Domestic Policy: Chapter Outline
Domestic Policy: Chapter Outline
Chapter 16
Domestic Policy
Figure 16.1 Minnesota Tea Party members protest in 2011, demanding repeal of the recently enacted Patient
Protection and Affordable Care Act. Protests against expanding the federal government’s role in the economy often
use “socialism” as a negative label, even when defending existing examples of government-run programs such as
Medicare. (credit: modification of work by “Fibonacci Blue”/Flickr)
Chapter Outline
16.1 What Is Public Policy?
16.2 Categorizing Public Policy
16.3 Policy Arenas
16.4 Policymakers
16.5 Budgeting and Tax Policy
Introduction
On March 25, 2010, both chambers of Congress passed the Health Care and Education Reconciliation
Act (HCERA).1 The story of the HCERA, which expanded and improved some provisions of the Patient
Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA), also known as Obamacare, is a complicated tale of insider
politics in which the Democratic Party was able to enact sweeping health care and higher education
reforms over fierce Republican opposition (Figure 16.1). Some people laud the HCERA as an example of
getting things done in the face of partisan gridlock in Congress; others see it a case of government power
run amok. Regardless of your view, the HCERA vividly demonstrates public policymaking in action.
Each of the individual actors and institutions in the U.S. political system, such as the president, Congress,
the courts, interest groups, and the media, gives us an idea of the component parts of the system and their
functions. But in the study of public policy, we look at the larger picture and see all the parts working
together to make laws, like the HCERA, that ultimately affect citizens and their communities.
What is public policy? How do different areas of policy differ, and what roles do policy analysts and
advocates play? What programs does the national government currently provide? And how do budgetary
policy and politics operate? This chapter answers these questions and more.
590 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
It is easy to imagine that when designers engineer a product, like a car, they do so with the intent of
satisfying the consumer. But the design of any complicated product must take into account the needs
of regulators, transporters, assembly line workers, parts suppliers, and myriad other participants in the
manufacture and shipment process. And manufacturers must also be aware that consumer tastes are fickle:
A gas-guzzling sports car may appeal to an unmarried twenty-something with no children; but what
happens to product satisfaction when gas prices fluctuate, or the individual gets married and has children?
In many ways, the process of designing domestic policy isn’t that much different. The government, just like
auto companies, needs to ensure that its citizen-consumers have access to an array of goods and services.
And just as in auto companies, a wide range of actors is engaged in figuring out how to do it. Sometimes,
this process effectively provides policies that benefit citizens. But just as often, the process of policymaking
is muddied by the demands of competing interests with different opinions about society’s needs or the
role that government should play in meeting them. To understand why, we begin by thinking about what
we mean by the term “public policy.”
Governments frequently interact with individual actors like citizens, corporations, or other countries.
They may even pass highly specialized pieces of legislation, known as private bills, which confer specific
privileges on individual entities. But public policy covers only those issues that are of interest to larger
segments of society or that directly or indirectly affect society as a whole. Paying off the loans of a specific
individual would not be public policy, but creating a process for loan forgiveness available to certain types
of borrowers (such as those who provide a public service by becoming teachers) would certainly rise to the
level of public policy.
A final important characteristic of public policy is that it is more than just the actions of government; it
also includes the behaviors or outcomes that government action creates. Policy can even be made when
government refuses to act in ways that would change the status quo when circumstances or public opinion
begin to shift.5 For example, much of the debate over gun safety policy in the United States has centered
on the unwillingness of Congress to act, even in the face of public opinion that supports some changes to
gun policy. In fact, one of the last major changes occurred in 2004, when lawmakers’ inaction resulted in
the expiration of a piece of legislation known as the Federal Assault Weapons Ban (1994).6
Figure 16.2 President Obama signs a 2009 executive order to accelerate the federal government’s recruitment and
hiring of returning veterans. Executive orders are an expression of public policy undertaken at the discretion of the
president.
Typically, elected and even high-ranking appointed officials lack either the specific expertise or tools
needed to successfully create and implement public policy on their own. They turn instead to the vast
government bureaucracy to provide policy guidance. For example, when Congress passed the Clean Water
Act (1972), it dictated that steps should be taken to improve water quality throughout the country. But
592 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
it ultimately left it to the bureaucracy to figure out exactly how ‘clean’ water needed to be. In doing so,
Congress provided the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) with discretion to determine how much
pollution is allowed in U.S. waterways.
There is one more way of thinking about policy outcomes: in terms of winners and losers. Almost by
definition, public policy promotes certain types of behavior while punishing others. So, the individuals
or corporations that a policy favors are most likely to benefit, or win, whereas those the policy ignores
or punishes are likely to lose. Even the best-intended policies can have unintended consequences and
may even ultimately harm someone, if only those who must pay for the policy through higher taxes. A
policy designed to encourage students to go to liberal arts colleges may cause trade school enrollment to
decline. Strategies to promote diversity in higher education may make it more difficult for qualified white
or male applicants to get accepted into competitive programs. Efforts to clean up drinking water supplies
may make companies less competitive and cost employees their livelihood. Even something that seems to
help everyone, such as promoting charitable giving through tax incentives, runs the risk of lowering tax
revenues from the rich (who contribute a greater share of their income to charity) and shifting tax burdens
to the poor (who must spend a higher share of their income to achieve a desired standard of living).
And while policy pronouncements and bureaucratic actions are certainly meant to rationalize policy, it is
whether a given policy helps or hurts constituents (or is perceived to do so) that ultimately determines
how voters will react toward the government in future elections.
Figure 16.3 In 1937, during the Great Depression, families in Calipatria, California, waited in line for relief
checks, part of the federal government’s newly introduced social safety net. (credit: modification of work by
the Library of Congress)
In recent decades, however, some have criticized these safety net programs for inefficiency and for
incentivizing welfare dependence. They deride “government leeches” who use food stamps to buy lobster or
other seemingly inappropriate items. Critics deeply resent the use of taxpayer money to relieve social problems
like unemployment and poverty; workers who may themselves be struggling to put food on the table or pay the
mortgage feel their hard-earned money should not support other families. “If I can get by without government
support,” the reasoning goes, “those welfare families can do the same. Their poverty is not my problem.”
So where should the government draw the line? While there have been some instances of welfare fraud, the
welfare reforms of the 1990s have made long-term dependence on the federal government less likely as the
welfare safety net was pushed to the states. And with the income gap between the richest and the poorest at
its highest level in history, this topic is likely to continue to receive much discussion in the coming years.
594 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
Where is the middle ground in the public policy argument over the social safety net? How can the government
protect its most vulnerable citizens without placing an undue burden on others?
