subject to information and control frictions.
In recent decades, much emphasis has been placed on aligning the interests of managers
and shareholders. Managerial compensation typically relies on financial yardsticks such as
profits, stock prices, and return on equity to achieve such alignment. This development has
been part of a broader trend referred to as “financialization,” whereby the financial sector and
financial activities grow in prominence within the economy, and financial markets and
measures increasingly guide economic activity.
Financialized governance may not actually work well for most shareholders. Even when
financialized governance benefits shareholders, significant tradeoffs and inefficiencies can
arise from the conflict between maximizing financialized measures and society’s broader
interest. For example, financialized governance provides incentives for slanted presentations
of accounting data and even outright accounting fraud. Misconduct, fraud or law evasion
directed at other stakeholders such as customers and governments may benefit shareholders,
but they may ultimately have to bear legal expenses, large fines, and loss of reputation.
Financialized incentives can also lead to misallocation through “short-termism” or


I am grateful to Daron Acemoglu, Jon Bendor, Anne Beyer, Steve Callander, Peter Conti-Brown, Lee
Drutman, Gordon Hansen, Martin Hellwig, David Hirshleifer, Peter Koudijs, David Kreps, Signe
Krogstrup, Enrico Moretti, Kjell Nyborg, Saule Omarova, Frank Partnoy, Jeff Pfeffer, Paul Pfleiderer,
Elizabeth Pollman, Heiner Schulz, Jennifer Taub, Timothy Taylor, Amit Seru, Eytan Sheshinski, Sarah
Soule, and Jeff Zwiebel for very helpful discussions and comments, and to Nathan Atkinson, Andrew
Baker,,Zhao Li and Sara Malik for excellent research assistantship. Contact: [email protected]
1
mismanagement of risk, whose upside benefits those controlling corporations while the
downside harms others, including shareholders and the broader economy.
Effective governance requires that those in control are accountable for actions they take.
However, those who control and benefit most from corporations’ success are often able to avoid
accountability. In cases such as corporate fraud or excessive endangerment in which the public
is insufficiently aware of the potential conflicts, governments may fail to design and enforce
the best rules because of the incentives of individuals within governments and their own lack
of accountability.
The important real-world issues around corporate governance do not fit neatly into most
common economic frameworks and models. The history of corporate governance includes a
parade of scandals and crises that have caused significant harm. Although each episode has its
unique elements, fraud, deception or other forms of misconduct by individuals in corporations
and in governments have often played a key role. After each scandal or crisis, the narratives of
most key individuals tend to minimize their own culpability or the possibility that they could
have done more to prevent the harm. Common claims from executives, boards of directors,
auditors, rating agencies, politicians, and regulators include “we just didn’t know,” “we
couldn’t have predicted,” or “it was just a few bad apples.” A recent report commissioned by
the independent directors of Wells Fargo Bank regarding the scandal in which bank employees
misled customers and fraudulently opened accounts for years referred to executives and the
board being “disinclined to view the problem as systemic” despite numerous flags and
opportunities to act (Independent Directors 2017, p. 6).
Economists, as well, may react to corporate scandals and crises with their own version of
“we just didn’t know,” as their models had ruled out certain possibilities. They may interpret
events as benign, arising from exogenous forces out of anybody’s control, or try to fit the
observations into alternative models. However, new models often still ignore highly relevant
issues around incentives, governance, enforcement, and accountability. Economists may
presume that observed reality is unchangeable or efficient under a set of frictions while leaving
out other frictions and ways to address them through changes in governance practices or policy.
Effective governance of institutions in the private and public sectors should make it
impossible for individuals in these institutions to get away with claiming that harm was out of
their control when in reality they had encouraged or enabled harmful misconduct and could
have and should have taken action to prevent it. Better practices and policy would follow.

Financialization and Shareholder Governance

The last few decades have seen an expansion of financial activity and financial markets
driven by a number of factors: increased volatility of exchange rates and interest rates,
globalization, changes in financial regulations, and financial innovations such as securitization
and derivatives (Davis 2011; Krippner 2011).

2
The expansion of financial activity has offered greater risk-sharing opportunities and
enabled innovations, large-scale investments, and economic growth. However, it has also
allowed risk to become hidden and magnified in an opaque and complex system that is rife
with conflicts of interest (Partnoy 2009; Zingales 2015). Whereas economists usually presume
that the size of a sector is efficient if it is determined in markets, recent empirical work argues
that “too much finance” may harm growth, create distortions, and contribute to income
inequality (Cecchetti and Kharroubi 2015; Cournède and Denk 2015; Haan and Sturm 2016).
My focus here is on the interaction of financialization and corporate governance.
Financialized governance starts with the view, especially dominant in the United States and the
United Kingdom, that corporations should focus on benefitting shareholders (Hansmann and
Kraakman 2001). The economics and finance literatures have focused almost exclusively on
the potential conflicts of interest between shareholders and managers (Bebchuk and Weisbach
2010). In recent decades, the main approach to resolve that conflict has been to incent
maximizing “shareholder value” by tying compensation to financial measures such as reported
earnings per share, revenues, stock prices and return on equity.
Prior to the 1970s, only 16 percent of the chief executive officers in S&P 500 companies
had performance-based compensation, but this proportion grew to 26 percent in the 1980s and
47 percent in the 1990s (Bank, Cheffins and Wells 2017). The vast majority of large
corporations today use earnings per share in incentive plans, and most use stock prices and
shareholder returns in their compensation plans (Reda, Schmidt and Glass 2016).
Compensation for managers (as well for as boards) typically includes restricted stocks and
options. In this way, corporations are effectively “managed” by markets and by accounting-
based metrics (Davis 2011).1
The prevalence of stock-based compensation affects the efficacy of corporate governance
arrangements, but understanding the issues around corporate governance more fully requires a
broader context. First, the shareholders of most public corporations today are not individuals
but rather institutional investors such as mutual funds, pension funds, hedge funds, or
endowments, which are usually corporations themselves with their own governance challenges.
Second, corporations may set up and invest in corporate subsidiaries, creating complex
corporate structures. In this environment, stock prices do not measure properly whether
managers actually benefit the majority of their ultimate shareholders. Third, some of the
tradeoffs associated with financialized corporate governance are relevant even in the absence
of shareholder-manager conflict and arise in the context of private corporations as well.

