Education and Economic Development
Education and Economic Development
INTRODUCTION
spent by most of the developed countries, but produce much lower outcomes.
Education investment is also crucial for the sustained economic growth that low–
income countries are seeking to stimulate, and without which long–term poverty
correlate of income inequality. Education plays a key role in creating human capital.
It has been observed that countries with similar levels of economic development
spend varying amounts on education sector. The size of spending on education also
changes within countries over time. Given this significant variation in expenditure on
education across and within countries, a natural question arises as to what factors help
to explain this difference. This issue is interesting from a public policy perspective
spending increases the human capital of the economy and can lead to direct growth
effects as well as indirect spill over benefits for the rest of the economy (Barro, 1991).
The role of education in economic development is recognised for quite some time in
neoclassical and endogenous growth models as follows. First, education increases the
human capital inherent in the labour force, which increases labour productivity and
1
growth; second, education may lead to increased innovations in the economy; and
lastly, education facilitates the diffusion of such innovations. However, they argue
that it is the quality of education, and not mere enrolments that is crucial in bringing
about development. There is a general consensus in the literature that expansion of the
for economic growth (Krueger and Lindahl, 2001; Greenaway and Haynes, 2003).
The focus of the world economists, particularly those pertaining to the developing
economic growth with human development. Economic growth alone, it is felt, is not
down to the bottom–most sections of the society. Hence, policy–makers in the world
have placed an overriding importance on the provision of basic social services like
education, health and nutrition for all sections of society particularly the poor. In a
wider sense, education may be described as all the activities by which a human group
transmits to its descendants a body of knowledge, skills and a moral code which
Thus, when people are well–educated, they can utilize the knowledge to make
reforms that lead to research and development. Education does not simply mean
bookish knowledge or learning things casually but holds a much deeper meaning.
Education has both intrinsic and instrumental value: it is desirable not only for the
individual but also for the society as a whole (Sen, 1999). In this sense, education
tasks of daily living and further passing on the social, cultural, spiritual and
2
important determinant of individual’s income, health (and health of their children),
and capacity to interact and communicate with others. Inequalities in education thus
may lead to inequalities in other dimensions of well–being. It is owing to this fact that
the main components of its Human Development Index (HDI) which measures the
status of human choices of the countries in the world. Unsurprisingly, the second
In fact, even in meeting the other goals, education plays the central role. For instance,
in the eradication of extreme poverty and hunger, they argue that education empowers
people with the necessary knowledge and skills needed to create or access jobs for
themselves. In this way, they are able to increase production or income to reduce
hunger and malnutrition. Because, it provides knowledge and skills, encourages new
upon as a right, or perceived as the goals of a social contract between the state and its
citizens to enhance the well–being of all individuals in the society, it is evident that
there is a significant role for public intervention. The responsibilities enjoined upon
the state in this regard necessitate expenditure on the provision and delivery of public
that suffer from high levels of poverty, inequality and market imperfections. Public
3
social and individual returns to investment makes the implementation of a financing
framework very difficult. As one progresses from the basic to higher levels of
education, private returns increase faster when compared to social returns. However,
scale economies in the provision of publicly funded school educational system. Such
differences are negligible for developed countries, indicating that possibilities for
reallocation exist as a country moves from the low–income to the high–income group.
across all the countries. A country’s educational sector competes for public resources
with all other sectors and is in competition for resources within various sub–sectors of
education.
exclusively with the availability of public resources and the private participation was
not considered as that much necessary and a good practice. The governments are
having sound budgets and are providing sufficient resources to the educational sector,
at least, up to the elementary and secondary levels. The present day advanced
economies and even the newly industrialized countries of East Asia have developed
their human resources with the strong backing of the public funds. However, the
situation changed considerably with the advent of economic reforms under the so–
counties were opened up in the private sector on a massive scale. It has brought up the
issues of rising costs, cost recovery and financing of education on the forefront of any
discussion related to the education sector. For the past many years, not only in India,
4
but also across the world, public expenditure on higher education is declining at least
in real prices as in relation to state incomes and budgets. The decline in public
sectors which is the most noticeable trend. Compelled by economic reform policies or
conceived of the rationale for reduced role of the state in funding higher education,
most of the countries have inflicted serious cuts in public budgets for higher
prevalent in the developing than that in the developed countries. There is a significant
fall even in the advanced countries such as the United Kingdom, Australia and New
Zealand. But, the higher education sector generally suffers much in the high income
countries. However, the decline has been steep in some countries such as Botswana,
development, along with the governments around the world, the central and state
governments in India have been allocating considerable share of their resources in the
Domestic Product (GDP) and is often the largest (non–defence) sector in the overall
represent an equivalent amount. In India, the policy makers have always emphasised
appropriately, public expenditure can overcome market failures that exacerbate the
However, it is important to recognize the fact that quantity is a first step to ensure
5
quality. In some of the developing countries where more than half of the population
have not been to the classroom, it is important to first get the children enrolled before
ensuring the quality of the educational system. Government of India (GOI) appointed
Majumdar Committee, 1999) which have indicated that in order to provide proper
6 percent of the Gross National Product (GNP) for public expenditure on education by
