Hendrick 2004
Hendrick 2004
1177/1078087404268076
Hendrick / FISCAL HEALTHURBAN
IN CHICAGO
AFFAIRS REVIEW / September 2004
This study presents a framework for assessing the financial condition and fiscal health of munici-
pal governments, develops indices for some dimensions of the framework, and applies the indi-
ces to 264 suburban municipalities in the Chicago metropolitan region. The framework is based
on a systems view of local government financial condition. It shows that fiscal health is a com-
plex and multidimensional concept with varying time frames. Furthermore, the dimensions are
related but often in indirect or nonlinear ways, indicating they must be measured separately
rather than combined into a comprehensive indicator of fiscal health. Indices developed here for
targeted dimensions of the framework are assessed and compared to alternative indicators of
fiscal health developed by others in the field.
Since the 1960s, urban municipal governments have faced cycles of fiscal
boom and bust that have produced wide fluctuations in their financial condi-
tion. In the 1960s and early 1970s, municipal revenues grew significantly
from both local sources and federal aid. This picture changed considerably
by the late 1970s as the flow of federal money ceased, the economy moved
into a deep recession, inflation soared, and citizen opposition to further taxa-
tion increased. In conjunction, the movement of population and businesses
from the central cities to the suburbs beginning in the 1950s drained central
cities’ revenue base and increased service demands in small suburban gov-
ernments that often were ill equipped to provide additional services. This
78
pattern was later repeated in suburbs near the central city as people and enter-
prises migrated to suburbs farther away. Although fiscal pressures stabilized
for most urban governments by the late 1980s (Bowman, MacManus, and
Mikesell 1992), the early 1990 recession lengthened the period of fiscal
stress for many until the mid-1990s when economic conditions improved
dramatically and local tax revenues increased faster than spending. However,
conditions have reversed once again for local governments since 2001 with
the precipitous decline of the stock market and accompanying recession that
have reduced state-shared and nonproperty tax revenues (Pagano and Hoene
2003).
The fiscal pressures faced by central cities in the late 1970s and early
1980s spawned numerous efforts across disciplines and organizations to
assess local government fiscal health and financial performance and, in some
cases, to develop indices of these conditions. Economists working in this area
primarily targeted environmental factors directly affecting revenues and
expenditures (Ladd and Yinger 1989; Bahl 1984; Advisory Commission on
Intergovernmental Relations [ACIR] 1971, 1979). Studies from political sci-
ence and sociology included some of these variables but added others focus-
ing on politics, demographics, and intergovernmental relations (e.g., politi-
cal culture, voting preferences, and state statutes) (Clark and Ferguson 1983;
Nathan and Adams 1976). Studies from public administration placed more
emphasis on governments’ finances and other aspects of their fiscal structure
over which officials have more control, such as operating position (e.g.,
liquidity), debt, and revenue and expenditure trends (Aronson and King
1978; Groves, Valente, and Shulman 1981; Brown 1993). Also during this
period, many governmental and nonprofit organizations commissioned stud-
ies of fiscal stress and financial condition for their specific needs (e.g., invest-
ment ratings and distribution of aid). (Burchell et al. [1981], Aronson [1984],
and Ross and Greenfield [1980] summarize and critique many measures
from this time period. Honadle and Lloyd-Jones [1998] compare measures
from public administration.)
Almost 20 years have passed since this body of research was completed,
and much has changed in that time that is relevant to assessing local govern-
ment financial conditions. Local governments have new sources of fiscal
stress, including tax limitations and unfunded mandates, and their fiscal
structure has become more complex and diversified (Sbragia 1996; Bahl
1996). In addition, there are many more suburban governments, and more
people live in suburbs than central cities or rural areas than in the past
(Ruchelman 1996).1 Most of the early measures of fiscal health were devel-
oped for larger, central cities rather than smaller, suburban municipalities,
The research presented here defines fiscal health very generally as the
ability of government to meet its financial and service obligations. It pro-
poses different dimensions of factors that affect fiscal health to varying levels
or degrees, and it recognizes that changes to fiscal health within these dimen-
sions occur in different time frames. Fiscal health measures based on this
approach will be useful to external groups and other financial stakeholders in
assessing the status of local government fiscal health and, more generally,
nomic, demographic, political features (IC) that determine fiscal wealth and
spending needs. Properties of the government’s fiscal structure include con-
ditions or policies that can develop over time in response to the fiscal environ-
ment (e.g., increasing reliance on sales taxes) or choices made in the short run
to accommodate more immediate problems (e.g., raising property taxes this
year or cutting back on purchasing). 2
In addition to revenues and spending levels, a government’s fiscal struc-
ture includes other features that can be characterized in different dimensions
with varying time frames. Fiscal slack (IIIA) represents the government’s
ability to buffer against environmental threats and uncertainty over a practi-
cal time period (Cyert and March 1963). Fiscal slack can be defined literally
as surplus resources, such as high fund balances. More generally, it is any
structural feature that increases a government’s financial options and flexi-
bility in managing risk and uncertainty, such as a diversified revenue struc-
ture or a higher level of discretionary spending in the budget. Relativity of
components (IIIB), another dimension of fiscal structure, is not really an
indicator of health as much as it modifies other conditions. For instance, high
dependence on sales tax revenue creates more risk for government due to the
greater volatility of sales receipts (sales tax revenue base) and thus a greater
need for higher levels of slack than a government more dependent on
property taxes.