1
An alternative approach to motivating managers to focus on shareholder value relies on the
market for corporate control (Manne 1965). The idea is that firms whose managers do not
maximize shareholder value as measured by the stock price will be targets of hostile takeovers
and the underperforming managers will be replaced. However, boards and managers can find
ways to raise the costs of hostile takeovers such as poison pill provisions, and governments
may block takeover transactions because of political pressures. Most corporate mergers today
are “friendly.”
3
Consider the layered ownership structure of public corporations. Institutional investors
accounted for only 6.1 percent of corporate ownership in the 1950s, and, by 2009, this fraction
grew to 73 percent for the top 1,000 largest US corporations (Gilson and Gordon 2013). Mutual
funds are usually subsidiaries of “management companies,” which are separate corporations
with their own objectives (Bogle 2005). This ownership system creates new agency problems
between corporate managers in the firms along the ownership chains and the investors at the
ends of the chains. Moreover, those who control institutional investors have their own
objectives that may conflict with their clients. The managers of institutional investors often
have little incentives to engage in the governance of portfolio firms even it would benefit
ultimate investors (Taub 2009). Gilson and Gordon (2013) refer to the conflicts between the
interests of funds’ managers and investors as the “agency costs of agency capitalism.”
Even if individuals held corporate shares directly, it is unclear that maximizing
“shareholder value” as currently practiced captures the preferences of most or all shareholders.
First, high-powered financialized incentives may be counterproductive when managers have
multiple tasks (Holmstrom and Milgrom 1991). Second, modern portfolio theory suggests that
investors should diversify their holdings, which means that shareholders often own shares in
multiple firms in the same industry. As shareholders, they may benefit if firms collude, but lack
of competition in product or labor markets harms them as customers or employees and distorts
the economy. Indeed, shareholder unanimity is not assured except under unrealistic
assumptions such as complete markets and perfect competition. Third, the ability to engage in
short selling and trade derivatives can decouple the economic interests of some shareholders
from their voting rights (Barry, Hatfield and Kominers 2013).
An interesting phenomenon in a broader governance context is the proliferation of opaque
shell corporations with no employees or publicly traded shares (Story and Soul 2015).
Individuals and corporations often create them to limit liability, hide activities, or avoid taxes
or other laws. Many jurisdictions, including Delaware (the most popular US state for
incorporation) do not require any information about the shareholders — so-called “beneficial
owners” — of corporations they register. One office building in Delaware is the legal address
of 285,000 separate businesses; Delaware uses revenues from taxes and fees by absentee
corporations to fund a significant part of its budget, and it has fought against federal legislation
that would increase the transparency of corporate ownership (Wayne 2012).

Tradeoffs from Financialized Corporate Governance

Financialized, shareholder-focused governance is appealing in its logic. However, in


addition to the issues already raised above, it introduces tradeoffs and potential distortions that
can have significant impact on the economy. Corporations interact with most of their
stakeholders, other than shareholders, through contracts and markets. Counterparties will be
more willing to engage with corporations, make investments, and produce economic
efficiencies if they trust that corporations would not harm them subsequent to their investments
(Mayer 2013). For example, if lenders cannot trust the legal system to collect loans in a timely
manner or prevent borrowers from exposing them to additional risk once the loan is made, they
4
will refuse to make loans or charge a high rate of interest. Creating trust requires being able to
make credible commitments, but making commitments may be impossible, difficult, or costly.
Dealing with externalities may require government action.
The cost of making and enforcing commitments is ultimately borne by the corporations’
residual claimants and by society as a whole through the government that creates and enforces
the rules. For corporations and their governance to support the economy best, it is important
that contract enforcement be efficient, markets be competitive, and appropriate rules correct
market failures and externalities. Financialized governance aims to focus corporate managers
on benefitting shareholders, but it can result in gaps between what is good for executives,
directors, and some shareholders and what is good for society as a whole.
I will focus on two types of tradeoffs that derive from frictions such as asymmetric
information and the difficulty and cost of effective commitments. First, financialized
governance may lead managers to manipulate disclosures and engage in deception, fraud, or
other misconduct. Second, financialized governance may cause inefficiencies through
misallocation of resources and risk. The culprit in many of the examples appears to be a focus
on financial metrics. The inefficiencies ultimately link to the weak or lacking incentives of
those who are in a position to put in place mechanism to prevent harmful conduct.
Corporate Opacity, Fraud, and Deception
Enforceable contracts and effective governance require reliable and verifiable information.
Extreme information asymmetries can cause markets, contract, laws, and the potential
discipline of reputation concerns to break down. Thus, providing information that enables
markets and contracts to function well, and which allows effective control and accountability,
is a key governance issue.

Managers whose compensation depends on financial targets have incentives to distort


information and to divert time and energy to actions that improve the appearance of meeting
or exceeding short-term financial targets. For example, managers may engage in “managing”
earnings within allowable accounting standards (Teoh, Welch and Wong 1998; Graham,
Harvey and Rajgopal 2005). These activities may become deceptive or fraudulent, as happened
at Tyco, Enron, WorldCom and numerous other institutions. Complex transactions in opaque
derivatives markets and the creation of off-balance-sheet subsidiaries make it difficult to detect
or distinguish financial fraud from other misleading disclosures, as illustrated by Lehman
Brothers’ use of “repo 105” transactions (Eisinger 2017). The complexities of securitization
and derivatives allow banks to manipulate valuations and hide losses (Piskorski, Seru and
Witkin 2015). Opaque off-balance-sheet subsidiaries can make large banking institutions
appear as “black boxes” to investors (Partnoy and Eisinger 2013).
Corporate fraud or misrepresentation can remain hidden for extended periods or even
indefinitely (Zingales 2015), which prevents effective accountability. It is often hard to pin the
responsibility and intent to specific and appropriate individuals. There are also insufficient
incentives or willingness within corporations to uncover fraud or deception, particularly if
executives are able to benefit from such practices. Whistleblowers face hardships, lose jobs
and opportunities, and may be unable to prevail if authorities are not inclined to pursue their
5
claims (Sawyer, Johnson and Holub 2010; Ben-Artzi 2016). Even if it is possible to trace
misconduct to specific individuals, markets may do little to correct the problem. Financial
advisors with record of misconduct continue to find employment (Egan, Matvos and Seru
2017).

The problem extends to auditors, which are supposed to be independent watchdogs, but in
fact have weak incentives to uncover fraud and do not opine on the absence of fraud. Despite
accounting scandals in the early 2000s that led to attempts to improve the quality of audits in
the United States, Ronen (2010, in this journal) describes auditors as “lapdogs” and the
Economist (2014b) calls them “dozy watchdogs.” Four large, for-profit corporations with little
accountability to the public dominate the auditing industry. These companies are opaque
themselves and some, such as KPMG, have been accused of fraud and obstruction of justice
repeatedly in recent years (Eisinger 2017).