a target year. Though the targeted expenditure levels have not been reached, a lot of
funds have been spent on education such as, building schools, increasing number of
infrastructure facilities at schools etc in the last sixty years. As a result, we find a
significant increase in educational institutions during the last six decades in India and
Thus, the high estimated rates of return to schooling are often cited as
justification for increased public investment in more and better quality schools. At the
same time, given budgetary constraints, many countries face important trade–off
For example, fiscal austerity programmes often make it necessary for countries to
reduced or reallocated within the overall budget. This is especially true for a transition
economy like India where acute financial constraints force the government to make
critical and sometimes unpopular choices. It means opening your minds up to learn
new things and pursue different options. The two dimensions of educational
6
investment i.e. quantity and quality, depend upon investment by the individual or
investment refers to the investment made by the students and/or their parents on their
significant not only because of their magnitudes, but also because of their nature and
household investment will enable its utilisation. The two are so inter–related and
distinguish Kerala from the rest of India. Kerala is much ahead of other major Indian
the literacy rate of over 90 percent and almost cent percent enrolment and very low
dropout rates at the primary and middle level (Nair, 1981; Tilak, 1994; Dreze and
Sen, 1995). In contrast to the tardy growth of education elsewhere in the country,
social development along with low per capita income is the combined result of many
facets of human life in the state. One of the major aspects of the existing pattern of
which is exemplified from the high rate of literacy for both men and women, and
7
agencies and several progressive and social reform movements have contributed
rather than mass education. Growing concerns on quality education force people to
education along with the resource constraints of government accelerated the problems
growth of unaided and self–financing institutions that had vanished from Kerala about
product rather than a social investment. People with high purchasing power can buy
quality education with high price. Restoration of old educational system, which was
Smith, education is another category of industry, which can be treated like any other
forms of fixed capital. While people with higher purchasing power procure quality
education and thereby invest more fixed capital, people with less purchasing power
procure less quality education and less capital investment. This unequal capital
investment influences returns, which in turn affects the income distribution and
widens income gap of the society. Families may or may not be willing to borrow
money for education, as education is a ‘risky’, and more over, the credit market for
it is mostly felt that the levels of investment of households in education are related to
more on education than poor income households. Households may feel compelled to
8
invest in education, if public efforts, as reflected in the quality of physical and human
circumstances even poor households spend on education out of compulsion. So, the
poorer the quality of infrastructure and other facilities in public schools, ceteris
paribus, the higher could be the level of expenditure of the households on education.
indicators, such as its availability within the habitation, the type of buildings, the
quality and quantity of teachers. The quantity and quality of school facilities could
facilities in public schools are better, families may not feel the need for incurring
investments in education, as they fill the gap in investments caused by cuts in (or
inadequate) public expenditure on education. On the other hand, it is also argued that
households feel enthusiastic and would willingly contribute to education and thus
education are related, either substituting each other or complementing each other. The
economic and social situations of people. The existing empirical literature is focused
9
development and economic growth, b) Public and household expenditure on
There are enough empirical literature which explores various aspects of the link
between the expenditure on education and other dimensions. The first among them
and economic growth. These studies evaluate the relative merits of developed
educational systems and their impact upon the economic development. A large body
of cross country studies concludes that the public and the private expenditure on
economic growth by using data of 100 countries with various levels of economic
development. The results show that the growth is positively related to the average
year of school attainment of males at the secondary and higher education level. The
study adds that workers with high educational background would be complementary
with new technologies which can diffuse the technology. The study also concludes
that both quality and quantity are important while quality is more important to
economic growth.
Pitchett (2001) studied about the mixed result of human capital achievement in
increasing the rate of growth of output per–worker. The study found that the
10
development impact of education varied widely across the countries for possible
reasons such as institutional governance, environment, overall supply and demand for
labour and the educational quality. He concludes that the extent and mix of this
phenomenon vary from country to country in explaining the actual economic impact
capita GDP in Australia over the period between 1969 and 2003. They found that the
further schooling while the net outcomes were positively influenced by economic
growth. The result shows that 13.7 percent of the annual growth in real GDP per
capita is because of the quality of the labour force. The study concludes that
secondary and higher education with a proper mix of vocational education are the
`3.7 during the study period. The result suggests that the magnitude of additional
has declined during the period under consideration. The study has also revealed that
income.
James (2008) studied the contribution of age structure to the change in the
economic growth in India. The study has found that, there is a clear, positive and
significant relationship between age structure and economic growth. The study
suggests that the educational achievements and health conditions of the people are far
11
from the desirable position. The study concludes that the government should improve
the health and educational conditions which can reap the real benefits of demographic
the per capita income and poverty reduction in India. Results show that the
Government expenditure on education and health has a large and positive significant
impact on per capita income with substantial reduction in the poverty of the nation.
The study concludes that other development expenditure also have significant positive
effects on growth. However, it is only about one half of the share of spending on
The international and national level studies conclude that education investment
and achievements are necessary for the growth and development of an economy.