Link to Learning
The idea of public policy is by its very nature a politically contentious one. Among the differences
between American liberals and conservatives are the policy preferences prevalent in each group. Modern
liberals tend to feel very comfortable with the idea of the government shepherding progressive social and
economic reforms, believing that these will lead to outcomes more equitable and fair for all members of
society. Conservatives, on the other hand, often find government involvement onerous and overreaching.
They feel society would function more efficiently if oversight of most “public” matters were returned to
the private sphere. Before digging too deeply into a discussion of the nature of public policy in the United
States, let us look first at why so many aspects of society come under the umbrella of public policy to begin
with.
Figure 16.4 This Library of Congress photo shows an early nineteenth-century subsistence farm in West Virginia,
which once included crops, livestock, and an orchard. (credit: modification of work by the Library of Congress)
Economists use the term goods to describe the range of commodities, services, and systems that help us
satisfy our wants or needs. This term can certainly apply to the food you eat or the home you live in, but it
can also describe the systems of transportation or public safety used to protect them. Most of the goods you
interact with in your daily life are private goods, which means that they can be owned by a particular person
or group of people, and are excluded from use by others, typically by means of a price. For example, your
home or apartment is a private good reserved for your own use because you pay rent or make mortgage
payments for the privilege of living there. Further, private goods are finite and can run out if overused,
even if only in the short term. The fact that private goods are excludable and finite makes them tradable. A
farmer who grows corn, for instance, owns that corn, and since only a finite amount of corn exists, others
may want to trade their goods for it if their own food supplies begin to dwindle.
Proponents of free-market economics believe that the market forces of supply and demand, working
without any government involvement, are the most effective way for markets to operate. One of the basic
principles of free-market economics is that for just about any good that can be privatized, the most efficient
means for exchange is the marketplace. A well-functioning market will allow producers of goods to come
together with consumers of goods to negotiate a trade. People facilitate trade by creating a currency—a
common unit of exchange—so they do not need to carry around everything they may want to trade at
all times. As long as there are several providers or sellers of the same good, consumers can negotiate
with them to find a price they are willing to pay. As long as there are several buyers for a seller’s goods,
providers can negotiate with them to find a price buyers are willing to accept. And, the logic goes, if prices
begin to rise too much, other sellers will enter the marketplace, offering lower prices.
A second basic principle of free-market economics is that it is largely unnecessary for the government to
protect the value of private goods. Farmers who own land used for growing food have a vested interest in
protecting their land to ensure its continued production. Business owners must protect the reputation of
their business or no one will buy from them. And, to the degree that producers need to ensure the quality
of their product or industry, they can accomplish that by creating a group or association that operates
outside government control. In short, industries have an interest in self-regulating to protect their own
value. According to free-market economics, as long as everything we could ever want or need is a private
good, and so long as every member of society has some ability to provide for themselves and their families,
public policy regulating the exchange of goods and services is really unnecessary.
Some people in the United States argue that the self-monitoring and self-regulating incentives provided
by the existence of private goods mean that sound public policy requires very little government action.
596 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
Known as libertarians, these individuals believe government almost always operates less efficiently than
the private sector (the segment of the economy run for profit and not under government control), and that
government actions should therefore be kept to a minimum.
Even as many in the United States recognize the benefits provided by private goods, we have increasingly
come to recognize problems with the idea that all social problems can be solved by exclusively private
ownership. First, not all goods can be classified as strictly private. Can you really consider the air you
breathe to be private? Air is a difficult good to privatize because it is not excludable—everyone can get
access to it at all times—and no matter how much of it you breathe, there is still plenty to go around.
Geographic regions like forests have environmental, social, recreational, and aesthetic value that cannot
easily be reserved for private ownership. Resources like migrating birds or schools of fish may have value
if hunted or fished, but they cannot be owned due to their migratory nature. Finally, national security
provided by the armed forces protects all citizens and cannot reasonably be reserved for only a few.
These are all examples of what economists call public goods, sometimes referred to as collective goods.
Unlike private property, they are not excludable and are essentially infinite. Forests, water, and fisheries,
however, are a type of public good called common goods, which are not excludable but may be finite. The
problem with both public and common goods is that since no one owns them, no one has a financial
interest in protecting their long-term or future value. Without government regulation, a factory owner can
feel free to pollute the air or water, since he or she will have no responsibility for the pollution once the
winds or waves carry it somewhere else (see Figure 16.5). Without government regulation, someone can
hunt all the migratory birds or deplete a fishery by taking all the fish, eliminating future breeding stocks
that would maintain the population. The situation in which individuals exhaust a common resource by
acting in their own immediate self-interest is called the tragedy of the commons.
Figure 16.5 Air pollution billows from a power plant before the installation of emission control equipment for the
removal of sulfur dioxide and particulate matter. Can you see why uncontrolled pollution is an example of the “tragedy
of the commons”?
A second problem with strict adherence to free-market economics is that some goods are too large, or too
expensive, for individuals to provide them for themselves. Consider the need for a marketplace: Where
does the marketplace come from? How do we get the goods to market? Who provides the roads and
bridges? Who patrols the waterways? Who provides security? Who ensures the regulation of the currency?
No individual buyer or seller could accomplish this. The very nature of the exchange of private goods
requires a system that has some of the openness of public or common goods, but is maintained by either
groups of individuals or entire societies.
Economists consider goods like cable TV, cellphone service, and private schools to be toll goods. Toll goods
are similar to public goods in that they are open to all and theoretically infinite if maintained, but they are
paid for or provided by some outside (nongovernment) entity. Many people can make use of them, but
only if they can pay the price. The name “toll goods” comes from the fact that, early on, many toll roads
were in fact privately owned commodities. Even today, states from Virginia to California have allowed
private companies to build public roads in exchange for the right to profit by charging tolls.8
So long as land was plentiful, and most people in the United States lived a largely rural subsistence
lifestyle, the difference between private, public, common, and toll goods was mostly academic. But as
public lands increasingly became private through sale and settlement, and as industrialization and the
rise of mass production allowed monopolies and oligopolies to become more influential, support for
public policies regulating private entities grew. By the beginning of the twentieth century, led by the
Progressives, the United States had begun to search for ways to govern large businesses that had managed
to distort market forces by monopolizing the supply of goods. And, largely as a result of the Great
Depression, people wanted ways of developing and protecting public goods that were fairer and more
equitable than had existed before. These forces and events led to the increased regulation of public and
common goods, and a move for the public sector—the government—to take over of the provision of many
toll goods.