Consumer fraud or deception, and other law evasion or misconduct, may actually benefit
shareholders, particularly if the misconduct remains hidden. Of course, if and when problems
come to light, the legal costs, fines and loss of reputation affect the corporation’s success and
are borne by shareholders, employees and possibly others. Recent examples include
Volkswagen’s evasion environmental regulations and the case of Wells Fargo Bank “cross
selling” and improperly opening accounts. New informatoin on corporate prosecutions and
misconduct keeps coming to the surface.2

The costs to society of corporate opacity, fraud, and deception are high. Lack of trust by
shareholders and other investors can increase the funding costs of corporations. Lenders who
fail to recognize loan losses avoid restructuring loans and may continue to lend to insolvent
borrowers rather than making new loans. Lingering debt overhang for households and lenders
can contribute to long-term recessions that harm entire economies, as happened in Japan in the
1980s, in the United States during the housing crisis, and European nations today (Admati and
Hellwig 2013; Mian and Sufi 2015). Ownership chains involving shell corporations can also
enable fraud and make contract enforcement and beneficial renegotiation more difficult, all of
which were evident in the recent mortgage crisis (Dayen 2016).

More subtle and harder to address are corporate strategies involving systematic and harmful
deception that may cause significant social harm to shareholders and consumers. Consider, for
example, tobacco companies that denied the addictiveness and harm from cigarettes for
decades even as they had information inconsistent with the claims they made, or the campaign
by the sugar industry to distort nutrition research and dietary guidelines by diverting attention
away from the harm of sugar consumption.. Akerlof and Shiller (2016) discuss these and other
cases where manipulation and deception by profit-maximizing corporations profit have caused
distortions and harm. The main weapon against such strategies is public education and

2
A new Corporate Prosecution Registry (Garrett and Ashley 2017) at the University of Virginia Law
School collects data on corporate prosecutions. The nonprofit Corporate Research Project collects
information with the purpose of increasing corporate accountability, including “corporate rap sheets”
(at http://corp-research.org/ )
6
awareness of how conflicts of interests can corrupt information sources, including even
supposedly neutral academic research.
Misallocation of Resources and Risk
A related but somewhat different set of tradeoffs from financialized corporate governance
involve inefficiencies from misallocation of resources and risk. First, managers may display
“short-termism” in response to short-term accounting metrics and pass up worthy long-term
investments (Graham, Harvey and Rajgopal 2005). Second, financialized governance can
encourage managers to endanger stakeholders—for example, by compromising product
quality, the health and safety of customers or employees, or even the solvency of the
corporation—particularly if such actions remain hidden and still allow the manager to be
rewarded upfront, before risks materialize. Shareholders may be harmed by being exposed to
excessive risks without compensation or even knowledge of the risk, but sometimes they
benefit from endangering or harming other stakeholders.
Because stock prices reflect assessments of future cash flows, stock-based compensation is
less prone to causing distortions than compensation based on short-term accounting measures.
In theory, if all investors have the same information as managers, their holding periods or
investment horizons do not matter, and neither does the timing of dividends. In that special
case, the stock price reflects the consequences of all corporate action for shareholders. If
managers of public corporations reinvest profits in worthy projects, shareholders who need
immediate cash can sell shares at prices that reflects the investments.

Accordingly, in the standard teaching of basic finance, shareholders agree that managers
should invest in projects that create value for the corporation, and increases in firm value raise
the share price. The conclusions change if managers have different information than investors.
In such cases, managers may make inefficient decisions that harm shareholders (and possibly
others) while inflating stock prices even in the absence of an underlying managers-shareholders
conflict (Narayanan 1985; Stein 1989).

Compensation based on earnings or return on equity targets without accounting for risk
create significant distortions that can harm shareholders (Admati and Hellwig 2013). For
example, it encourages managers to magnify risk by using debt even if doing so harms
shareholders and others. The incentives are particularly strong if managers can reduce taxes for
the corporation or take risk in ways that magnify the upside for shareholders while sharing
downside risk with others.
Managers can also “front load” the upside and reap large bonuses, because return measures
are high at first while potential losses, realized later, fall mainly on shareholders and others
(Bhagat 2017). Those who manage institutional investors such as asset management
companies, pension funds, mutual funds and endowments may also be judged by short-term
return measures and expose the ultimate investors to excessive risk (Bogle 2005; Partnoy
2009). In some cases like public pension funds, banks with insured deposits or institutions
whose creditors are likely to receive support from governments or central banks, a share of the
downside risk ultimately falls on taxpayers.

7
Risk taking in innovation, where those who take the risk bear the downside, is useful and
beneficial if taken properly and responsibly. Indeed, managers fearing for their jobs may be
excessively risk averse and take too little such risk. The problem of excessive risk taking arises
when executives can shift downside risk and endanger others inefficiently. Cases such as
Volkswagen, British Petroleum, or the nuclear industry in Japan illustrate the problem and the
potential harm that can result. Dispersed consumers or the public do not have sufficient
information or ability to bring about safer practices or to prompt action to eliminate products
that turn out to be unsafe (Felcher 2001).

Another example of the harmful consequences of financialized corporate governance that


may lead to lower firm value and collateral harm is excessive use of debt funding by
corporations. Managers acting on behalf of shareholders of indebted corporations make
investment and funding decisions that may not maximize the total value of the corporation. In
particular, they may make excessively risky investments increases indebtedness inefficiently
because shareholders benefit fully from the upside of risk while sharing an increased downside
risk with creditors (or others). At the same time, indebted corporations avoid taking actions
that benefit creditors and the corporation as a whole at shareholders’ expense, such as beneficial
reductions of indebtedness and some worthy investments with insufficient “upside” (Admati,
DeMarzo, Hellwig and Pfleiderer, forthcoming).
Heavy borrowing thus leads to distorted investments and to an increased risk of defaults
and bankruptcies that entail deadweight cost and, for large corporations, can cause collateral
harm to employees, customers, and the community. The problem of excessive and reckless use
of debt is particularly harmful in banking, where passive depositors and short-term creditors
do not provide market discipline, and explicit and implicit guarantees exacerbate the
distortions, essentially feeding a “debt addiction” that characterizes heavy borrowing. Unless
regulations counter the harmful incentives, the result is distorted credit markets, financial
instability, including periodic financial crises, and further governance problems, recklessness,
and distorted competition when institutions are considered “too big to fail.”