Therefore, it is important to examine the Kerala level studies to recognize the status of
education in Kerala. It is empirically proved that people are a type of economic asset
and that increased investment in health, skills and knowledge provide an increase in
their human capital investment, thereby enhancing their earning capacity and income
level, which in turn contribute significantly to the economic liberation of the weaker
life. According to Dreze and Sen (1996), Kerala’s experience powerfully brings out
the dialectical relationship between educational progress and social change: the spread
made an early start down that road, in the nineteenth century, leading to wide–ranging
12
social achievements later. Education elevated the self–esteem of the most oppressed
and is one of the reasons for loosening the rigid social structure and greater civic
parental involvement in local schools. Unlike other States of India, people in Kerala
are more politically conscious and are active in the democratic process indicating the
The birth rate in Kerala shows a rapid decline before the intensification of
family planning programme and the impact of this fall has already begun to be felt in
the growth rate of primary school enrolment (Nair, 1974, 1994). There is no reason
other than the influence of education for better performance in demographic changes
and producing both public and private benefits. The repressed groups and
liberation from caste disabilities since social situation in Kerala was wretched during
the late eighteenth and early nineteenth century (Tharakan, 1984). In short, Kerala
catalyst for all the closely interrelated economic, social, cultural and demographic
Pillai (2008) examined the chain reaction between the human capital
concludes that Kerala had, in the field of social infrastructure, achieved only the quasi
13
capability or q–capability enhancement and she is yet to strive for the true
authorities, including the centre and the state governments from a functional point of
view to develop the educational institutions and their participation. Researchers in this
reduce the gap between private and social returns, so that individual incentives to
invest in education are no longer distorted. One of the main arguments for
between social and private returns to education. When education creates positive
laws, can, in principle, move society closer to efficient outcomes. A large body of
spending on long run real growth on a panel data of 15 countries including India over
the period between 1972 and 1999. They found that the current expenditure is more
14
productive than capital expenditure because of non–optimum level of capital
spending. The study concluded that the expenditure on health and education had a
negative impact on the growth rate mainly by the distorted incentive structure,
added that existing projects rather than new projects are better to enhance the
Development (R and D) spending in the United States of America. He found that the
major proportion of the Government research and development spending crowd out
private spending by raising wages and reduction in the total labour force in this sector.
The study concluded that research and development can be an inventive activity rather
a percent of GNP declined from 4.1 percent to 3.8 percent during the period from
1990 to 1996. The decline in the share of elementary education was seen coupled with
the reduction of per–pupil expenditure especially in low income states. The study
He found that the subsidization helped to create a large reservoir of scientific and
technical personnel. He added that the fee subsidies and other specific subsidies are
very effective but inadequate to meet the needs of poor people. The study concludes
15
Hong et al (2009) investigated the impact of public goods such as education on
the per capita income and poverty reduction in India. The study results show that
Government expenditure on education and health had a large and positive significant
Banerji (2000) investigated the schooling of children in the urban metros such
as Mumbai and Delhi. The study found that the main reason of poor attendance of
slum children is their economic circumstances and the school accessibility problems.
The study yielded the insight that main reason of slum children not being in school
has less to do with their economic circumstances than with the school systems short
comings. The study recommended that the infrastructure and the quality of
in the broad context of the economy, society and polity. They found that the share of
education in the state’s budget has substantially declined. The study concluded that
spend a lot on acquiring education even in rural India (Tilak, 2002). The willingness
range from existing national legislation to the quality of education on offer at state
schools. These factors do vary considerably between member states and even vary
down to the level of individual households. National level estimates based on NAS
also reveal that household expenditure on education in India is sizeable. For instance,
this expenditure constituted 2.5 percent of GNP in 1970-71 (Tilak, 1985). The view,
16
that the government meets the entire expenditure on education and household
until some information was made available on the extent of household expenditure.
From a quick look through the meagre research available on household expenditure
on education, it was clear that the earlier presumptions were wrong (Shah, 1969).
It was found that household expenditure was sizeable in India and Kerala.
Panchamukhi (1965) and Kothari (1966) estimated the total costs of education
included not only public or government costs but also household costs. Majority of
Accordingly, they found that the total costs of education constituted about 6 percent
of GNP in 1959 to 1960. Based on a small sample of students in Baroda, Shah (1969)
estimated that tuition and non–tuition costs incurred by the families on elementary
Pakistan. The study found that there is a joint endogeneity of child labour, child
schooling and child poverty. The study seeks to empirically prove that there is a sharp
tradeoff between child labour and child schooling with a gender bias. The study
recognized the positive role of adult education levels of the household and realized
that the increased public awareness has a positive influence in reducing child labour
hours. The study concludes that inequality and credit–constraints3 may increase the
child labour hours. He recommended that an enrolment subsidy coupled with the mid
day meal programme can encourage the parents to keep their children in school and
out of employment.
Behrman et al (1999) made a pioneering study by using the data from Vietnam
on the role of household income on child schooling. They also studied the
17
intergenerational mobility and equality of opportunity. Their results suggest that the
children of high income households have shown good education results with a minor
degree of gender bias. The study concluded that the policies of progressive school
fees are less meaningful in the sense that they are only about one–third of what
education of the households in Indonesia. They find that the expenditure on female
student is a luxury good4 and it is reduced or eliminated when hardship hits on the
family. The study revealed that the cutback in expenditure on girl child is strictly to
those households which are not able to smooth their consumption expenditure.
Indonesia during the period 1994-1996. The study finds that family wealth is the most
concludes that parent’s recent death has a large effect on a child’s enrolment and there
the human capital of children in Peru. He also tested if there is any possibility of
transmitting poverty across generations via macro economic crisis. He found that the
parents were reluctant to cut back in key human capital investment of their children.
He concluded that the children exposed to the crisis were most likely to combine work
with school and had completed more grades than children unexposed to crisis.
The impact of birth order and family size on the educational attainment of
children in Norway was studied by Black (2005). The study found that there is a
negative correlation between family size and children’s education while the inclusion
of birth order or twin birth as an instrument which affect of family size is negligible.
18
The study concludes that adult earnings, employment and teenage childbearing have
strong bearing for birth order effects with these outcomes particularly among women.