Figure 16.6 In an example of distributive policy, the Union Pacific Railroad was given land and resources to help
build a national railroad system. Here, its workers construct the Devil’s Gate Bridge in Utah in 1869.
The same process operates in the agricultural sector, where various federal programs help farmers and
food producers through price supports and crop insurance, among other forms of assistance. These
programs help individual farmers and agriculture companies stay afloat and realize consistent profits.
They also achieve the broader goal of providing plenty of sustenance for the people of the United States,
so that few of us have to “live off the land.”
Milestone
The Hoover Dam: The Federal Effort to Domesticate the Colorado River
As westward expansion led to development of the American Southwest, settlers increasingly realized that
they needed a way to control the frequent floods and droughts that made agriculture difficult in the region.
As early as 1890, land speculators had tried diverting the Colorado River for this purpose, but it wasn’t until
1922 that the U.S. Bureau of Reclamation (then called the Reclamation Service) chose the Black Canyon
as a good location for a dam to divert the river. Since it would affect seven states (as well as Mexico),
the federal government took the lead on the project, which eventually cost $49 million and more than one
hundred lives. The dam faced significant opposition from members of other states, who felt its massive price
tag (almost $670 million in today’s dollars10) benefitted only a small group, not the whole nation. However, in
1928, Senator Hiram Johnson and Representative Phil Swing, both Republicans from California, won the day.
Congress passed the Boulder Canyon Project Act, authorizing the construction of one of the most ambitious
engineering feats in U.S. history. The Hoover Dam (Figure 16.7), completed in 1935, served the dual purposed
of generating hydroelectric power and irrigating two million acres of land from the resulting reservoir (Lake
Mead).
Figure 16.7 Workers construct the Hoover Dam, a distributive policy project, in Nevada in 1932.
Was the construction of the Hoover Dam an effective expression of public policy? Why or why not?
Link to Learning
Other examples of distributive policy support citizens’ efforts to achieve “the American Dream.” American
society recognizes the benefits of having citizens who are financially invested in the country’s future.
Among the best ways to encourage this investment are to ensure that citizens are highly educated and
have the ability to acquire high-cost private goods such as homes and businesses. However, very few
people have the savings necessary to pay upfront for a college education, a first home purchase, or the
start-up costs of a business. To help out, the government has created a range of incentives that everyone
in the country pays for through taxes but that directly benefit only the recipients. Examples include grants
(such as Pell grants), tax credits and deductions, and subsidized or federally guaranteed loans. Each of
these programs aims to achieve a policy outcome. Pell grants exist to help students graduate from college,
whereas Federal Housing Administration mortgage loans lead to home ownership.
While distributive policy, according to Lowi, has diffuse costs and concentrated benefits, regulatory
policy features the opposite arrangement, with concentrated costs and diffuse benefits. A relatively small
number of groups or individuals bear the costs of regulatory policy, but its benefits are expected to
be distributed broadly across society. As you might imagine, regulatory policy is most effective for
controlling or protecting public or common resources. Among the best-known examples are policies
designed to protect public health and safety, and the environment. These regulatory policies prevent
manufacturers or businesses from maximizing their profits by excessively polluting the air or water,
selling products they know to be harmful, or compromising the health of their employees during
production.
In the United States, nationwide calls for a more robust regulatory policy first grew loud around the turn
of the twentieth century and the dawn of the Industrial Age. Investigative journalists—called muckrakers
by politicians and business leaders who were the focus of their investigations—began to expose many of
the ways in which manufacturers were abusing the public trust. Although various forms of corruption
topped the list of abuses, among the most famous muckraker exposés was The Jungle, a 1906 novel by
Upton Sinclair that focused on unsanitary working conditions and unsavory business practices in the
meat-packing industry.11 This work and others like it helped to spur the passage of the Pure Food and
Drug Act (1906) and ultimately led to the creation of government agencies such as the U.S. Food and Drug
Administration (FDA).12 The nation’s experiences during the depression of 1896 and the Great Depression
of the 1930s also led to more robust regulatory policies designed to improve the transparency of financial
markets and prevent monopolies from forming.
A final type of policy is redistributive policy, so named because it redistributes resources in society from
one group to another. That is, according to Lowi, the costs are concentrated and so are the benefits, but
different groups bear the costs and enjoy the benefits. Most redistributive policies are intended to have a
sort of “Robin Hood” effect; their goal is to transfer income and wealth from one group to another such
that everyone enjoys at least a minimal standard of living. Typically, the wealthy and middle class pay
into the federal tax base, which then funds need-based programs that support low-income individuals
and families. A few examples of redistributive policies are Head Start (education), Medicaid (health
care), Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF, income support), and food programs like the
Supplementary Nutritional Aid Program (SNAP). The government also uses redistribution to incentivize
specific behaviors or aid small groups of people. Pell grants to encourage college attendance and tax credits
to encourage home ownership are other examples of redistribution.
In practice, public policy consists of specific programs that provide resources to members of society, create
regulations that protect U.S. citizens, and attempt to equitably fund the government. We can broadly
categorize most policies based on their goals or the sector of society they affect, although many, such as
food stamps, serve multiple purposes. Implementing these policies costs hundreds of billions of dollars
each year, and understanding the goals of this spending and where the money goes is of vital importance
to citizens and students of politics alike.
Figure 16.8 In 1930, when this Ford automotive plant opened in Long Beach, California, American workers had few
economic protections to rely on if they were injured or could not maintain such physical activity as they aged.
Social Security addresses these concerns with three important tools. First and best known is the retirement
benefit. After completing a minimum number of years of work, American workers may claim a form
of pension upon reaching retirement age. It is often called an entitlement program since it guarantees
benefits to a particular group, and virtually everyone will eventually qualify for the plan given the
relatively low requirements for enrollment. The amount of money a worker receives is based loosely on his
or her lifetime earnings. Full retirement age was originally set at sixty-five, although changes in legislation
have increased it to sixty-seven for workers born after 1959.15 A valuable added benefit is that, under
certain circumstances, this income may also be claimed by the survivors of qualifying workers, such as
spouses and minor children, even if they themselves did not have a wage income.
A second Social Security benefit is a disability payout, which the government distributes to workers who
become unable to work due to physical or mental disability. To qualify, workers must demonstrate that the
injury or incapacitation will last at least twelve months. A third and final benefit is Supplemental Security
Income, which provides supplemental income to adults or children with considerable disability or to the
elderly who fall below an income threshold.