Some Policy Proposals


The key to improving corporate governance is to increase transparency, create better
internal and external control and accountability, and address distortions and inefficiencies
through effective laws and regulations. With financialized governance, executives will
obviously seek to maintain market power and prevent entry, and antitrust laws should attempt
to promote competition and entry. I will focus this discussion on addressing the potential
inefficiencies discussed above from opacity, fraud, and excessive endangerment.
One place to start reducing corporate opacity would be to require shell corporations to
reveal the identity of their beneficial owners, and any limits to their liability, so that authorities
and the public can better track chains of ownership. Such laws exist in many jurisdictions but,
surprisingly, not in United States (Caldwell 2016). It also makes sense to consider whether the
privilege of incorporation should be available as easily as it is now. One idea is that

8
incorporations would require a disclosure of purpose, at least in general terms, which would be
revised and examined periodically with possible termination if the corporation is primarily set
for the purpose of increasing opacity and evading laws. Such examinations could also lead to
charges of tax evasion or fraud.

For large corporations, it may be useful to find more un-conflicted sources of information
outside the corporations by providing incentives to independent analysts to expose misconduct,
given the difficulty of relying on whistleblowers and the conflicts of interest of auditors and
rating agencies paid by the corporations. Since producing reliable information is so critical for
effective governance, it may be desirable to delegate some of these functions to government
agencies or to not-for-profit organizations with committed and un-conflicted experts.3 Unless
rating agencies are more accountable to the public, regulations and institutional investors
should avoid relying on their scores (Partnoy 2016).

As abstract entities, corporations cannot go to jail. Extracting fines from corporations does
not prevent corporate fraud and misconduct if shareholder governance is weak. The individuals
who are involved in, encourage or tolerate corporate misconduct or law evasion often benefit
from effective personal impunity, because their personal culpability or intent cannot be
established with sufficient confidence to meet a legal standard. Unless shareholder governance
is effective, executives and board members also rarely lose their jobs.

The ability to deter large corporations from bad behavior is limited by the fact that imposing
the most severe punishments — huge fines, or worse, the revocation of license to conduct
business — would cause significant collateral harm to innocent employees and others (Garrett
2016). Such issues do not arise if we increase accountability for individual executives and
board members. Doing so may require re-examination of the laws and rules defining liability
that would give authorities sufficient tools to pursue individuals in civil and criminal courts,
and to claw back pay. Devoting sufficient resources to investigations of individuals, which tend
to be complex and risky, may also be necessary (Eisinger 2017).

There have been attempts to improve corporate governance and prevent accounting fraud
through laws. However, the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 that came as a response to the Enron
bankruptcy and the numerous accounting scandals around that time did not prevent the massive
fraud and deception by many financial firms that contributed to the housing crisis and to the
near implosion of the financial system in 2008 (Coates and Srinivasan 2014). There is also no
evidence that independent directors have prevented fraud (Avci, Schipani and Seyhun2017).
The 2010 Dodd-Frank Act has done little to address corporate fraud except for attempting to
encourage whistleblowers.

Many deceptive practices fall in a gray area where it is difficult to identify or establish that
they are fraudulent with intent to deceive as defined under law. To prevent corporations from

3
Shifting the responsibility for choosing auditors to private insurance companies (Ronen 2010)
may be helpful but it does not address the distorted incentives of individuals in response to
their own compensation and the lack of personal accountability when responsibility is diffused.
9
hiding safety problems that they are aware of, laws are needed to force corporations to take
strong action to inform consumers about safety issues and to prohibit settlements that
specifically obscure safety violations. Consumer protection laws are useful when it is difficult
for consumers to evaluate products, e.g., in the context of financial services (Campbell 2016).
Educating the public to be more aware of potential conflicts of interest, thus creating savvier
consumers of products and information, including from experts and media, would also help.

To address the problem of corporations transferring risk inefficiently to others and


misallocating resources, it is important that incentives offered to managers create a long-term
focus. Corporations should also have processes to ensure that relevant information about safety
issues is not diffused or lost and reaches executives in positions of control. Measures that
prevent or reduce harm are obviously better for all, including shareholders who would
otherwise deal with fines and the company’s loss of reputation.

Effective laws and regulations are essential when competitive markets and contracts do not
work to create effective commitments or in the presence of externalities. In creating laws and
regulations, the key should be first on prevention of harm if it can be achieved at a reasonable
cost rather than focusing on how to deal with the conduct after the fact. For example, preventing
traffic accidents through appropriate traffic laws such as speed limits and proper infrastructure
is better than relying solely on insurance, fines, prisons, civil litigations and ambulances.
Similarly, it may be significantly more cost efficient and prevent collateral harm to try to detect
and address misconduct, fraud and endangerment early than to deal with consequences such as
nuclear disasters, oil spills, car explosions, or financial crises once they happen. In the case of
children’s products in the United States, for example, safety standards are lax and corporations
often obscure information about unsafe products (Felcher 2001).

Of course, it is important that policymakers choose the least costly ways to achieve prudent
conduct. Yet, some laws are counterproductive and interfere with efficient governance. For
example, tax laws in many jurisdictions favor debt over equity funding. Such laws are distortive
by creating incentives for inefficient indebtedness (Hirshleifer and Teoh 2009; Admati,
DeMarzo, Hellwig and Pfleiderer, forthcoming). This feature of tax codes is particularly
perverse for banks, which already have incentives to choose dangerous debt levels. The
Economist (2015) called tax-free debt “a vast distortion in the world economy [that] is wholly
man-made.” Bankruptcy codes that favor commitments in derivatives and short-term debt (so-
called repos) over other corporate liabilities, and which also exacerbate the conflict of interest
between managers with financialized compensation and society, should be changed (Skeel and
Jackson 2012).

Political Economy and Corporate Governance

By putting in place laws and regulations and by enforcing contracts and rules, governments
play a critical role in affecting corporate governance practices and determining how well
corporations serve society. The determination of the rules in turn, and how they affect different

10
stakeholders, depend on policymakers’ incentives and on the political process (Pagano and
Volpin 2005). Policymakers may help corporations create useful commitments and thus
become more efficient, or instead impose excessive and costly rules on some corporations
while tolerating or even perversely encouraging reckless conduct in other contexts.
To see some of the issues, it is instructive to compare corporate governance and aviation
safety. A key reason for the safety of airplane travel is that lapses in safety are extremely salient
to the public. Authorities design rules that anticipate potential problems and reduce, and they
investigate problems promptly. In addition, the incentives of those in the private aviation
sector, from the airplane manufacturers to the airlines employees to those working in airports
to monitor air traffic do not conflict with the public’s interest in safety. Finally, a key
underlying reason for aviation safety has to do with accountability. In virtually all plane
crashes, it is possible to point to the cause of the crash. Individuals found responsible or
negligent stand to lose jobs or reputation from plane crashes, and they might even get into legal
trouble. Although it takes much technology and collaboration across jurisdictions, safety
prevails in aviation and mistakes rarely recur.
Corporate governance issues are in some cases starkly different. When those in control of
corporations can harm others in abstract or invisible ways such as excessive financial risk or
other subtle endangerment, governments may lack the political will to consider the issues, do
a thorough autopsy when problems arise and invest properly in putting in place effective rules
to prevent the problems from repeating. Governments may enact inefficient, excessive, or
wasteful rules that create or exacerbate distortions in order to serve other political objectives.