Richard (2009) investigated the factors that influenced the parental spending
on children’s primary education in Malawi. The study found that the level of
household income both in rural and urban areas had positively and significantly
that the elasticity of spending on education of rural households is more sensitive to the
education level of the head of the household, size of the household and caste are
households. Moreover, results suggest that school related variables and government
shishwala village of the Bhiwani district in Haryana is done by Singh (2008). His
study reveals that the relative share of vegetarian food items declines as the size of
holding increases. The results indicated that expenditure on education show a clear
difference between male and female child and it is favourable to the male child.
Kumar (2004) studied the private household cost of medical and paramedical
education in Kerala. He found that the education background of parents and the nature
of the schools had influenced the entry barriers of students to these courses in Kerala.
He also proved that the entry into the medical education is extremely difficult to the
19
Nair (2004) studied the various aspects and dimensions of household cost of
school education in Kerala. He found that the role of private sector in the education
under the aided and unaided management. The total per–student cost varies
considerably between the types of management. He argues that the rise in income
through the remittances and other related developments leads to the rise of unaided
education in Kerala. He found that the parental costs are substantially higher for the
joined students than for others. He argued that the lower income households with
annual income of less than fifty thousand rupees secured only 14 percent of the seats
in professional education. He found that against the mounting private costs, students
financing colleges in Kerala. They found that the reach of self–financing professional
institutions is limited to only five to ten percent of the households in the state. They
the educational system has far reaching long term problems to the whole of Kerala
society.
education across the world. Majority of these studies conclude that the role of
20
Keane (2002) examined the impact of borrowing constraints and financial aid
programmes like guaranteed student loans and tuition subsidies in the college
attendance of the United States of America. He finds that borrowing constraints have
a little effect on the college attendance decisions while tuition subsidies play a modest
role in reducing inequality in schooling and earnings. He concluded that the inequality
enrolment.
and the cyclicality of college enrolment in the United States of America. He found
that the liquidity constraints coupled with business cycles and its impact upon the
college enrolment depend on various factors like demographics, opportunity cost and
education in India. He found that, confronted with declining public budgets for
education on the one hand, developing countries like India have been examining
alternative methods of financing higher education. The study concluded that student
loans had made little contribution to the efficiency and equity of higher education in
India.
financing higher education in India. He found that all the methods of financing have
various problems and benefits in the wake of privatisation. The study concluded that a
proper mix of public and private sources will be beneficial for the development of
education in India.
21
Chattopadhaya (2007) made a comprehensive study on the modes and
loans5, graduate tax, education vouchers, self financing market determined courses,
reduction in the peer student cost and tax financing are the main alternative routes to
Tilak (2008) analyzed the political economy of external aid for education in
India. According to him, the effects of external assistance are very serious and have
dangerous long term effects on the development of education and on the society at
large. He argues that if the country goes for external aid to launch an umbrella of
programmes it may be effective in a short term basis only to fill the resource gap.
Over the last two decades there is an outpouring of empirical work exploring
the impact of ‘human capital’–a concept of worker quality and skills generally
measured by formal education, on the level and growth of productivity. Returns from
education are the rewards for investing in education. This reward can be in the form
of earnings and other social returns like honour, status, accommodating attitude etc.
Adam Smith himself, only recently the implications of the approach have been spelled
out by Mincer (1958) and Becker and Tomes (1979,1986) in the now famous human
capital approach. Since then number of studies have estimated earnings functions
(Mincer, 1974; Bhagwati 1975; Psacharopoulos, 1977; Tilak, 1987; Currie, 1995;
Card, 1999). Social disadvantages in education, experienced earlier in life, also have a
22
Blundell, Dearden, Goodman and Reed (2000) have classified returns from
investment in higher education into three main categories: a) Private financial return
improvements in individual’s welfare that are not a part of measured earnings (e.g,
easy access to highly paid jobs, better working environment and so on) and c) Social
individuals of the society. It is over and above private returns from education. It
Returns from education generally vary with the level of education. Empirical
analysis of returns from education has shown mixed results. Psacharopoulos (1994)
summarized the patterns of rate of return from education prevailing throughout the
world as: a) rate of return from education diminishes with the levels of education, i.e.
primary schooling has more returns than those of secondary schooling and the
secondary education gives more returns than even higher education, b) The returns
from education are higher in the private sector than that of public sector. The
private sector and fixed and rigid pay structure in the public sector, c) The pattern of
returns from education remains almost stable as far as the developed countries are
considered and d) Female’s private returns from education are higher than their male
counterparts. The rates of return from education in developing countries are higher
countries support a positive relationship between the two. The positive and significant
continue their studies beyond the compulsory level of education. More educated
23
workers get, on an average more returns than their less educated counterparts. They
can perform a wider range of tasks and they can easily be trained in new skills.
Educated workers get higher wages, more respect and dignity, stable and sustained
employment and higher horizontal and vertical mobility. So, education as a measure
of human capital accumulation plays an important role in one’s wages and earnings
differentials. Kruger and Summers (1988) have rigorously analyzed the wage
differentials between private and public sectors in the industrial world and found that
investment on the nations, firms and households. They have found that educational
investment is highly positive and it can provide monetary and non–monetary returns
and thereby develop the nation and equip its people with a good standard of living.
household data of Venezuela and Guatemala. He found that the overall private return
in Guatemala is over and above 15 percent while the rate of return is high to the male
workers in private sector. The study added that it is due to the high level of literacy
while primary education had shown high rate of return in the country.
impact of education on the determination of income. The study proved that there is a
clear influence of education on household income. They concluded that the major
depreciation rates, family size, formal post school training, effect of mobility and
residual variables.