During the George W. Bush administration, Social Security became a highly politicized topic as the
Republican Party sought to find a way of preventing what experts predicted would be the impending
collapse of the Social Security system (Figure 16.9). In 1950, the ratio of workers paying into the program
to beneficiaries receiving payments was 16.5 to 1. By 2013, that number was 2.8 to 1 and falling. Most
predictions in fact suggest that, due to continuing demographic changes including slower population
growth and an aging population, by 2033, the amount of revenue generated from payroll taxes will no
longer be sufficient to cover costs. The Bush administration proposed avoiding this by privatizing the
program, in effect, taking it out of the government’s hands and making individuals’ benefits variable
instead of defined. The effort ultimately failed, and Social Security’s long-term viability continues to
remain uncertain. Numerous other plans for saving the program have been proposed, including raising
the retirement age, increasing payroll taxes (especially on the wealthy) by removing the $118,500 income
cap, and reducing payouts for wealthier retirees. None of these proposals have been able to gain traction,
however.
Figure 16.9 President George W. Bush discusses Social Security in Florida at the outset of his second term in 2005.
While Social Security was designed to provide cash payments to sustain the aged and disabled, Medicare
and Medicaid were intended to ensure that vulnerable populations have access to health care. Medicare,
like Social Security, is an entitlement program funded through payroll taxes. Its purpose is to make sure
that senior citizens and retirees have access to low-cost health care they might not otherwise have, because
most U.S. citizens get their health insurance through their employers. Medicare provides three major forms
of coverage: a guaranteed insurance benefit that helps cover major hospitalization, fee-based supplemental
coverage that retirees can use to lower costs for doctor visits and other health expenses, and a prescription
drug benefit. Medicare faces many of the same long-term challenges as Social Security, due to the same
demographic shifts. Medicare also faces the problem that health care costs are rising significantly faster
than inflation. In 2014, Medicare cost the federal government almost $597 billion.16
Medicaid is a formula-based, health insurance program, which means beneficiaries must demonstrate
they fall within a particular income category. Individuals in the Medicaid program receive a fairly
comprehensive set of health benefits, although access to health care may be limited because fewer
providers accept payments from the program (it pays them less for services than does Medicare). Medicaid
differs dramatically from Medicare in that it is partially funded by states, many of which have reduced
access to the program by setting the income threshold so low that few people qualify. The ACA (2010)
sought to change that by providing more federal money to the states if they agreed to raise minimum
income requirements. Many states have refused, which has helped to keep the overall costs of Medicaid
lower, even though it has also left many people without health coverage they might receive if they lived
elsewhere. Total costs for Medicaid in 2014 were about $492 billion, about $305 billion of which was paid
by the federal government.17
Collectively, Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid make up the lion’s share of total federal government
spending, almost 50 percent in 2014 and more than 50 percent in 2015. Several other smaller programs also
provide income support to families. Most of these are formula-based, or means-tested, requiring citizens
to meet certain maximum income requirements in order to qualify. A few examples are TANF, SNAP (also
called food stamps), the unemployment insurance program, and various housing assistance programs.
Collectively, these programs add up to a little over $480 billion.
Much of the nation’s science and technology policy benefits its military, for instance, in the form of
research and development funding for a range of defense projects. The federal government still promotes
research for civilian uses, mostly through the National Science Foundation, the National Institutes of
Health, the National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA), and the National Oceanic and
Atmospheric Administration. Recent debate over these agencies has focused on whether government
funding is necessary or if private entities would be better suited. For example, although NASA continues
to develop a replacement for the now-defunct U.S. space shuttle program (Figure 16.10), much of its
workload is currently being performed by private companies working to develop their own space launch,
resupply, and tourism programs.
Figure 16.10 NASA launches the space shuttle Discovery from the Kennedy Space Center in 2007. Should the
private sector fund space exploration programs rather than the government? (credit: NASA)
The problem of trying to direct and fund the education of a modern U.S. workforce is familiar to many
students of American government. Historically, education has largely been the job of the states. While they
have provided a very robust K–12 public education system, the national government has never moved to
create an equivalent system of national higher education academies or universities as many other countries
have done. As the need to keep the nation competitive with others became more pressing, however, the
U.S. government did step in to direct its education dollars toward creating greater equity and ease of access
to the existing public and private systems.
The overwhelming portion of the government’s education money is spent on student loans, grants, and
work-study programs. Resources are set aside to cover job-retraining programs for individuals who lack
private-sector skills or who need to be retrained to meet changes in the economy’s demands for the
labor force. National policy toward elementary and secondary education programs has typically focused
on increasing resources available to school districts for nontraditional programs (such as preschool and
special needs), or helping poorer schools stay competitive with wealthier institutions.
has chosen to provide significant agriculture and energy subsidies to cover the risks inherent in the
unpredictability of the weather and oil exploration. Government subsidies also protect these industries’
profitability. These two purposes have even overlapped in the government’s controversial decision to
subsidize the production of ethanol, a fuel source similar to gasoline but generated from corn.
When it comes to regulation, the federal government has created several agencies responsible for
providing for everything from worker safety (OSHA, the Occupational Safety and Health Administration),
to food safety (FDA), to consumer protection, where the recently created Bureau of Consumer Protection
ensures that businesses do not mislead consumers with deceptive or manipulative practices. Another
prominent federal agency, the EPA, is charged with ensuring that businesses do not excessively pollute the
nation’s air or waterways. A complex array of additional regulatory agencies governs specific industries
such as banking and finance, which are detailed later in this chapter.
Link to Learning
The policy areas we’ve described so far fall far short of forming an exhaustive list.
This site (https://openstaxcollege.org/l/29PoliAgen) contains the major topic
categories of substantive policy in U.S. government, according to the Policy Agendas
Project. View subcategories by clicking on the major topic categories.
16.4 Policymakers
Learning Objectives
By the end of this section, you will be able to:
• Identify types of policymakers in different issue areas
• Describe the public policy process
Many Americans were concerned when Congress began debating the ACA. As the program took shape,
some people felt the changes it proposed were being debated too hastily, would be implemented too
quickly, or would summarily give the government control over an important piece of the U.S.
economy—the health care industry. Ironically, the government had been heavily engaged in providing
health care for decades. More than 50 percent of all health care dollars spent were being spent by the
U.S. government well before the ACA was enacted. As you have already learned, Medicare was created
decades earlier. Despite protesters’ resistance to government involvement in health care, there is no
keeping government out of Medicare; the government IS Medicare.
What many did not realize is that few if any of the proposals that eventually became part of the ACA were
original. While the country was worried about problems like terrorism, the economy, and conflicts over
gay rights, armies of individuals were debating the best ways to fix the nation’s health care delivery. Two
important but overlapping groups defended their preferred policy changes: policy advocates and policy
analysts.