Even when corporate governance failures becomes clear, for example in scandals or crises,
it is often hard to trace the harm to specific individuals or policies. The governance and
accountability of government institutions can become a challenge for society. I discuss several
issues that arise at the intersection of political economy and corporate governance: capture, law
enforcement, and companies operating across legal jurisdictions. I then offer the financial
industry as an example in which these issues are particularly stark.
Capture
Laws and regulations will not work well when those charged with setting and implementing
them collaborate with those in the industry even if these collaborations harm the public (Stigler
1971; Acemoglu 2003). The dynamics of capture are often subtle. Corporations employ
lobbyists, consultants, lawyers, public relation firms, and influential, connected individuals to
shape rules and their implementation. Such activities have expanded greatly in recent years
(Drutman 2015). The realities of revolving doors and campaign finance in the United States
have increased the impact of those who can fund politicians (Lessig 2012).
When the issues are complex and government resources are limited, staffers and
policymakers sometimes rely on corporations and their lobbyists to draft rules (Lipton and
Protess 2013). Complex laws and regulations create a bloated ecosystem of experts who find
revolving opportunities in the private and government sector based on knowing the details
(McCarty 2013; Lucca, Seru and Trebbi 2014).

11
The actual workings of capture and the corrosive impact it can have on the effectiveness of
governments are often invisible. If budgets are tight and expertise lies mostly with conflicted
individuals, rules are more likely to become distorted and fail to serve the public interest. The
“thin political markets” that produce the rules do not balance the interests of different
constituents, affecting even basic accounting rules, which are the fundamental building blocks
of effective governance (Ramanna 2015). The mix of genuine confusion and distorted
incentives compound the problems and leads to “intellectual capture” (Johnson and Kwak
2010).
Given the critical importance of appropriate and well-crafted rules, reducing the wage
disparity between policymakers and the private sector would be desirable. Low salaries
encourage the government-to-lobbyist revolving door and may deprive the government of
experts who are more likely to stand up to pressure from the industry and protect the public
interest through effective rules (Drutman 2015).
Corporations fight against rules and their implementation in courts, where outcomes often
depend both on the on the biases and ability of specific judges to understand the complex issues
and the quality of the lawyers making the arguments. The resources of corporations often
overwhelm those that governments are able or willing to devote to the issues.
It does not follow from this discussion of capture that governments should impose no rules
on corporations or, alternatively, that all regulations are useful. Rather, my point is that the
incentives of those who work in government matter, and that it is important that they use their
power properly and be accountable to the public. Governments can fail by intervening too much
or too little, by creating inefficient and excessively complex rules, or by not devoting enough
resources to writing and enforcing rules. Rules should be as cost-beneficial as possible to
address market failures while avoiding waste of taxpayer or corporate resources. Preventing
capture and providing proper incentives for regulators and others involved in policy is itself an
important objective (Carpenter and Moss 2013).
Effectiveness of Enforcement

A related issue is that laws and regulations may fail to achieve their goals if governments
do not enforce them consistently and effectively. As a representative example, consider the
Deutsche Bank whistleblower who contacted the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC)
to report a significant mismarking of derivatives position; this case only received attention after
the media investigated and reported the allegations (Ben-Artzi 2016). The result was a fine of
$55 million, effectively paid by current shareholders, with little if any direct consequences for
those responsible for the fraud. Revolving doors between Deutsche Bank compliance and SEC
enforcement may have played a role in this case.

The US Department of Justice and other regulatory agencies have changed how they handle
corporate crime, particularly fraud, since the late 1990s. The main tool has become settlements
with deferred prosecutions and fines, while indictments of individuals, particularly executives,
have become extremely rare since the cases of Enron and others in the early 2000s. Among the
reasons for the shift is the length and complexity of investigations and trials of individuals, lack

12
of investigative resources, and the loss of some legal tools to pursue individuals (Eisinger
2017). However, large fines do not appear to change corporate culture or act as deterrent
(Garrett 2016).

If lack of resources undermines enforcement, misconduct is even less likely to surface, and
it thus can become more prevalent. For example, the 2010 Dodd-Frank Act expanded the scope
of the Commodities and Futures Trading Commission (CFTC)’s jurisdiction dramatically,
beyond the $34 trillion US futures market to the much larger market in derivatives traded
outside established exchanges, estimated to be as large as $400 trillion in so-called “notional
value.” Yet the agency is severely underfunded, relative to other agencies and given the
enormous size of the markets it oversees. One person at the CFTC oversees the $117 billion
U.S. oil market where wholesale prices for gasoline and heating oil are set (Leising 2017). The
departing head of compliance of CFTC said in March 2017 that the agency is unable to
investigate the “massive amount of misconduct” in derivatives markets (Freifeld 2017). The
effectiveness of banking regulations also depends significantly on the resources and incentives
of regulators (Agrawal, Lucca, Seru and Trebbi2014).

Regulation across Jurisdictions

The political economy of corporations involves competition among jurisdictions. This


competition can happen within countries: as noted, state-level corporate havens such as
Delaware may benefit while harming taxpayers and citizens in other jurisdictions such as the
US federal government. Holding corporations responsible can be even harder in the context of
a global economy. At the international level, Panama, Liberia and Bermuda are popular havens
for many corporations and wealthy individuals (Davis 2011), but the United States and some
other developed nations are among the easiest places to hide wealth (Economist 2016).
Corporations can “shop jurisdictions” and set up opaque corporations or subsidiaries that
allow them to avoid taxes or other laws (OECD 2015). The process of negotiating and
coordinating of international regulation often results in a race to the bottom that lessens the
effectiveness of the regulations that would have otherwise been adopted in at least some
countries. Politicians tend to side with “their” corporations, because corporate voice is more
salient to them than the broader and more passive public whose voice might be missing (Admati
and Hellwig 2013, Chapter 12).

Corporations have also used international trade agreements to challenge actions of


governments. Opaque tribunals of private lawyers, where corporations can sue but
governments cannot sue or appeal on behalf of their citizens, adjudicate disputes between
corporations and national governments, (Economist 2014a).