Financial managers also recognize very short-term conditions of fiscal
health (IIIC), usually related to a government’s operating position. Measures
of this dimension focus primarily on cash flow and whether the government
can generate enough cash during the fiscal year to pay its bills on time. Oper-
ating deficits and liquidity (cash/liabilities) rates are examples of indicators
of very short-term fiscal health, in contrast to indicators of midterm fiscal
health. Measures of midterm fiscal health, which include indicators of slack
and risk, examine a government’s ability to meet budgetary obligations over
a few years and focus on features that facilitate or hinder its adaptation to fis-
cal shocks or declines.3 Another governmental dimension of fiscal health
reflects the degree to which current financial decisions have obligated future
resources (IIID). Although this dimension represents long-term fiscal health,
it is qualitatively different from the environmental dimensions because gov-
ernment controls these obligations. In this case, the decision to issue more
bonds or slow pension contributions are choices that reduce future slack
rather than increase future spending needs. Future debt and pension spending
needs are a function of interest rates, an uncontrollable feature of the envir-
onment, that determine the cost of debt and the return on pension investments.
Measures of balance or adaptation (II), which is another midterm measure
of fiscal health, assess how well government’s fiscal structure, over which
for poor communities than wealthy ones but less threatening to both types of
governments than reductions in sales receipts or property values.
Although measures of fiscal health and conditions are likely to be related
across dimensions, the examples above demonstrate these dimensions may
vary independently or in nonlinear ways. A government with high environ-
mental stress (low property and residential wealth with high spending needs)
is more likely to have low slack, high future obligations, and more difficulty
meeting payroll. Similarly, it will be easier for a government with low envi-
ronmental stress to maintain adequate slack, maintain a solvent budget, and
meet short-term obligations. But these outcomes are not always certain. A
government with high environmental stress that is well managed and has a
history of sound fiscal decisions may find it difficult but not impossible to
have a good budgetary position and short-term solvency, although maintain-
ing short-term fiscal health will be more difficult. Likewise, a government
with low environmental stress may experience more budgetary stress, lower
slack, and more short-term insolvency if it is poorly managed and has a his-
tory of unsound fiscal practices, although it will have more options for raising
revenue or reducing spending than governments in less wealthy or more
needy environments. Thus, municipalities with high levels of stress on one
dimension may not necessarily have high or low levels of stress on other
dimensions, although they are more likely to have high levels of stress across
dimensions, and, over time, stress in one area may lead to stress in other
areas. To complicate matters further, interpretation of conditions in one area
may depend on conditions in another area, such as whether the level of slack
is appropriate to the level of risk in the fiscal structure and volatility of the
environment. The complexity and indirect nature of the relationships
between dimensions make it difficult to construct one, comprehensive indi-
cator of fiscal health or financial condition. Rather, measures of these dimen-
sions should be constructed separately and assessed in relation to one another
to produce a complete and more accurate picture of fiscal conditions.
This study focuses its analyses on four dimensions in Table 1: revenue
wealth (IA), spending needs (IB), fiscal balance (II), and fiscal slack (IIIA).