24
Orazem et al (1995) examined the impact of transition to a market economy on
the structure of wages and employment during the period from 1987 to 1991 on
Slovenian workers. According to them, the employment and real wages fell
dramatically over the period, while the losses were the highest for the least skilled
employees. The study concluded that women workers gained more when compared to
the men primarily because women occupied safe sectors which was unaffected by
Angrist (1995) analyzed the economic returns from schooling in the West Bank
and Gaza Strip. He found that the wage differences between the schooling groups fell
by over one and half percent mainly because of the large increase in the size of the
educated labour force in the area. The study recommended that low economic return
especially in a developing economy even with a low rate of social return from
education.
Hameresh (1998) examined the determining forces in the decision to work and
leisure of a person in the United States. The study found that the tradeoff between the
work and leisure is based on time budgets, economic and non–economic incentives at
the time of work and leisure are the major determinants of decision making in USA.
household income was studied by Jolliffee (2002). He found that the maximum level
determining the total household income. The study concluded that the schooling
distribution across the male and female members may also influence the long term
25
Holmund et al (2006) estimated the impact of the gap years between the high
data. They found that the postponement of higher education is associated with a
persistent and non–trivial earnings penalty. The main source of the persistent penalty
experience appeared to be the loss of work experience after studies. The study added
that the postponement of higher education reduces the present value of life time
earnings by nearly one half of one year’s peak earnings in the economy.
Unni (2002) examined the nature of education and the earnings among the
ethnic groups in rural India. She found that the households whose major source of
income came from salaried jobs had on an average the highest household incomes in
all ethnic groups. The results showed that across various ethnic groups, the scheduled
castes, scheduled tribes and Muslims were the groups which were having the lowest
income. The Christian households had the highest mean years of education with least
gender difference while the Hindu households had invested the most in education.
Tilak (1981) analysed the education and return to education and discrimination
in the labour market in the West Godawari district of Andhra Pradesh. He found that
there is high rate of return to education to the backward castes than non–backward
castes purely on economic grounds in spite of the wage discrimination against them.
The high level of initial investment leads to a low rate of returns mainly because of
cultural factors.
city. He found that the shape of supply and demand for human capital is determined
position of households and availability of non–human capital. He pointed out that the
26
schooling and parental backgrounds together determine the labour market position of
Warangal city. The study revealed that household savings are positively related with
the educational attainment of the head of the household and it is systematic and
statistically significant. The study concludes that both the marginal propensity to
consume and average propensity to consume have increased for scheduled caste and
Husain (2005) examined the demand for primary education to the Muslim slum
dwellers in Kolkata. He found that the boys are satisfied with primary education and
the perceived returns from education are different for Muslims and non–Muslims. The
study concluded that majority of the boys and girls did not reach at higher level of
education. He recommended that as the state spending towards slum education are
preference of women in Thrissur district of Kerala. The results show that the
residential and marital status, presence of relatives, mother’s employment status and
family income are the statistically significant variables in determining the female
labour force participation. The study concludes that marital status and family income
on a sample of 100 entrepreneurs in the Ernakulum district of Kerala. The study found
that in general, the entrepreneurs with small business units are not highly educated.
The results suggest that entrepreneurship was the second or third corner in the case of
27
majority of samples. The study concluded that the success more or less depends on
Education has various types of returns. It varies from social returns to private
non–financial return from education. This section evaluates the empirical studies
Muney (2005) tested the causal impact of education on health in USA. The
study proved that the additional year of education lowers the probability of dying in
the next 10 years by approximately 1 to 6 percentage points. The study concluded that
education can increase life expectancy which implies that returns from education
the generation. The study found that an increase in the schooling of women would not
have beneficial effects on the schooling of their children. The results suggest that
educated mothers will spend more time in the labour market and hence less time is
spent with their children. But, other outcomes like children’s health may positively be
influenced by them. The study concluded that these results may not be applicable to
the rural India. The study has also added that elimination of endowment effects and
the husband schooling reduce the impact of woman schooling on their children.
and the development of social and political institutions based on South African time
series data. They found that human capital matters for growth through its quality
concluded that human capital does not stand alone as either the level of economic
28
development matters or distributional conflicts influence the human capital
investment decisions. The social, human and political capital as well as economic
data and found that the education coupled with experience and skills can generate
interaction, independence and occupational prestige. The study reveals that education
reduces the chances of the unemployed, and it improves the position in labour and
marriage market. They concluded that skills learned in school could also lead to better
inversely related to both maternal education and female labour force participation in
India. Disaggregated analysis showed that female labour force participation had no
impact on child mortality among females with fewer than seven years of education.
The study concluded that the relative impact of maternal education on child mortality
the fertility in Andhrapradesh and Uttarpradesh. They found that female literacy
reduced the birthrates of these states while the magnitude of the reduction is
comparatively small. The study concluded that female literacy coupled with other
provision of health and family planning can increase the effectiveness of female
literacy in these states. Fourth strand of literature focuses on the various problems of
29
These studies generally concluded that the problems are inevitable in the course of
development and that they can be solved by a proper plan and action by public and
private authorities.
education leads to greater income equality, which, in turn is likely to favour higher
rates of growth. As education becomes more broadly based, low–income people are
better able to seek out economic opportunities. Empirical researches on education and
poverty, parental education and income, parental attitudes and neighbourhood factors.