POLICY ADVOCATES
Take a minute to think of a policy change you believe would improve some condition in the United States.
Now ask yourself this: “Why do I want to change this policy?” Are you motivated by a desire for justice?
Do you feel the policy change would improve your life or that of members of your community? Is your
606 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
sense of morality motivating you to change the status quo? Would your profession be helped? Do you feel
that changing the policy might raise your status?
Most people have some policy position or issue they would like to see altered (see Figure 16.11). One
of the reasons the news media are so enduring is that citizens have a range of opinions on public policy,
and they are very interested in debating how a given change would improve their lives or the country’s.
But despite their interests, most people do little more than vote or occasionally contribute to a political
campaign. A few people, however, become policy advocates by actively working to propose or maintain
public policy.
Figure 16.11 In 2010, members of PETA (People for the Ethical Treatment of Animals) demonstrate against a local
zoo. As policy advocates, PETA’s members often publicize their position on how animals should be treated.
One way to think about policy advocates is to recognize that they hold a normative position on an issue,
that is, they have a conviction about what should or ought to be done. The best public policy, in their
view, is one that accomplishes a specific goal or outcome. For this reason, advocates often begin with an
objective and then try to shape or create proposals that help them accomplish that goal. Facts, evidence,
and analysis are important tools for convincing policymakers or the general public of the benefits of their
proposals. Private citizens often find themselves in advocacy positions, particularly if they are required to
take on leadership roles in their private lives or in their organizations. The most effective advocates are
usually hired professionals who form lobbying groups or think tanks to promote their agenda.
A lobbying group that frequently takes on advocacy roles is AARP (formerly the American Association
of Retired Persons) (Figure 16.12). AARP’s primary job is to convince the government to provide more
public resources and services to senior citizens, often through regulatory or redistributive politics. Chief
among its goals are lower health care costs and the safety of Social Security pension payments. These aims
put AARP in the Democratic Party’s electoral coalition, since Democrats have historically been stronger
advocates for Medicare’s creation and expansion. In 2002, for instance, Democrats and Republicans were
debating a major change to Medicare. The Democratic Party supported expanding Medicare to include
free or low-cost prescription drugs, while the Republicans preferred a plan that would require seniors
to purchase drug insurance through a private insurer. The government would subsidize costs, but many
seniors would still have substantial out-of-pocket expenses. To the surprise of many, AARP supported the
Republican proposal.
Figure 16.12 First Lady Michelle Obama shows her AARP membership card on her fiftieth birthday in January 2014.
AARP is a major policy advocate for older people and retirees.
While Democrats argued that their position would have provided a better deal for individuals, AARP
reasoned that the Republican plan had a much better chance of passing. The Republicans controlled the
House and looked likely to reclaim control of the Senate in the upcoming election. Then-president George
W. Bush was a Republican and would almost certainly have vetoed the Democratic approach. AARP’s
support for the legislation helped shore up support for Republicans in the 2002 midterm election and also
help convince a number of moderate Democrats to support the bill (with some changes), which passed
despite apparent public disapproval. AARP had done its job as an advocate for seniors by creating a new
benefit it hoped could later be expanded, rather than fighting for an extreme position that would have left
it with nothing.18
Not all policy advocates are as willing to compromise their positions. It is much easier for a group
like AARP to compromise over the amount of money seniors will receive, for instance, than it is for an
evangelical religious group to compromise over issues like abortion, or for civil rights groups to accept
something less than equality. Nor are women’s rights groups likely to accept pay inequality as it currently
exists. It is easier to compromise over financial issues than over our individual views of morality or social
justice.
POLICY ANALYSTS
A second approach to creating public policy is a bit more objective. Rather than starting with what ought
to happen and seeking ways to make it so, policy analysts try to identify all the possible choices available
to a decision maker and then gauge their impacts if implemented. The goal of the analyst isn’t really to
encourage the implementation of any of the options; rather, it is to make sure decision makers are fully
informed about the implications of the decisions they do make.
Understanding the financial and other costs and benefits of policy choices requires analysts to make
strategic guesses about how the public and governmental actors will respond. For example, when
policymakers are considering changes to health care policy, one very important question is how many
people will participate. If very few people had chosen to take advantage of the new health care plans
available under the ACA marketplace, it would have been significantly cheaper than advocates proposed,
but it also would have failed to accomplish the key goal of increasing the number of insured. But if people
608 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
who currently have insurance had dropped it to take advantage of ACA’s subsidies, the program’s costs
would have skyrocketed with very little real benefit to public health. Similarly, had all states chosen to
create their own marketplaces, the cost and complexity of ACA’s implementation would have been greatly
reduced.
Because advocates have an incentive to understate costs and overstate benefits, policy analysis tends to
be a highly politicized aspect of government. It is critical for policymakers and voters that policy analysts
provide the most accurate analysis possible. A number of independent or semi-independent think tanks
have sprung up in Washington, DC, to provide assessments of policy options. Most businesses or trade
organizations also employ their own policy-analysis wings to help them understand proposed changes
or even offer some of their own. Some of these try to be as impartial as possible. Most, however, have a
known bias toward policy advocacy. The Cato Institute, for example, is well known and highly respected
policy analysis group that both liberal and conservative politicians have turned to when considering
policy options. But the Cato Institute has a known libertarian bias; most of the problems it selects for
analysis have the potential for private sector solutions. This means its analysts tend to include the rosiest
assumptions of economic growth when considering tax cuts and to overestimate the costs of public sector
proposals.
Link to Learning
Both the Congress and the president have tried to reduce the bias in policy analysis by creating their
own theoretically nonpartisan policy branches. In Congress, the best known of these is the Congressional
Budget Office, or CBO. Authorized in the 1974 Congressional Budget and Impoundment Control Act, the
CBO was formally created in 1975 as a way of increasing Congress’s independence from the executive
branch. The CBO is responsible for scoring the spending or revenue impact of all proposed legislation to
assess its net effect on the budget. In recent years, it has been the CBO’s responsibility to provide Congress
with guidance on how to best balance the budget (see Figure 16.13). The formulas that the CBO uses in
scoring the budget have become an important part of the policy debate, even as the group has tried to
maintain its nonpartisan nature.
Figure 16.13 The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) is responsible for studying the impact of all proposed
legislation to assess its net effect on the budget and tracking federal debt. For example, this 2010 CBO chart shows
federal debt held by the public as a percentage of gross domestic product from 1790 through 2010 and projected to
2035.