Table 2 presents a summary of the most widely cited recent and past fiscal
health indicators and comments on how they compare to the set of dimen-
sions and system of measurement proposed here. Table 2 also comments on
other qualities of the indicators, including their applicability to local govern-
ments in other states or suburban governments and their appropriateness for
broad-based monitoring of local conditions. Although some indicators in
Table 2 produce very good measures of dimensions IA, IB, and II, not all
are appropriate for suburban governments or can be adapted easily to local
governments in other states. Many indicators also combine dimensions, and
(text continued on page 90)
A) Nathan and Adams (1976): Intercity Hardship IC Unemployment, dependency of population, educa-
Index (Brookings) tion, income, crowded housing, poverty
B) Congressional Budget Office (1978): Urban IA, IB, IC, ID (1) Social need: unemployment, per cap income (2)
Need Index Economic need: employment change, population
change, per capita income change, density, pre-
1940 house (3) Fiscal need: tax effort, property tax
base, service needs index composed of community
need index, tax effort, and property tax base
C) U.S. Department of the Treasury (1978): urban IIIE Average change in weighted variables: population,
fiscal strain per capita income, own-source revenue burden,
long-term debt per capita, property value (full
market); revenue burden = own-source revenues
per capita
D) Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental II, IIIE Tax effort and change in tax effort, as a percentage of
Relations (ACIR) (1979) fiscal blood pressure median; tax effort = own-source taxes/personal
income
E) Howell and Stamm (1979): urban fiscal crisis All of I, II, IIIA, IIIC (1) Economic: change – population, single-family
(Touche, Ross & Co. and First National Bank, housing starts, manufacture-unemployment ratio,
Boston) manufacture capital spend; family income, manu-
(continued)
87
88
TABLE 2 (continued)
A) Nathan and Adams (1976): Intercity Hardship Standardize, then average all variables Limited to one dimension. Data are easily available.
Index (Brookings)
B) Congressional Budget Office (1978): Urban Community index constructed from fac- Most variables are easily available if state govern-
Need Index tor analysis of 20 variables represent- ment collects tax base information, but the index is
ing age of population and infrastruc- extremely complex and double counts some vari-
ture, poverty, race, crime, and so on. ables or constructs. Merges change dimension
Standardize variables as index and with others.
average all variables in each
dimension.
C) U.S. Department of the Treasury (1978): urban Sum of weighted z values Reliance on per capita distorts suburban conditions.
fiscal strain Weights are somewhat arbitrary. Limited to
change.
D) ACIR (1979) fiscal blood pressure Establishes a 2 × 2 table (4 categories) of Four categories are gross indicator only. Consider
fiscal blood pressure at a cutoff of 100 change directly. Income is only tax base and mea-
for both variables, or retain as ratio of sure not easily adjusted to other bases.
static/dynamic
E) Howell and Stamm (1979): urban fiscal crisis Maps average of all financial perfor- Similar dimensions as proposed here and recognize
(Touche, Ross & Co. and First National Bank, mance variables on 16 categories of nonlinearity between dimensions. However, not
Boston) fiscal condition defined by economic, summarize as indicators within dimensions. Most
social, and structural variables economic variables are not available. Reliance on
others have unreasonable data and calculation requirements that limit their
use by external organizations for monitoring purposes. For this reason, new
measures of these dimensions are explored here.
The next section discusses characteristics of the municipalities in the Chi-
cago region and the fiscal data used here. Subsequent sections identify the
measures, show how they are calculated, and evaluate their validity by ex-
amining their associations with other dimensions and comparing them to
selected indicators in Table 2.
MUNICIPALITIES IN THE
CHICAGO REGION AND FISCAL DATA
1980s, large areas of an outer ring, beginning about 35 miles from Chicago,
were beginning to develop heavily and encompass the region’s four, larger
satellite cities: Elgin, Aurora, Waukegan, and Joliet. As development in-
creased in the middle and outer rings, many suburbs in the inner ring declined
economically and looked more like depressed areas of the inner city. How-
ever, the pattern of development and decline in the Chicago region and
around the city was not uniform. Residential development and new centers of
employment tended to concentrate in the north and northwest suburbs of the
middle and outer ring, but many inner-ring suburbs to the north retained their
White, wealthy, and professional residents. In contrast, many inner- and
middle-ring suburbs south of Chicago, and many suburbs in the near south-
west and west sides, have become poorer, less White, and more blue-collar
(Orfield 2002).
Data used to measure the fiscal health variables are from two primary
sources. Socioeconomic and demographic data were obtained from the 1990
and 2000 U.S. census. Financial data were obtained from the Illinois Comp-
troller’s Office (IOC) and the Illinois Department of Revenue. At the end of
each fiscal year, all governments issue an annual financial report that con-
tains their primary balance sheets and statements of revenues, expenditures,
and expenses. All local governments in the state of Illinois are required to
report much of this information to the IOC every year. All financial data were
averaged for the years 1997 to 2000 to reduce measurement error and the
incompatibilities associated with variation in accounting practices among
the suburbs. Given that 18% of the governments in this region may still prac-
tice cash accounting, the most important source of such variation is cash ver-
sus accrual accounting. Averaging eliminates the effects of these timing dif-
ferences and reduces the impact of unique events that may dramatically affect
revenues or expenditures in the short run.5 Finally, unless indicated other-
wise, all measures of fiscal structure, such as revenues and fund balances,
include all governmental funds (general, debt service, special revenue, and
capital funds where indicated) and do not include proprietary funds (enter-
prise and fiduciary/pension).