There is by now a sizable body of evidence (Hanushek et al, 2005) that educational
The impact of mother’s education seems to be considerably stronger than that of the
chances of schooling. Girls from the Muslim and scheduled caste/ scheduled tribe
families have lower probability of entering school, higher chances of dropout and
lower grade completion levels, compared to those from the Hindu general caste
families. Social disadvantage also matters for the phase of higher education, where it
30
is evident that educational inequalities linked to family background tend to persist and
university attendance has shown that people from lower income backgrounds have
significantly lower participation rates (Raju, 1991). The other feature of higher
education and its connection to social disadvantage is that people from poorer
lower economic and social benefits. This includes a lower likelihood of studying at
Services (GATS) for the higher education system of India. They found that the
absence of pressure groups in third world countries and late participation in the
discussions and early opening of markets will have an adverse impact on India’s
higher education sector. The study concluded that the early opening of sectors other
than education will have a long term negative effect on Indian economy.
context of globalization and privatisation in Asia. The study reveals that the Asian
countries can address the issue of poverty and development through higher education
reforms. It concludes that the high inequalities in income and literacy disparity can be
system in Pakistan. He found that the neoliberal policies of the World Bank can help
the system only if there is an active regulation and financial intervention by the state.
31
Upadhaya (2007) explored the extent of wastage in Indian higher education
system. He found that the inefficient and ineffective subsidy system, scarcity of
of women education are the major causes of the wastages in the Indian higher
education system. The study concluded that there are supply and demand side
education in India. He found that the market logic may seriously compromise the
value and quality of higher education and this weakens the ability to build an
inclusive society. He recommended that the private participation may be helpful with
the objectives of expansion and excellence for the Indian education system.
Tilak (2001a) examined the status of higher education in Kerala. The study
suggested that it is due to the neglect of higher education system that Kerala had
lagged behind in the economic performance compared to other states of India. The
study concluded that improvement in the quantity and quality of higher education may
Another area where there is recent empirical work on the various kinds of
disparities in the education systems of the world includes India and Kerala. The
disparities are found in the areas of geography, level of education, quantity and
long run economic growth. He found that gender inequality in education may
negatively affect the economic growth by lowering the average level of human capital
32
via the low investment on education and high population growth. The study
concluded that there is a difference of per capita income between 0.4 to 0.9
percentage points in the East Asia, Sub–Saharan Africa, South Asia and Middle East.
human and physical capital based on the data of countries. The results showed that the
capital. In advanced countries the return from human and physical capital tends to be
equated at the margin. He concluded that data reaffirm the validity of human capital
various types of tuition subsidies. The results show that each type of subsidies has
various types of merits and demerits. He found that the tuition subsidies are effective
with a marginal increase in the schooling of lower income population. The study
concluded that education subsidies in general and tuition subsidies in particular can
education in India. The study suggested that there are differential enrolment rates for
boys and girls. The study concludes that there is a clear gender bias against the female
children in India. However, the gender bias varies according to the nature of the
households. She has also found that only person based rather than household based
data can accurately capture the full extent of gender bias in India.
India and China. The results show that China developed a strong vocational
educational system compared to India. However, India had improved its position in
terms of quantity and quality. He found that China made considerable progress with
33
its high quality institutions. However both in India and China have to enforce reforms
Pradhan et al (2000) made a detailed study about the rural and urban
disparities of expenditure pattern in India. Evidences indicate that there are wide
disparities in the social and economic indicators in rural and urban India. They find
that, the per capita annual expenditure on education is `101 in rural and `455 in urban
areas of India. The study concludes that the expenditure on education was the lowest
for agriculture wage earners and the highest for the salaried households.
schooling across the states like Andhrapradesh, Kerala, Maharashtra and Tamil Nadu.
The study finds that aided and un–aided schools perform better than government
schools while it is inaccessible to the disadvantaged groups of the society. The study
concluded that the strengthening of aided schools by narrowing the gap between the
privileged group and their disadvantaged poor is an effective means to improve the
women and family structure in Kerala. They came to realize that education and
girls. They also suggested that women have poor say on the property rights,
education, marriage and property decisions. The work concluded that there is a clear
Naidu et al (2007) compared the education sector facilities during the period
from 1970-1971 to 2000-2001 in the districts of Kerala. The results suggested that the
certain backward districts like Malappuram, Idukki, Wayanad and Kasaragode lags
34
behind when compared to other districts. The study concluded that the disparity in
India has a very large number of people below the poverty line. Therefore, a
expenditure. For instance, budgetary allocation for education has steadily increased
However, this falls short of the desired target of six percent of GDP to education as
reiterated by the national education policies of 1986 and 1992. Moreover, given the
resource constraints faced by a developing country like India, there are certain limits
income. Consequently, late 1980s saw cut backs in expenditure on social services due
to fiscal stringency. This was further accentuated with the introduction of new
economic policy in 1991 and the government has been encouraging participation of
private agents in sectors that hitherto have been public monopolies. However, there is
no in–depth study regarding the impact of economic reforms on the education sector
particularly education financing in India. The latest trends and pattern of government
examine the trend and pattern of expenditure on education in India in the context of
economic reforms. Majority of the people lives in the rural areas in India. But, there
are no serious studies regarding the nature of rural and urban differences of household
35
expenditure on education in India. The enrolment and other educational indicators are
biased against the rural areas in India. Further, it is important to examine the role of
education in India.
Kerala is one of the educationally developed states in India and the social
developments of the state are comparable to the developed countries of the world. The
present study, hence, selected Kerala as the region for a focused study. This is mainly
because of its unique educational features when compared to the other states in India.