In the executive branch, each individual department and agency is technically responsible for its own
policy analysis. The assumption is that experts in the Federal Communications Commission or the Federal
Elections Commission are best equipped to evaluate the impact of various proposals within their policy
domain. Law requires that most regulatory changes made by the federal government also include the
opportunity for public input so the government can both gauge public opinion and seek outside
perspectives.
Executive branch agencies are usually also charged with considering the economic impact of regulatory
action, although some agencies have been better at this than others. Critics have frequently singled out
the EPA and OSHA for failing to adequately consider the impact of new rules on business. Within the
White House itself, the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) was created to “serve the President of
the United States in implementing his [or her] vision” of policy. Policy analysis is important to the OMB’s
function, but as you can imagine, it frequently compromises its objectivity during policy formulation.
Link to Learning
Get Connected!
Preparing to Be a Policymaker
What is your passion? Is there an aspect of society you think should be changed? Become a public policy
advocate for it! One way to begin is by petitioning the Office of the President. In years past, citizens wrote
letters to express grievances or policy preferences. Today, you can visit We the People, the White House
online petitions platform (Figure 16.14). At this government site, you can search for petitions related to your
cause or post your own. If your petition gets enough signatures, the White House will issue a response. The
petitions range from serious to silly, but the process is an important way to speak out about the policies that
are important to you.
Figure 16.14 The White House petition website encourages citizens to participate in the democratic
process.
Follow-up activity: Choose an issue you are passionate about. Visit We the People
(https://openstaxcollege.org/l/29WHpet) to see if there is already a petition there concerning your chosen
issue. If so, join the community promoting your cause. If not, create your own petition and try to gather enough
signatures to receive an official response.
In the second policy phase, enactment, the elected branches of government typically consider one specific
solution to a problem and decide whether to pass it. This stage is the most visible one and usually garners
the most press coverage. And yet it is somewhat anticlimatic. By the time a specific policy proposal (a
solution) comes out of agenda setting for a yes/no vote, it can be something of a foregone conclusion that
it will pass.
Once the policy has been enacted—usually by the legislative and/or executive branches of the
government, like Congress or the president at the national level or the legislature or governor of a
state—government agencies do the work of actually implementing it. On a national level, policy
implementation can be either top-down or bottom-up. In top-down implementation, the federal
government dictates the specifics of the policy, and each state implements it the same exact way. In
bottom-up implementation, the federal government allows local areas some flexibility to meet their
specific challenges and needs.20
Evaluation, the last stage of the process, should be tied directly to the policy’s desired outcomes.
Evaluation essentially asks, “How well did this policy do what we designed it to do?” The answers
can sometimes be surprising. In one hotly debated case, the United States funded abstinence-only sex
education for teens with the goal of reducing teen pregnancy. A 2011 study published in the journal
PLoS One, however, found that abstinence-only education actually increased teen pregnancy rates.21 The
information from the evaluation stage can feed back into the other stages, informing future decisions and
creating a public policy cycle.
A country spends, raises, and regulates money in accordance with its values. In all, the federal
government’s budget for 2016 was $3.8 trillion. This chapter has provided a brief overview of some of
the budget’s key areas of expenditure, and thus some insight into modern American values. But these
values are only part of the budgeting story. Policymakers make considerable effort to ensure that long-
term priorities are protected from the heat of the election cycle and short-term changes in public opinion.
The decision to put some policymaking functions out of the reach of Congress also reflects economic
philosophies about the best ways to grow, stimulate, and maintain the economy. The role of politics in
drafting the annual budget is indeed large (Figure 16.15), but we should not underestimate the challenges
elected officials face as a result of decisions made in the past.
612 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
Figure 16.15 Strategists discuss the budget in the Roosevelt Room of the White House in 2009.
began to argue that the social welfare and high tax policies created in the name of Keynesianism were
overstimulating the economy, creating a situation in which demand for products had outstripped
investors’ willingness to increase production.22 They called for an approach known as supply-side
economics, which argues that economic growth is largely a function of the productive capacity of a
country. Supply-siders have argued that increased regulation and higher taxes reduce the incentive to
invest new money into the economy, to the point where little growth can occur. They have advocated
reducing taxes and regulations to spur economic growth.
Figure 16.16 This chart of U.S. federal spending for 2015 shows the proportions of mandatory and discretionary
spending, about 57 percent and 43 percent, respectively.
Congress is ultimately responsible for setting the formulas for mandatory payouts, but as we saw in the
earlier discussion regarding Social Security, major reforms to entitlement formulas are difficult to enact. As
a result, the size and growth of mandatory spending in future budgets are largely a function of previous
legislation that set the formulas up in the first place. So long as supporters of particular programs can block
changes to the formulas, funding will continue almost on autopilot. Keynesians support this mandatory
614 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
spending, along with other elements of social welfare policy, because they help maintain a minimal level
of consumption that should, in theory, prevent recessions from turning into depressions, which are more
severe downturns.
Portions of the budget not devoted to mandatory spending are categorized as discretionary spending
because Congress must pass legislation to authorize money to be spent each year. About 50 percent
of the approximately $1.2 trillion set aside for discretionary spending each year pays for most of the
operations of government, including employee salaries and the maintenance of federal buildings. It also
covers science and technology spending, foreign affairs initiatives, education spending, federally provided
transportation costs, and many of the redistributive benefits most people in the United States have come
to take for granted.24 The other half of discretionary spending—and the second-largest component of
the total budget—is devoted to the military. (Only Social Security is larger.) Defense spending is used to
maintain the U.S. military presence at home and abroad, procure and develop new weapons, and cover
the cost of any wars or other military engagements in which the United States is currently engaged (Figure
16.17).
Figure 16.17 The war in Afghanistan, ongoing since 2001, has cost the United States billions of dollars in
discretionary military spending authorized by Congress every year.
In theory, the amount of revenue raised by the national government should be equal to these expenses,
but with the exception of a brief period from 1998 to 2000, that has not been the case. The economic
recovery from the 2007–2009 recession, and budget control efforts implemented since then, have managed
to cut the annual deficit—the amount by which expenditures are greater than revenues—by more than
half. However, the amount of money the U.S. government needed to borrow to pay its bills in 2016 was
still in excess of $400 billion25. This was in addition to the country’s almost $19 trillion of total debt—the
amount of money the government owes its creditors—at the end of 2015, according to the Department of
the Treasury.