I) Environment
1 Alsip Cook 80.3 163.1 82.4 –0.516 63 96.9 92.6 94.2 0 –0.305 99 –36 85
2 Arlington Heights Cook 130.5 232.2 137.0 0.156 188 103.1 78.6 74.9 0 –0.44 75 113 193
3 Barrington Cook 172.0 170.5 444.4 1.523 247 118.8 81.8 110.4 0 –0.12 126 121 200
4 Barrington Hills Cook 284.2 19.7 19.3 1.412 245 106.3 60.1 242.8 1 –0.28 102 143 219
a
(K ) Balance:
Weighted (M) (Na) (P) Expenditure/
a
Own-Source (La) Revemue/ Weighted (O ) Expenditure/ Need –
Municipality Revenue Wealth Total Wealth (M2) Expenditures Need Total Need P2 Revenue/
Number Municipality County per Capita Order bA + bB +bC (K/L) Order per Capita Order bE + bF + bG + bH (N/O) Order Wealth(P2 – M2) Order
II) Balance
1 Alsip Cook 62.2 33 81.9 0.76 69 69.6 48 94.4 0.74 43 –26 99
2 Arlington Heights Cook 112.1 158 133.5 0.84 90 106.0 149 85.8 1.24 136 46 174
3 Barrington Cook 199.4 242 308.0 0.65 39 186.2 235 100.8 1.85 208 169 237
4 Barrington Hills Cook 248.7 250 186.0 1.34 197 205.5 241 85.1 2.41 222 25 150
Slack:
a a a
(Qa) (R ) (S ) (T ) Average of %
Municipality % Fund % Capital % Enterprise % Debt % Median Residential
Number Municipality County Balance Expenditures Fund Service Q, mR, mS (100 – T)a Order Home Rule EAV Order Population
NOTE: EAV = equalized assessed value; z = z value; b = standardized regression slope; m = % of median for all cases. All rank orders are presented as ascending.
a. Presented as % of median value for all cases.
b. Presented as Z value.
93
94 URBAN AFFAIRS REVIEW / September 2004
municipalities.6 This section discusses each of the indicators, and the follow-
ing section evaluates the indicators relative to other measures of fiscal health
and demonstrates their use through mapping.
ENVIRONMENTAL INDICATORS:
REVENUE WEALTH AND SPENDING NEEDS
separately for home rule (R2 = .61) and non–home rule (R2 = .58) municipali-
ties. Using a different set of slopes to construct the wealth measure for home
rule and non–home rule governments recognizes their different opportunities
to collect taxes. As indicated in Appendix A, EAV and sales are more impor-
tant to non–home rule governments, and personal income is more important
to home rule municipalities. Although it may seem contrary to expectations,
the low slope for EAV and high slope for income per capita in home rule gov-
ernments may reflect their larger size and greater access to a broader range of
taxes and revenues than non–home rule governments. Thus, EAV taxes may
be less important to home rule governments because of expanded revenue
opportunities and greater capacity to collect revenue.
The spending needs measure is constructed from four variables: median
age of housing, weighted crime rate per capita (percentage residential), pop-
ulation density (population/square miles), and whether a municipality is in a
fire district. Measures of spending needs developed in prior research for
larger and central cities target many more factors, such as age of the popula-
tion, poverty, and employment, that may not be relevant to suburban govern-
ments that do not provide extensive social or health services (Ladd and
Yinger 1989; Rafuse and Marks 1991). In this case, prior analyses of spend-
ing in the Chicago suburbs indicate that age of housing and crime rate have a
significant effect on expenditures, whereas other variables such as age of the
population and poverty have no effect. Past studies have shown crime rate to
be a good general indicator of public safety expenditures (e.g., police, fire,
and inspection), and age of housing is often used to measure infrastructure
and public works maintenance needs (Clark and Ferguson 1983).7 Popula-
tion density measures the economies of scale for service delivery: The more
people per square mile, the less costly to deliver services (Berne and Schram
1986).8 Finally, municipalities that are in a fire district will have substantially
reduced spending needs for salaries, equipment, and pension obligations.
Similar to the wealth index, the spending need index was created by con-
verting the four component variables into z values, weighting them with stan-
dardized regression slopes (weighted expenditures per capita as the depend-
ent variable), and them summing the weighted values. Because demand for
services is such a big factor in determining actual spending in communities,
regardless of their needs, income per capita was included in the regression
equation as a measure of demand for services (R2 = .53). Using income per
capita as a measure of demand is well documented in the fiscal stress litera-
ture (Ladd and Yinger 1989; Clark and Ferguson 1983).