It is well known that school education and literacy rate are well developed in the state
when compared to the other states in India. However, the quality of education is low
of revised education loan scheme (commenced from the financial year 2001-02) and
the other hand, normative specifications and personal financing decisions are
determining the factors that influence expenditure on education by the state as well as
the households is not only informative but also essential to understand the process that
36
government lacks adequate resources to finance education and hence households have
to necessarily finance their education at least partly, b) the belief that household
expenditure, such as fees would improve efficiency in the system, by making the
children more serious with studies and c) the necessity to fully exploit the ability and
The present study is primarily concerned with the question: that is, why do
households invest in education in India and Kerala? In other words, which are the
anticipate economic and non–economic benefits from education. If the income of the
household is low, effective demand for education can be low and there can also be
that public expenditure on education has a crucial role in determining the household
expenditure on education in rural India. The link between the macro economy and the
studies using more recent data and the advanced techniques are required for making
any meaningful conclusion. Despite the growing awareness of mass emancipation and
regeneration through the process of education in Kerala, little attention has been paid
educational attainment and social development. The present study is a modest attempt
to fill this lacuna. The in–depth studies with regard to household expenditure on
37
education are scanty both in India and Kerala. The studies regarding household
expenditure on education, its determinants and financial return are meager in all
education are concentrating on the involvement of public and other private agencies
and their participation in education. In the context of these problems the study moves
and Kerala.
2. To compare the rural and urban household expenditure on education in India and
Kerala.
Kerala.
The study is both theoretical and empirical in nature. The research emphasizes
the fact that, in view of the differences in the socio–economic background of different
regions, specific studies are necessary to understand the intricacies in government and
developments and expenditure on education, the present study has used the sources
38
(UNESCO) data Series. The data for financing education was obtained from
Plan documents, Planning Commission and state government budget documents are
the other major sources of the study for analyzing the economic aspects involved in
The study has also used the sources like Statistics for Planning in Kerala,
economics and statistics of Kerala. There are two main types of database on
final consumption expenditure’ on education (and other food and non–food items)
based on estimates made by the National Sample Survey Organisation (NSSO) in the
National Accounts Statistics (NAS). But, the NAS does not give any details regarding
being national in coverage. The second important source is the household surveys of
the National Sample Survey Organisation (NSSO). The several rounds of the NSSO
regular rounds also do not provide any additional details on the levels of education or
rural and urban areas separately and also by expenditure (monthly per capita
expenditure) groups.
39
More importantly, the NSSO occasionally conducts surveys concentrating on
education. One such was the 42nd round conducted in 1986-87. The survey was
repeated in 1995-96 and 2007-08 of 52nd and 64th rounds respectively. Elaborate and
comparable results on household expenditure on education are given in 52nd and 64th
rounds. Therefore, present study focused on these rounds results for analysis. These
surveys provide a lot of detailed information that helps estimation of the rate of
such as region, gender and by household expenditure groups. There are other
India and Kerala. These variables include GDP of India, per capita income of India,
Kerala, remittances to Kerala, Gross State Domestic Product (GSDP) of Kerala and
per capita income of Kerala are taken to identify the determinants of household
expenditure on education in India and Kerala. The sources of these variables are
following section. Primary data is collected from the rural6 and urban7 areas of
Thrissur district in Kerala. In order to analyze the trend and pattern of public
expenditure on education, national level data for the relevant years were collected.
Firstly, percentage change of the data is estimated. Percentage change of variable can
40
value/Current year value) x 100. Percentage change will be helpful to analyze the
relative change in the value with respect to different years. This time series data are
used to study the trends in public expenditure on education. In addition, the present
study has used Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) to infer the trend of
expenditure on education in India. The following trend equation is estimated for each
of the variables.
Then [anti-log of b–1] x 100 will be annual compound growth rate of each
variable. Equations are estimated by ordinary least square method, separately for each
variables and growth trends and growth rates are derived. The CAGR equation is used
To analyze the rural and urban household expenditure on education, the present
study has used two main tools: ratio of urban to rural household expenditure on
education and percentage change over the period. The ratio of urban to rural
household expenditure on education is a tool to derive the relative divide of rural and
to one when the rural and urban household expenditure on education is the same. If
the ratio of urban to rural is greater than one, it is biased in favor to urban areas. On
the contrary, if the urban–rural ratio is less than one it is biased towards rural areas. Its
extent and degree depend on the value of the ratio of urban to rural household
change in the value with respect to different years. Percentage change is separately
41
After the identification of trend and pattern of government and household
Kerala. The study has used the tools like percentage change, CAGR and ratio of urban
to rural household expenditure on education in order to analyze the trend and pattern
of household expenditure on education in Kerala. Besides this, the study has used
items of education. The primary objective of the study is to find out the determinants
variables are analyzed through regression techniques and time series data for India
and Kerala.
level variables are collected from Thrissur district of Kerala. Sampling framework to
collect the primary data is given in chapter 7. The study has focused on the
during the year 2001-02 and the occupational achievement and financial income of
these students/children during the year 2010-11. For this, the study collected the
primary data from the households who have higher secondary or more or higher
expenditure on education in the year 2001-02. This is to know the financial return
from household expenditure on education within a ten year period (2001-02 to 2010-
11). However, the data was collected for the year 2010-11 also. In a nutshell, the
study selected primary data from two types of household groups from the Thrissur
district. The data regarding the household expenditure on education in the year 2001-
42
02 and its financial impact in 2010-11 were collected from a set of households in the
education in the year 2010-11. But, it is important to know the current trend and
expenditure on education were collected for the year 2010-11 from another group
Education has both intrinsic and instrumental value; it is desirable not only for
the individual but also for the society as a whole. Education as private good benefits
directly those who receive it, which in turn affects the individual’s future income
stream. At the aggregate level, a better educated workforce will increase the stock of
‘human capital’ in the economy and increase its productivity. Considering the
externalities in education, it is widely accepted that the state has an important role to
in July 1991. These measures included consistent and coordinated steps to reduce
protection and liberalise controls over industry and foreign investment and to increase
policies had serious implications for social sector, as it led to drastic reduction in
against the traditional goal of India’s social policy to promote equal opportunity.