Balancing the budget has been a major goal of both the Republican and Democratic parties for the past
several decades, although the parties tend to disagree on the best way to accomplish the task. One
frequently offered solution, particularly among supply-side advocates, is to simply cut spending. This has
proven to be much easier said than done. If Congress were to try to balance the budget only through
discretionary spending, it would need to cut about one-third of spending on programs like defense, higher
education, agriculture, police enforcement, transportation, and general government operations. Given the
number and popularity of many of these programs, it is difficult to imagine this would be possible. To
use spending cuts alone as a way to control the deficit, Congress will almost certainly be required to
cut or control the costs of mandatory spending programs like Social Security and Medicare—a radically
unpopular step.
TAX POLICY
The other option available for balancing the budget is to increase revenue. All governments must raise
revenue in order to operate. The most common way is by applying some sort of tax on residents (or on their
behaviors) in exchange for the benefits the government provides (Figure 16.18). As necessary as taxes
are, however, they are not without potential downfalls. First, the more money the government collects
to cover its costs, the less residents are left with to spend and invest. Second, attempts to raise revenues
through taxation may alter the behavior of residents in ways that are counterproductive to the state and
the broader economy. Excessively taxing necessary and desirable behaviors like consumption (with a sales
tax) or investment (with a capital gains tax) will discourage citizens from engaging in them, potentially
slowing economic growth. The goal of tax policy, then, is to determine the most effective way of meeting
the nation’s revenue obligations without harming other public policy goals.
Figure 16.18 A U.S. marine fills out an income tax form. Income taxes in the United States are progressive taxes.
As you would expect, Keynesians and supply-siders disagree about which forms of tax policy are best.
Keynesians, with their concern about whether consumers can really stimulate demand, prefer progressive
taxes systems that increase the effective tax rate as the taxpayer’s income increases. This policy leaves those
most likely to spend their money with more money to spend. For example, in 2015, U.S. taxpayers paid
a 10 percent tax rate on the first $18,450 of income, but 15 percent on the next $56,450 (some income is
excluded).26 The rate continues to rise, to up to 39.6 percent on any taxable income over $464,850. These
brackets are somewhat distorted by the range of tax credits, deductions, and incentives the government
offers, but the net effect is that the top income earners pay a greater portion of the overall income tax
burden than do those at the lowest tax brackets. According to the Pew Research Center, based on tax
returns in 2014, 2.7 percent of filers made more than $250,000. Those 2.7 percent of filers paid 52 percent of
the income tax paid.27
Supply-siders, on the other hand, prefer regressive tax systems, which lower the overall rate as individuals
make more money. This does not automatically mean the wealthy pay less than the poor, simply that
the percentage of their income they pay in taxes will be lower. Consider, for example, the use of excise
taxes on specific goods or services as a source of revenue.28 Sometimes called “sin taxes” because they
tend to be applied to goods like alcohol, tobacco, and gasoline, excise taxes have a regressive quality,
since the amount of the good purchased by the consumer, and thus the tax paid, does not increase at the
616 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
same rate as income. A person who makes $250,000 per year is likely to purchase more gasoline than a
person who makes $50,000 per year (Figure 16.19). But the higher earner is not likely to purchase five times
more gasoline, which means the proportion of his or her income paid out in gasoline taxes is less than the
proportion for a lower-earning individual.
Figure 16.19 A gas station shows fuel prices over $3.00 a gallon in 2005, shortly after Hurricane Katrina disrupted
gas production in the Gulf of Mexico. Taxes on gasoline that are based on the quantity purchased are regressive
taxes.
Another example of a regressive tax paid by most U.S. workers is the payroll tax that funds Social Security.
While workers contribute 7.65 percent of their income to pay for Social Security and their employers pay
a matching amount, in 2015, the payroll tax was applied to only the first $118,500 of income. Individuals
who earned more than that, or who made money from other sources like investments, saw their overall
tax rate fall as their income increased.
In 2015, the United States raised about $3.2 trillion in revenue. Income taxes ($1.54 trillion), payroll taxes
on Social Security and Medicare ($1.07 trillion), and excise taxes ($98 billion) make up three of the largest
sources of revenue for the federal government. When combined with corporate income taxes ($344 billion),
these four tax streams make up about 95 percent of total government revenue. The balance of revenue is
split nearly evenly between revenues from the Federal Reserve and a mix of revenues from import tariffs,
estate and gift taxes, and various fees or fines paid to the government (Figure 16.20).
Figure 16.20
Figure 16.21 Investors crowd Wall Street during the Bankers Panic of 1907.
The Federal Reserve System is overseen by a board of governors, known as the Federal Reserve Board.
The president of the United States appoints the seven governors, each of whom serves a fourteen-year
term (the terms are staggered). A chair and vice chair lead the board for terms of four years each. The
most important work of the board is participating in the Federal Open Market Committee to set monetary
policy, like interest rate levels and macroeconomic policy. The board also oversees a network of twelve
regional Federal Reserve Banks, each of which serves as a “banker’s bank” for the country’s financial
institutions.
Insider Perspective
Figure 16.22 Economist Alan Greenspan (a) was chair of the board of governors of the Federal Reserve
System from 1987 to 2006, the second-longest tenure of any chair. Current Fed chair Janet Yellen (b)
succeeded Ben Bernanke in 2014, after serving as vice chair for four years. Prior to serving on the Federal
Reserve Board, Yellen was president and CEO of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.
The Fed, and by extension its chair, have a tremendous responsibility. Many of the economic events of the past
five decades, both good and bad, are the results of Fed policies. In the 1970s, double-digit inflation brought
the economy almost to a halt, but when Paul Volcker became chair in 1979, he raised interest rates and
jump-started the economy. After the stock market crash of 1987, then-chair Alan Greenspan declared, “The
Federal Reserve, consistent with its responsibilities as the nation’s central bank, affirmed today its readiness
to…support the economic and financial system.”30 His lowering of interest rates led to an unprecedented
decade of economic growth through the 1990s. In the 2000s, consistently low interest rates and readily
available credit contributed to the sub-prime mortgage boom and subsequent bust, which led to a global
economic recession beginning in 2008.
Should the important tasks of the Fed continue to be pursued by unelected appointees like those profiled in
this box, or should elected leaders be given the job? Why?
620 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
Link to Learning
Do you think you have what it takes to be chair of the Federal Reserve Board? Play
this game (https://openstaxcollege.org/l/29ChrtheFed) and see how you fare!