The composite index of environmental fiscal health was created by sub-
tracting the rank order of each municipality on the need index from the rank
order of each municipality on the wealth index. The reason for using rank
orders rather than the z values is to remove the distributional effects associ-
ated with extreme values and outliers in either the wealth or need index but
not the other. Measures of fiscal health for municipalities with this condition
can be highly distorted by a composite index using z values, which was dem-
onstrated from the obvious misplacement of some municipalities in the bot-
tom and top 15% of the scale.9 Using “sophisticated” ordinal scaling (rank
orders) rather than interval scaling (z values), in effect, relaxes assumptions
about the measurement precision of the component variables in the final
index, which may be prudent under these circumstances.
FISCAL STRUCTURE:
SLACK
balance the budget during times of fiscal stress (Bahl 1984; Gold 1986). This
variable is calculated as a percentage of total minus capital expenditures.
Enterprise funds are another source of slack in a government’s budget,
although their use in managing fiscal stress is more indirect than unreserved
fund balances. Within the Chicago region, 88% of municipalities have enter-
prise funds dedicated primarily to water and sewerage. Although provision
of water and sewerage increases municipal spending burdens, it also pro-
vides opportunities for municipalities to share revenues and costs with a sep-
arate set of funds that are less visible to public scrutiny. Extensive interviews
with financial officials in the region indicate the importance of these funds as
an indirect source of slack (e.g., charging a larger portion of public works sal-
aries to the water and sewer fund during fiscal stress). Percentage enterprise
fund is measured as enterprise income as a percentage of enterprise income
plus own-source revenues.
Another slack measure is percentage capital expenditures of total expen-
ditures. The practice of increasing capital expenditures during good times
and decreasing them during bad times is well known (Levine, Rubin, and
Wolohojian 1981). This is especially true for municipalities that use pay-as-
you-go financing of capital items. Alternatively, a high percentage of debt
service expenditures represent fixed, nondiscretionary spending that reduces
slack. In this case, percentage debt service must be reversed by subtract-
ing the value from 100 to accommodate the order of the other three slack
indicators.
All four slack variables are measured as a percentage of their median and
then averaged to form the composite index of fiscal slack. Although no
weights were given to the component variables, this should be explored in
future research given that their contribution to adaptation or fiscal perfor-
mance may vary. However, this task will require a better understanding of the
role of slack in governments’ fiscal affairs and the potentially complex rela-
tionship of slack to other dimensions of fiscal health, especially current oper-
ating conditions (Table 3IIIC) and change (Table 3ID and 3IIIE).
An additional important source of slack that is well documented, but not
included here due to its nonlinear relationship with the other variables, is
organizational size. Although size is often recognized in organizational and
managerial theories as an element of slack, it can be defined in numerous
ways (e.g., population, municipal employment, or value of budget). Larger
organizations have more horizontal and vertical linkages that increase offi-
cials’ options and opportunities for managing their environment and struc-
ture (Thompson 1967). The greater volume of activities in larger govern-
ments also increases their capacity to share or trade off among activities,
which gives them more flexibility than small governments (Mattson 1994;
Median G) %
% RTS % Median Weighted
Municipality Wealth Total % Median F) Revenue Capacity Ressidential Sales Receipts
Number Municipality County bzA + bzB + bzC Order Clark City Wealth Order per Capita Order EAV Order per Capita Population
Environmental
Health: Brookings B) CBO B) CBO
Municipality Need Total Wealth – Need Hardship Reverse Social Reverse Economic
Number Municipality County bzE + bzF + bzG + bzH Order (D2 – I2) Order Index Order Need Order Need Order Population
NOTE: RTS = representative tax system; EAV = equalized assessed value; CBO = Congressional Budget Office. All rank orders are presented as ascending.
Hendrick / FISCAL HEALTH IN CHICAGO 101
Buffalo Grove. The indices RW, CCW, and BH all show Alsip to be relatively
poor, but it has had moderate increases in population and employment
between 1995 and 2000. This situation accounts for its moderate ranking for
the CBO-EN measure and distinguishes it from other municipalities that are
both poor and have had recent declines in revenue wealth and underlying
economic conditions. In contrast, Buffalo Grove has the opposite problem. It
is a very wealthy community (RW rank = 206) that has experienced recent
declines in revenue wealth and economic conditions.
The bottom portion of Table 4 (II) shows three balance measures for reve-
nue. These measures are the revenue burden index proposed here (RWW),
Clark’s revenue effort (CRE) measure, and the RTS revenue effort (RTS-RE)
measure. These indicators are correlated highly but demonstrate key differ-
ences, which are related to differences already discussed with the RW indi-
ces.15 In this case, not correcting for per capita distortions only enhances the
distortions in the ratio calculations. Thus, the RTS-RE index will be higher
than the RWW index but lower than the CRE index for municipalities with
lower levels of residential properties such as Alsip, Bridgeview, and Coun-
tryside. The opposite situation exists for a municipality such as Barrington
Hills, which is a very wealthy residential community with a five-acre mini-
mum lot size and therefore very low EAV per square mile. In this case, the
RWW index shows Barrington Hills placing a lot of revenue burden on its
residents, in comparison to the RTS-RE index, which shows that residents
have far less revenue burden.