Corporate Governance in the Financial Sector


Banks and the financial industry provide an extreme illustration of the distortions created
by financialized corporate governance and the shortcomings of laws and regulations. History

13
shows that in the context of banking, governments often lack the political will needed to
address market failures, and the difficulty of commitments, through effective rules. Sovereign
default and other government actions have often caused banking crises (Reinhart and Rogoff
2009).
Today, and even after the crisis of 2007-2009, the result of the combined failure of
corporate governance and policy is a set of overly fragile financial institutions and a highly
interconnected and fragile system that endangers and harms the economy unnecessarily. In
extreme contrast with aviation, where many individuals and institutions collaborate to maintain
safety, most of those within the private and public institutions involved in the financial sector
benefit personally from practices that create excessive endangerment and by concealing this
reality from the public (Admati and Hellwig 2013; Admati 2017).
Economists treat banks as special because of their role in the payment system and their
intermediation function, although loans can — and are — made by other types of institutions.
Because banking has always been fragile and has repeatedly produced cycles of booms, busts
and crisis, a common view is that fragility is inherent to banking and fundamentally
unavoidable.
It is true that banks are prone to liquidity problems: that is, circumstances can arise in which
they have trouble converting illiquid assets to cash quickly at a reasonable price to satisfy
creditors’ demands. These problems can result in panics and runs if depositors and short-term
creditors withdraw their funding. Banks can reduce the likelihood of such problems by
reducing their opacity and indebtedness (for example by using their profits as a source of
funding or issuing more shares and having better disclosures). However, banks have been able
to remain dangerously and inefficiently indebted and to obscure the true exposure to risk of
their shareholders, creditors and taxpayers through opaque disclosures.
When banks were run as partnerships in 19th century England, they commonly funded half
of their loans with equity, and their owners or shareholders had unlimited liability, exposing
their personal wealth to the risk that their bank’s assets would not be sufficient to pay deposits.
A century ago in the United States, bank equity levels were around 20 percent or more and
shareholders often had increased liability. Over the years, banks became limited liability
corporations and some operate within large holding companies engaging in extensive trading
and other activities beyond making loans to individuals and businesses. To prevent disruptions
from liquidity problems and runs, governments have created safety nets such as deposit
insurance and central bank lending. These safety nets can cause weakening and even
breakdown of corporate governance.
What actually makes banks and other financial institutions “special” is their unusual ability
to shift downside risk and costs to others and the fact that normal market forces do not work to
counter the distorted incentives of those who control them. For example, outside banking,
bankruptcy courts prevent shareholders of insolvent corporations from benefitting at the
expense of creditors, for example by “looting” the corporation or gambling for resurrection
inefficiently. By contrast, hidden insolvencies can persist in so-called “zombie banks” if
authorities do not intervene, because depositors and short-term creditors use their ability to

14
withdraw funding, close out their positions, or count on explicit or implicit guarantees to
protect themselves (Akerlof and Romer 1993; Skeel and Jackson 2012).
Financial innovations such as securitization and derivatives, and the creation of complex
structures around the globe have also allowed financial institutions to take risks and increase
their indebtedness while hiding their true financial health from investors and regulators
(Partnoy and Eisinger 2013). Corporate structures are particularly complex and opaque in large
banking institutions (Carmassi and Herring 2014).
Poor risk governance and the distorted incentives of traders, described in many books about
the culture of banking since the 1980s (for example, Partnoy 2009; Das 2010), appear to persist.
The US Senate investigation of the JPMorgan Chase “whale trades” in 2013, which involved
taking on huge positions in thinly traded markets in London leading to losses of over $6 billion,
showed that risk controls in at last some of the largest institutions remain highly problematic
(Norris 2013). However, except in such extreme cases, or after bankruptcies or crises, poor risk
governance in banking is invisible.
Governments can counter the incentives for endangerment in banking, for example, by
insisting that shareholders bear more of the risks they take and by reducing the opacity of the
system through better disclosures and tracking of risk. Bank lobbyists often threaten that such
steps would “harm credit and growth.” In fact, the most costly and harmful outcomes arise
from a combination of too much credit in boom times, overly complex and ineffective
regulations that exacerbate governance and other distortions, and “extend and pretend” policies
that tolerate and support insolvent and dysfunctional banks and other borrowers for too long.
The dynamics of regulatory capture are particularly strong in the financial sector
(Connaughton 2012). US Senator Richard Durbin admitted in a 2009 interview that “banks are
still the most powerful lobby in Capitol Hill and they frankly own the place.”
The regulatory capture problem arises because politicians often view banks and financial
firms as a source of funding for favored projects rather than as a source of risk for the public,
and thus choose to make cut deals that compromise efficiency and stability. Even after the
devastating financial crisis of 2007-2009 and the recession that followed, policymakers failed
to learn key lessons. Implicit guarantees, which perversely encourage and reward recklessness
and are ultimately costly to the public, appear free to politicians. The jargon and technical
issues and the abstract nature of the risk muddle the policy debate and create public confusion
about the issues and the relevant tradeoffs (Admati and Hellwig 2013; Admati 2016, 2017).
Other misconduct such as fraud and deception plague the financial sector, leading to
invisible harm to many and to hundreds of billions in fines in recent years (Zingales 2015). The
largest financial institutions, considered “too big to fail” have outsized power that distorts
competition and the economy, and they are especially inefficient and dangerous, being
effectively above the rules. Fragmented regulatory structures, such as in the United States, and
the ability to play off governments and regulatory agencies, have made financial regulation
particularly challenging to design and enforce. The main problem remains the lack of collective
political will to create a safe and efficient global financial system.