The reason for investigating the social outcomes of learning, therefore, relates
to the traditional goal of equity and social justice embedded in most social
programmes. The increased focus of active social policies means that governments
need to focus more on education and education policy, to make sure that a group of
43
disadvantaged individuals is not left behind. Moreover, since educated parents are
more likely to send their children to school, the benefits of education are perpetuated
from one generation to another generation. In fact, the indirect spill–over benefits of
education are so substantial, that they are often considered to be of greater importance
than the direct financial benefits that accrue from it. Thus, the analysis of household
subgroups in the population are of major concern for policy–makers. The present
academic research hopes to provide some insight into the relative merits of
Kerala. This is a modest attempt to study the trend and pattern of expenditure on
education in India and Kerala, its determinants and financial return from expenditure
on education in Kerala. These aspects are being neglected in education related studies
especially because they have had little access to the modern and recent data available
at present.
might develop or alter over time, study the causes of those changes. The role of
Therefore, the study about the household expenditure is highly important and
relevant. Educated and trained people can determine the growth and development of a
country. The present study may be used as a guideline to plan and design the
44
education developments in India as well as Kerala. Households should increase the
India’s economic history. Therefore, the trend analysis can help one to realize the
future actions in this direction. Subsequently, further studies can consult the findings
The scope of the present study is limited to explore the extent of household
expenditure on education and its various dimensions. Specifically, it studies the link
and the study tries to make a preliminary step in this regard. There are discrepancies
in the various sources of secondary data. However, part of the analysis of the present
study is based on the secondary data mainly from NSSO education surveys. The
limited to two periods 1995-1996 and 2007-2008. The study has not analyzed
participation, dropout and discontinuance of relevant age groups in India. The primary
data collected from respondents comprise two periods 2001-2002 and 2010-2011,
since the households may not keep the expenditure details, it is difficult to get the
agencies, with its break–up on various components. The present study has focused
Kerala. Moreover, the study has other limitations viz., selection of only one district
45
for primary survey, limited analysis on returns to education and non–consideration of
The present study has focused on two major contributors of total expenditure
on education in India and Kerala. They are households and public agencies. However,
other private agencies like NGOs, charitable institutions etc also contribute to the total
was a major limitation to these sources of spending in India and Kerala. Similarly,
may remind one of the limitations of this work. Despite the limitations, present study
the research problem, objectives of the study and data and methodology. Second
chapter gives a detailed view of the theoretical perspectives which explain the relation
Chapter 6 presents the determinants and financial return from household expenditure
on education in India and Kerala. Chapter 7 discusses the results of the primary
46
survey of the rural and urban households of Thrissur district in Kerala. Findings,
End Notes
1. Demographic dividend is a window of opportunity in the development of a society or nation
that opens up as fertility rates decline when faster rates of economic growth and human
development are possible which can be combined with effective policies and markets. Over the
next two decades the continuing demographic dividend in India could add about two
percentage points per annum to India’s per capita GDP growth.
2. Child labour refers to the employment of children in any work or activity that deprives children
of their childhood, and /or interferes with their ability to attend regular school, and that is
mentally, physically, socially or morally dangerous and harmful to their overall development.
3. From an economic perspective ‘credit–constraints’ means people would not be able to borrow
or lend in smoothing out year to year fluctuations in income, to produce a smooth consumption
stream. Credit–constraints in education are potentially harmful to both efficiency and equity. It
worlds with credit–constraints, shocks to income get reflected as shocks to consumption. They
lead to an inefficient allocation of resources and may work to perpetuate and widen income
inequality across generations.
4. Luxury good is a good for which demand increases more than proportionally as income rises,
and is a contrast to a necessity good, for which demand is not related to income
5. The Income Contingent loan (ICL) is a method of repaying education loan and easier for
students who intend to pursue jobs with lower salaries, such as careers in public service. It does
this by pegging the monthly payments to the borrower's income, family size, and total amount
borrowed. The monthly payment amount is adjusted annually, based on changes in annual
income and family size. The crucial feature to understand is that in an income-contingent
repayment arrangement, the repayment burden (percentage of earnings that must go to loan
repayment) is stipulated in the loan contract, but not the repayment period. This contrasts with
conventional loan repayment contracts (like most mortgages and current student loans) where
the repayment period is stipulated in the contract, but the annual relative burden of
repayment—the relationship between fixed repayments and current income—varies.
7. Urban area is that which follows all places with a Municipality, Corporation or Cantonment or
Notified Town Area all other places which satisfy the following criteria :a minimum
population of 5, 000,or at least 75percent of the male working population is non-agricultural, or
a density of population of at least 400 sq. Km i.e. 1000 per sq. Mile.
47