With respect to the slack index, one way to demonstrate this measure’s
performance is to examine correlations of this variable with other variables to
see if the values are in the expected direction. Table 5 demonstrates how well
the wealth, need, and balance indices predict slack in the municipalities. As
expected, slack is higher in municipalities that are wealthier, have higher
spending needs, and are better balanced. Given that slack also improves flexi-
bility and coping ability, one would expect that governments needing less
flexibility and coping opportunities to have less slack built into their budget.
This is supported by the correlations showing that home rule and larger gov-
ernments, and those with more revenue diversification and greater depend-
ence on property taxes, have less slack. The correlations also show that the
CWW, CRE, and RTS-RE indices are related in the expected direction but
demonstrate a problem with the alternative indicators of fiscal health. Specif-
ically, the uncorrected per capita values create more extreme outliers in the
distributions for these indices, which produce less stable correlations (i.e.,
the correlations change greatly as outliers are removed).
To demonstrate how suburbs cluster according to the three primary fiscal
health indices, three different maps of the Chicago suburbs also are pre-
sented. In all cases, the suburbs are grouped into quartiles on the relevant
index. Figure 1 presents the map of the index for environmental health. Fig-
ure 2 presents a map of the primary balance index. Both figures show the
extent to which a government’s balance with the environment is limited by
external conditions but not completely determined by them. Thus, a suburb’s
ability to adapt to its environment in a positive way depends strongly on the
opportunities and demands it faces, and there may be little that an extremely
poor and needy suburb can do to improve financial performance; some
municipalities with poor environmental health adjust better than others do.
Although these two maps display some similarities to the map of tax
capacity for Chicago suburbs presented by Orfield (2002, map 1-27), there
are some distinct differences. Both sets of maps show the impoverished sub-
urbs south of Chicago and the wealthy suburbs to the north and northwest.
However, Figures 1 and 2 show a distinct band of wealthy/low need and well-
balanced suburbs surrounding the inner-ring suburbs to the west and on the
near southwest side. Also, environmental heath is shown to be worse and fis-
cal balance more precarious for the outer-ring suburbs that are composed of
satellite cities and low-density, rural suburbs. The primary difference
between Orfield’s maps and those presented here is that Orfield’s measure
of tax capacity focuses on property tax (weighted according to other tax
CONCLUSION
long-term fiscal health and more short-term operating functions. Some rela-
tionships in this area are fairly obvious. For instance, revenue deficits, which
are a feature of current operating position (Table 3IIIC), obviously reduce
slack in the short run and are likely to threaten budgetary solvency over time.
More serious problems with fiscal structure or long-term solvency also make
revenue deficits and budgetary insolvency more likely, but these effects and
their relationship to other areas of midterm fiscal health are less well
understood.
Particularly critical for measuring fiscal health is to determine how the
different dimensions of slack are related to one another, which requires a
broader understanding of the impact of slack on overall fiscal performance.
For the most part, economists and political scientists have overlooked this
aspect of financial condition and how it fits into the dynamics of govern-
ments’ financial activities, in both the long run and short run. As such, much
improvement could be made to developing measures of slack and exploring
its role in budgetary and other levels of solvency. Including a measure of size
of government in slack is one option discussed previously, but there are many
ways of measuring size, and its relationship to other dimensions or compo-
nents of slack is highly contingent. With respect to overall financial health,
fiscal slack will have to be assessed relative to other dimensions, especially
risk and other areas of fiscal structure.
Risk and current operating position are two other areas requiring more
research on measurement and their impact on financial performance, but
there is already much research in public accounting and on debt from various
disciplines that address relevant questions on these topics. More problematic
and less well understood are the dimensions of environmental and structural
change, especially how and when particular changes affect fiscal health.
These relationships can be particularly complex and nonlinear. For instance,
it is generally recognized by research and financial officials that population
change signals and improves fiscal health, but rapidly developing municipal-
ities face a host of different problems, opportunities, and constraints than do
nondeveloping ones. Little is known about how population change affects
municipal fiscal health relative to conditions in the other dimensions.