15
Conclusion

Milton Friedman (1970) famously argued that the social responsibility of corporate
managers is to “make as much money as possible while conforming to the basic rules of society,
both those embodied in law and those embodied in ethical custom.” Friedman presumes that
the firms operate in an environment of “open and free competition without deception and
fraud,” and he warns that chief executive officers who “pontificate” about corporate social
responsibility will bring back “the iron fist of government bureaucrats.”
However, “free and open” markets may not become competitive and without deception and
fraud on their own. Rules matter. The limited liability and separate legal status of corporations
has benefits, but it also creates problems of misaligned incentives, and lack of individual
accountability exacerbates these problems. Those who manage firms will respond in
predictable ways to financialized incentives. Private sector mechanisms such as auditors or
rating agencies are unlikely to uncover fraud, or provide reliable information, without law
enforcement and proper regulations and oversight.
The interactions between governments and corporations, even in well-functioning
democracies, can promote efficiency, but they can also be wasteful and exacerbate distortions
that benefit only few. The issue is not the size of governments, but rather conflicts of interests
affecting people in all institutions, and particularly the quality, integrity, and effectiveness of
the institutions that design, implement and enforce the rules.
Distortions from inefficient corporate governance are important determinants of economic
outcomes. To ensure competition and create accountability, brave and well-informed
policymakers --- including brave government bureaucrats --- must erect and implement
effective systems that can counter the incentives of corporate managers to extract rents,
deceive, and mismanage risk. In a democracy, individuals in governments must also be
accountable if they fail to act in the public interest. In reality, inefficient governance may
persist.
The status quo, in which governments too often tolerate or exacerbate corporate governance
distortions rather than alleviate them, is dangerous and harmful. Positive change requires better
understanding of the underlying reasons. Economists can play an important role by studying
these important issues, clarifying the tradeoffs associated with governance mechanisms,
identifying instances where markets and institutions cause harm, and suggesting approaches to
reduce the scope for abuses of power by individuals in all institutions. Increasing transparency,
holding those in control more accountable, and creating and enforcing better laws and
regulations to address corporate fraud and endangerment would be highly beneficial.

References
Acemoglu, Daron. 2003. “Why Not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, Commitment,
and Politics,” Journal of Comparative Economics 31: 620-652.

16
Admati, Anat R. 2016. “The Missed Opportunity and Challenge of Capital Regulation.”
National Institute Economic Review, February, R4-R14. (Related materials linked at
https://www.gsb.stanford.edu/faculty-research/excessive-leverage )
Admati, Anat R. 2017. “It Takes a Village to Maintain a Dangerous Financial System.” in Just
Financial Markets? Finance in a Just Society. Lisa Herzor, ed. Oxford University Press.
Admati, Anat R., Peter M. DeMarzo, Martin F. Hellwig and Paul Pfleiderer. Forthcoming.
“The Leverage Ratchet Effect.” Journal of Finance.
Admati, Anat R. and Martin F. Hellwig. 2013. The Bankers’ New Clothes: What’s Wrong with
Banking and What to Do about It. Princeton, NY: Princeton University Press. (Excerpts and
more materials linked at http://bankersnewclothes.com/ )
Agrawal, Sumit, David Lucca, Amit Seru and Francesco Trebbi. 2014. “Inconsistent
Regulators: Evidence from Banking.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. Q 129 (2): 889-938.
Akerlof, George A. and Paul M. Romer. 1993. “Looting: The Economic Underworld of
Bankruptcy for Profit.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 1-73.
Akerlof, George A. and Robert J. Shiller. 2016. Phishing for Phools: The Economics of
Manipulation and Deception. Princeton University Press.
Avci, Burcu S., Cindy A. Schipani and H. Nejat Seyhun. 2017. “Do Independent Directors
Curb Financial Fraud? The Evidence and Proposals for Further Reform.” Indiana Law
Review. forthcoming.
Bank, Stephen A., Bran R. Cheffins and Harwell Wells. 2017. “Executive Pay: What Worked?”
Journal of Corporation Law, forthcoming.
Barry, Jordan M., John William Hatfield, and Scott Duke Kominers. 2013. “On Derivatives
Markets and Social Welfare: A Theory of Empty Voting and Hidden Ownership.” Virginia
Law Review 99: 1103-1167.
Bebchuk, Lucian A. and Michael S. Weisbach. 2010. “The State of Corporate Governance
Research.” Review of Financial Studies 23(3): 939-961.
Ben-Artzi, Eric. 2016. “We Must Protect Shareholders from Executive Wrongdoing.” August
18.
Bhagat, Sanjai. 2017. Financial Crisis, Corporate Governance, and Bank Capital. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Bogle, John C. 2005. The Battle for the Soul of Capitalism. New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press.
Caldwell, Leslie. 2016. “End the Corporate Shell Games.” Bloomberg View, November 30.
Campbell, John Y. 2016. “Restoring Rational Choice: The Challenge of Consumer Financial
Regulation.” American Economic Review 106(5):1-30.
Carmassi Jacopo and Herring, Richard J. 2014. “Corporate Structures, Transparency and
Resolvability of Global Systemically Important Banks.” Working paper.
Carpenter, Daniel and David Moss, eds. 2013. Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest
Influence and How to Limit It, Cambridge: Cambridge University.
Cecchetti, Stephen G. and Enisse Kharroubi. 2015. “Why Does Financial Sector Growth
Crowd Out Real Economic Growth?” BIS Working Paper 490, February.

17
Coates, John C. 2015. “Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and
Implications.” Yale Law Journal 124: 882-1011.
Coates, John C. and Suraj Srinivasan. 2014, “SOX After Ten Years: A Multidisciplinary
Review,” Accounting Horizons, 28(3): 627–671.
Connaughton, Jeff. 2012. Payoff: Why Wall Street Often Wins. Westport, CT: Prospecta Press.
Cournède, Boris and Oliver Denk. 2015. “Finance and economic growth in OECD and G20
countries.” OECD Economics Department Working Paper 1223.
Das, Satyajit. 2010. Traders, Guns & Money: Knowns and Unknowns in the Dazzling World
of Derivatives, 2nd edition, Harlow et al.: Financial Times Prentice Hall.
Davis, Gerald F. 2011. Managed by the Markets: How Finance Reshaped America. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Dayen, David. 2016. Chain of Title: How Three Ordinary Americans Uncovered Wall Street's
Great Foreclosure Fraud. The New Press.
Drutman, Lee. 2015. The Business of America is Lobbying: How Corporations Became
Politicized and Politics Became More Corporate. New York: Oxford University Press.
Durbin, Dick. 2009. Interview by Bill Moyers for Bill Moyers Journal. May 8.
http://www.pbs.org/moyers/journal/05082009/transcript1.html
The Economist. 2014a. “The Arbitration Game.” October 11.
The Economist. 2014b. “The Dozy Watchdogs.” December 13.
The Economist. 2015. “The Great Distortion.” May 16.
The Economist. 2016. “The Biggest Loophole of All.” February 20.
Egan, Mark, Gregor Matvos and Amit Seru. 2017. “The Market for Financial Adviser
Misconduct,” Working paper.
Eisinger, Jesse. 2017. The Chickenshit Club: The Justice Department and the Failure to
Prosecute White Collar Criminals. Simon and Schuster.
Felcher, Marla. 2001. It’s No Accident: How Corporations Sell Dangerous Baby Products.
Monroe, ME: Common Courage Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1970. “The Social Responsibility of Business is to Increase its Profits.” New
York Times, September 13.
Freifeld, Karen. 2017. “Misconduct rife in derivatives - ex-CFTC enforcement chief,” Reuters.
March 24.
Garrett, Brandon L. 2016. Too Big to Jail: How Prosecutors Compromise with Corporations,
Belknap Press.
Garrett, Brandon L., and Jon Ashley. 2017. Corporate Prosecution Registry.
http://lib.law.virginia.edu/Garrett/corporate-prosecution-registry/about.html
Gilson, Ronald J. and Jeffrey N. Gordon. 2013. “The Agency Costs of Agency Capitalism:
Activist Investors and the Revaluation of Governance Rights.” Columbia Law Review 113:
863-927.