Key Terms
bottom-up implementation a strategy in which the federal government allows local areas some
flexibility to meet their specific challenges and needs in implementing policy
Congressional Budget Office the congressional office that scores the spending or revenue impact of all
proposed legislation to assess its net effect on the budget
debt the total amount the government owes across all years
deficit the annual amount by which expenditures are greater than revenues
discretionary spending government spending that Congress must pass legislation to authorize each year
distributive policy a policy that collect payments or resources broadly but concentrates direct benefits
on relatively few
entitlement a program that guarantees benefits to members of a specific group or segment of the
population
free-market economics a school of thought that believes the forces of supply and demand, working
without any government intervention, are the most effective way for markets to operate
Keynesian economics an economic policy based on the idea that economic growth is closely tied to the
ability of individuals to consume goods
laissez-faire an economic policy that assumes the key to economic growth and development is for the
government to allow private markets to operate efficiently without interference
libertarians people who believe that government almost always operates less efficiently than the private
sector and that its actions should be kept to a minimum
mandatory spending government spending earmarked for entitlement programs guaranteeing support
to those who meet certain qualifications
Medicare an entitlement health insurance program for older people and retirees who no longer get
health insurance through their work
policy advocates people who actively work to propose or maintain public policy
policy analysts people who identify all possible choices available to a decision maker and assess the
potential impact of each
progressive tax a tax that tends to increase the effective tax rate as the wealth or income of the tax payer
increases
public policy the broad strategy government uses to do its job; the relatively stable set of purposive
governmental behaviors that address matters of concern to some part of society
recession a temporary contraction of the economy in which there is no economic growth for two
consecutive quarters
622 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
redistributive policy a policy in which costs are born by a relatively small number of groups or
individuals, but benefits are expected to be enjoyed by a different group in society
regressive tax a tax applied at a lower overall rate as individuals’ income rises
regulatory policy a policy that regulates companies and organizations in a way that protects the public
safety net a way to provide for members of society experiencing economic hardship
Social Security a social welfare policy for people who no longer receive an income from employment
supply-side economics an economic policy that assumes economic growth is largely a function of a
country’s productive capacity
top-down implementation a strategy in which the federal government dictates the specifics of public
policy and each state implements it the same exact way
Summary
16.4 Policymakers
The two groups most engaged in making policy are policy advocates and policy analysts. Policy advocates
are people who feel strongly enough about something to work toward changing public policy to fix it.
Policy analysts, on the other hand, aim for impartiality. Their role is to assess potential policies and predict
their outcomes. Although they are in theory unbiased, their findings often reflect specific political leanings.
The public policy process has four major phases: identifying the problem, setting the agenda,
implementing the policy, and evaluating the results. The process is a cycle, because the evaluation stage
should feed back into the earlier stages, informing future decisions about the policy.
Review Questions
1. Which of the following is not an example of a 5. Which type of policy directly benefits the most
public policy outcome? citizens?
a. the creation of a program to combat drug a. regulatory policy
trafficking b. distributive policy
b. the passage of the Affordable Care Act c. redistributive policy
(Obamacare) d. self-regulatory policy
c. the passage of tax cuts during the George
W. Bush administration 6. Of the types of goods introduced in this
d. none of the above; all are public policy section, which do you feel is the most important to
outcomes the public generally and why? Which public
policies are most important and why?
2. Public policy ________.
a. is more of a theory than a reality 7. Social Security and Medicare are notable for
b. is typically made by one branch of their assistance to which group?
government acting alone a. the poor
c. requires multiple actors and branches to b. young families starting out
carry out c. those in urban areas
d. focuses on only a few special individuals d. the elderly
3. What are some of the challenges to getting a 8. Setting aside Social Security and Medicare,
new public policy considered and passed as law? other entitlement programs in the U.S.
government ________.
4. Toll goods differ from public goods in that a. constitute over half the budget
________. b. constitute well under one-quarter of the
a. they provide special access to some and not budget
all c. are paid for by the states with no cost to the
b. they require the payment of a fee up front Federal government
c. they provide a service for only the wealthy d. none of the above
d. they are free and available to all
624 Chapter 16 | Domestic Policy
9. What societal ills are social welfare programs 13. A deficit is ________.
designed to address? a. the overall amount owed by government
for past borrowing
10. Which stage of the public policy process b. the annual budget shortfall between
includes identification of problems in need of revenues and expenditures
fixing? c. the cancellation of an entitlement program
a. agenda setting d. all the above
b. enactment
c. implementation 14. Entitlement (or mandatory) spending is
d. evaluation ________.
a. formula-based spending that goes to
11. Policy analysts seek ________. individual citizens
a. evidence b. a program of contracts to aerospace
b. their chosen outputs companies
c. influence c. focused on children
d. money d. concentrated on education
12. In the implementation phase of the policy 15. When times are tough economically, what can
process, is it better to use a top-down approach or the government do to get the economy moving
a bottom-up approach on Federal policies? Why? again?
16. What might indicate that a government is passing the policies the country needs?
17. If you had to define the poverty line, what would you expect people to be able to afford just above that
line? For those below that line, what programs should the government offer to improve quality of life?
18. What is the proper role of the government in regulating the private sector so people are protected
from unfair or dangerous business practices? Why?
19. Is it realistic to expect the U.S. government to balance its budget? Why or why not?
20. What in your view is the most important policy issue facing the United States? Why is it important
and which specific problems need to be solved?
21. What are some suggested solutions to the anticipated Social Security shortfall? Why haven’t these
solutions tended to gain support?
22. Whose role is more important in a democracy, the policy advocate’s or the policy analyst’s? Why?
23. Which stage of the policy progress is the most important and why?
Alesina, Alberto and Howard Rosenthal. 1995. Partisan Politics, Divided Government and the Economy. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Baumgartner, Frank R. and Bryan D. Jones. 1993. Agendas and Instability in American Politics. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Birkland, Thomas A. 1997. After Disaster: Agenda Setting, Public Policy, and Focusing Events. Washington,
DC: Georgetown University Press.
Glick, Henry R. 1992. The Right to Die: Policy Innovation and Its Consequences. New York: Columbia
University Press.
Guell, Robert. 2014. Issues in Economics Today, 7th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill Education.
Keech, William R. 1995. Economic Politics: The Costs of Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Kingdon, John W. 1995. Agendas, Alternatives and Public Policies, 2nd ed. New York: HarperCollins.
Lowi, Theodore J. 1969. The End of Liberalism: Ideology, Policy, and the Crisis of Public Authority. New York:
W.W. Norton.
Pierson, Paul. 2004. Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Riker, William H. 1986. The Art of Political Manipulation. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Robertson, David B. and Dennis R. Judd. 1989. The Development of American Public Policy: The Structure of
Policy Restraint. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman.
Rochefort, David A. and Roger W. Cobb. 1994. The Politics of Problem Definition: Shaping the Policy Agenda.
Lawrence, KS: University Press of Kansas.
Sabatier, Paul A. 1999. Theories of the Policy Process. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.