Although the research presented here does not offer a complete set of
measures of fiscal health, it does provide a useful starting point for future
research. Remembering that the purpose of developing such measures is to
allow policy makers and financial stakeholders to evaluate the fiscal health
and financial condition of a wide range of governments, future research will
have to link indicators to outcomes in a manner that is useful to them. This
will require future discussions and analyses of the properties of balance and
adaptation, such as stability or sustainability, in the context of financial per-
APPENDIX A
Operationalization of Fiscal Indicators
Most financial variables are calculated as an average for the years from 1997 to 2000,
corrected for inflation, and (unless indicated otherwise) represent totals for all gov-
ernmental funds that include general, special revenue, debt, capital, and expendable
trust. Governmental funds do not include enterprise funds. Sales taxes include home
rule sales taxes plus state-shred sales taxes because they are distributed based on point
of sale. Equalized assessed value (EAV) is corrected for the underassessment of resi-
dential and commercial properties in Cook County. The source for most of the finan-
cial data is the Illinois Office of the Comptroller (IOC). Other financial data were ob-
tained from the Illinois Department of Revenue (IDOR). Socioeconomic and demo-
graphic data are from the U.S. Census Bureau (1990, 2000). Population figures for
1997-2000 that are used in the per capita calculations are extrapolated from census
figures for 1990 and 2000.
ro = rank order
rate of change = (t – (t – 1)/(t – 1))
z = z value transformation
m = value presented as a percentage of its median
b1i = standardized slope of regression equation with weighted own-source reve-
nues per capita as dependent variable; home rule governments only
b2i = standardized slope of regression equation with weighted own-source reve-
nues per capita as dependent variable; non–home rule governments only
b3i = standardized slope of regression equation with weighted (total expenditures –
capital expenditures) per capita as dependent variable
TOSR (total own source revenue) = property tax + sales tax + other tax + nontax
OTHER INDICATORS
APPENDIX B
Descriptive Information for All Variables
Mean Median Minimum Maximum SD
A) External environmental
conditions
Income per capita 29,712 25,031 7,818 97,999 15,163
Sales receipts per capita 16,813 9,477 46 574,583 39,397
Equalized assessed value
(EAV) per square mile
(100s) 55,524 45,381 521 230,240 40,413
Crime per 1,000 population 41.2 28.3 3.95 1057 74.0
Median age housing 1,969.4 1,971 1,939 1,997 13.0
Density 3,204 2,747 24.8 15,378 2,495
Fire district 0 = 141 1 = 118 (45%)
(continued)
APPENDIX B (continued)
Mean Median Minimum Maximum SD
B) Fiscal balance
Expenditures per capita 837.3 583.1 45.2 24,040 1,856
Own-source revenue per cap 722.2 499.2 34.8 21,917 1,649
C) Internal conditions: slack
% fund balance 75.9 58.5 –92.5 609.7 –92.5
% enterprise revenue 23.6 24.4 00 70.0 13.9
% debt service 9.0 8.0 00 39.4 7.5
% capital expenditures 8.0 7.2 00 38.3 5.9
D) Other indicators
Population 17,623 10,653 106 142,990 20,850
% change population 33.9 10.1 –97.5 1,489 107.8
% White population 80.9 89.4 1.77 99.3 22.2
% managerial and professional 35.6 34.1 7.97 70.4 14.1
% owner-occupied housing 36.2 35.9 20.9 53.8 4.9
% residential EAV 70.0 72.6 3.4 100.0 19.7
Home rule 0 = 165 1 = 96 (37%)
% property tax 32.7 33.3 00 74.8 15.5
% sales tax 24.2 21.8 00 84.6 15.6
% intergovernmental 20.3 18.6 1.0 64.6 9.0
Revenue diversification 0.86 0.88 0.28 0.997 0.11
NOTES
1. A U.S. Census Bureau (1999) Internet release for 1999 shows that 52% of total family
households in the United States are located in suburban areas compared to nonmetropolitan areas
or central cities.
2. Another important environmental factor that could be represented as a separate dimension
is service demands, which are a function of stakeholder preferences rather than a component of
need.
3. Municipal governments often reserve three months of spending in their fund balance to
maintain good cash flow in the short run and use the remaining portion of the fund balance as a
more long-term rainy-day fund.
4. Non–home rule municipalities may not increase property taxes more than the lesser of 5%
or the rate of inflation.
5. Discussions with financial managers and auditors in the region indicate that major timing
differences in accounting for revenues and expenditures disappear over a three- to five-year
period. Although each year of financial data is corrected for inflation using the Chicago con-
sumer price index, the correction has no effect on the relative values of the measures among
municipalities. Thus, regression slopes, z values, and percentage median values will be the same
for inflation-corrected and uncorrected variables.
6. A complete list of the indicators for all municipalities in the Chicago region is available
from the author upon request.
7. Unfortunately, the crime variable reduces the number of cases from 264 to 241 because
some municipalities do not have their own police. These municipalities rely on the county to pro-
vide police services, and separate crime statistics are not reported for them. Most of these munic-
ipalities have populations less than 1,000 and are in Lake County.