18
Graham, John R., Campbell R. Harvey, and Shiva Rajgopal. 2005. “The Economic
Implications of Corporate Financial Reporting.” Journal of Accounting and Economics
40(1): 3-73.
de Haan, Jacob and Jan Egbert Strum. 2016. “Finance and income inequality: A review and
new evidence.” Working paper, April.
Hansmann, Henry and Reinier Kraakman. 2001. “The End of History for Corporate
Law.” Georgetown Law Journal 89: 439-468.
Hansmann, Henry and Mariana Pargendler. 2014. “The Evolution of Shareholder Voting
Rights: Separation of Ownership and Consumption.” Yale Law Journal 123: 100-165.
Hirshleifer, David and Siew Hong Teoh. 2009. “Systemic risk, coordination failures, and
preparedness externalities Applications to tax and accounting policy.” Journal of Financial
Economic Policy Research 1(2): 128-142.
Holmstrom, Bengt and Paul Milgrom. 1991. “Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive
Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization.
7 Sp: 24-52.
Independent Directors of the Board of Wells Fargo & Company. 2017. Sales Practices
Investigation Report. New York. Independent Directors of Wells Fargo & Company.
Johnson, Simon and James Kwak. 2010. 13 Bankers: The Wall Street Takeover and the Next
Financial Meltdown, New York: Pantheon.
Krippner, Greta R. 2011. Capitalizing on Crisis. Harvard University Press.
Leising, Matthew. 2017. “Hunting for Dirty Deeds in the $34 Trillion U.S. Futures Market: A
market watchdog has more info than it can afford to sort through.” Bloomberg Businessweek.
February 16.
Lessig, Lawrence. 2012. Republic, Lost: How Money Corrupts Congress--and a Plan to Stop
It. New York: Twelve.
Lipton, Eric and Ben Protess. 2013. “Banks’ Lobbyists Help in Drafting Financial Bills.” New
York Times, May 23.
Lucca, David, Amit Seru, and Francesco Trebbi. 2014. “The Revolving Door and Worker
Flows in Banking Regulation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 65, 17-32.
Mayer, Colin. 2013. Firm commitment: Why the corporation is failing us and how to restore
trust in it. OUP Oxford.
Manne, Henry G. 1965. "Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control." Journal of Political
Economy 73(2): 110-120
McCarty, Nolan. 2013. “Complexity, Capacity, and Capture.” In Preventing Regulatory
Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit It, edited by Daniel Carpenter and
David Moss, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 99-123.
Mian, Atif and Amir Sufi. 2015. House of Debt: How They (and You) Caused the Great
Recession, and How We Can Prevent It from Happening Again. University of Chicago Press.
Narayanan, M.P. 1985. “Managerial Incentives for Short-term Results.” Journal of Finance 55:
1469-1484.

19
Norris, Floyd. 2013. “Masked by Gibberish, the Risks Run Amok.” New York Times, March
21.
OECD. 2015. Measuring and Monitoring BEPS [Base erosion and profit shifting] Action 11,
Final Report.
Pagano, Marco and Paolo F. Volpin. 2005. "The Political Economy of Corporate Governance."
American Economic Review. 95(4): 1005-1030
Partnoy, Frank. 2009. Infectious Greed: How Deceit and Risk Corrupted the Financial
Markets. New York: Public Affairs.
Partnoy, Frank. 2016. “What’s (Still) Wrong with Credit Rating Agencies.” Working Paper.
Partnoy, Frank and Jesse Eisinger. 2013. “What’s Inside America’s Big Banks.” Atlantic, Jan-
Feb.
Piskorski, Tomasz, Amit Seru and James Witkin. 2015. “Asset Quality Misrepresentation by
Financial Intermediaries: Evidence from the RMBS Market.” Journal of Finance 70(6):
2635-2678.
Ramanna, Karthik. 2015. Political Standards: Corporate Interest, Ideology, and Leadership in
the Shaping of Accounting Rules for the Market Economy. Chicago University Press.
Reda, James F., David M. Schmidt, and Kimberly A. Glass. 2016. “Study of 2015 Short- and
Long-Term Incentive Design Criteria Among Top 200 S&P 500 Companies.” Working
Paper.
Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2009. This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of
Financial Folly. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Ronen, Joshua. 2010. “Corporate Audits and How to Fix Them.” Journal of Economic
Perspective 24(2): 189-210.
Sawyer, Kim R., Jackie Johnson, and Mark Holub. 2010. “The Necessary Illegitimacy of the
whistleblower.” Business and Professional Ethics Journal 29(1-4):85-107.
Skeel, David A. Jr., and Jackson, Thomas H. 2012. “Transaction Consistency and the New
Finance in Bankruptcy.” Columbia Law Review. 112:152-202.
Stein, Jeremy C. 1989. "Efficient Capital Markets, Inefficient Firms: A Model of Myopic
Corporate Behavior." Quarterly Journal of Economics 104(4): 655-669.
Stigler, George J. 1971. “The Theory of Economic Regulation.” The Bell Journal of Economics
and Management Science 2(1): 3-21.
Story, Louise and Stephanie Soul. 2015. “Towers of Secrecy: Piercing the Shell Companies.”
New York Times. February 7-14 (seven-piece series).
Taub, Jennifer. 2009. “Able but Not Willing: The Failure of Mutual Fund Advisers to Advocate
for Shareholders’ Rights.” The Journal of Corporation Law 34(3): 102-151.
Teoh, Siew Hong, Ivo Welch, and T.J. Wong. 1998. “Earnings management and the
underperformance of seasoned equity offerings.” Journal of Financial Economics 50: 63-99
Wayne, Leslie. 2012. “How Delaware Thrives as a Corporate Tax Haven.” New York Times.
June 20.
Zingales, Luigi. 2015. “Presidential Address: Does Finance Benefit Society?” Journal of
Finance 70(4): 1327-1363.
20

You might also like