8. Another variable that should be included here is miles of roads given suburbs’ responsi-
bilities in this service area and its high cost. However, this information is not available centrally,
which makes obtaining these data over time almost impossible. Median age of housing and den-
sity may measure some of the attributes of public works spending needs, but not all.
9. Correlations of the external health index calculated with z values versus rank orders with
various fiscal structural features, such as dependence on property tax and intergovernmental rev-
enue, show little difference between the two indices.
10. One means of maintaining consistency in the method of standardization across all vari-
ables is to use percentage of median rather than z values to construct the environmental fiscal
health index. However, correlations of the two forms of the wealth and need indices with other
indicators of wealth and fiscal structure, and the use of both forms in analyses in other research
projects, demonstrate that z values are better indicators of environmental fiscal health than are the
median values.
11. Correlations between unreserved fund balance and the other three slack variables range
between .2 and .3. However, there is little association among these other three variables.
12. Clark’s functional performance index cannot be calculated meaningfully with the Illi-
nois Comptroller’s Office (IOC) spending data because the IOC spending categories are too
aggregate.
13. Pearson’s r: revenue wealth (RW) and Clark city wealth (CCW) = .55; RW and represen-
tative tax system revenue capacity (RTS-RC) = .84; CCW and RTS-RC = .77.
14. Pearson’s r: environmental health (EH) and Brookings hardship (BH) = .77; EH and so-
cial need component of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO-SN) = .72; BH and CBO-SN = .95.
15. Clark’s revenue effort (CRE) = own-source revenues per capita/city wealth. Pearson r:
revenue burden index proposed here (RWW) and CRE = .74; RWW and RTS revenue effort
(RTS-RE) = .86; CRE and RTS-RE = .86, after removing eight outliers.
16. Space does not permit a detailed discussion of municipalities with relatively low levels of
environmental health and relatively good balance and/or high slack.
REFERENCES
Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations. 1971. Measuring the fiscal capacity and
effort of state and local areas. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
. 1979. Measuring the fiscal blood pressure of the states: 1964-1975. Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.
. 1981. Measuring local discretionary authority. Washington, DC: Government Printing
Office.
. 1988. State fiscal capacity and effort. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
. 1989. Local revenue diversification: Local sales taxes. Washington, DC: Government
Printing Office.
Aronson, J. R. 1984. Municipal fiscal indicators. In Crisis and constraint in municipal finance:
Local fiscal prospects in a period of uncertainty, edited by J. Carr, 3-53. New Brunswick, NJ:
Center for Urban Policy Research.
Aronson, J. R., and A. E. King. 1978. Is there a fiscal crisis outside of New York? National Tax
Journal 31 (2): 135-55.
Bahl, R. W. 1984. Financing state and local government in the 1980’s. New York: Oxford Univ.
Press.
. 1996. Local government expenditures and revenues. In Management policies in local
government finance, 4th ed., edited by J. R. Aronson and E. Schwartz, 77-95. Washington,
DC: International City Managers Association.
Baum, J. C. 1996. Organizational ecology. In Handbook of organization studies, edited by
S. Clegg, C. Hardy, and W. Nord, 57-76. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Berne, R., and R. Schramm. 1986. The financial analysis of governments. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice Hall.
Bowman, J., S. MacManus, and J. Mikesell. 1992. Mobilizing resources for public services:
Financing urban governments. Journal of Urban Affairs 14 (3/4): 311-35.
Brown, K. W. 1993. The 10-point test of financial condition: Toward an easy-to-use assessment
tool for smaller governments. Government Finance Review 9 (1): 21-25.
Bunce, H. L., and S. G. Neal. 1984. Trends in city conditions during the 1970’s: A survey of
demographic and socioeconomic changes. Publius 14 (2): 7-19.
Burchell, R. W., L. David, G. Sternlieb, J. W. Hughs, and S. C. Casey. 1981. Measuring urban dis-
tress: A summary of the major urban hardship indices and resource allocation systems. In
Cities under stress, edited by R. Burchell and D. Listokin, 159-229. Piscataway, NJ: Center
for Urban Policy Research.
Clark, T. N., and L. C. Ferguson. 1983. City money: Political processes, fiscal strain and
retrenchment. New York: Columbia Univ. Press.
Congressional Budget Office. 1978. City need and the responsiveness of federal grants pro-
grams. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
Cyert, R. M., and J. G. March.1963. A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice Hall.
Gold, S. 1986. State government fund balances, financial assets and measures of budget surplus:
federal-state-local fiscal relations. In Technical papers, Vol. 2, 593-662. Washington, DC:
National Council of State Legislators.
Groves, S. M., and M. G. Valente. 1994. Evaluating financial condition: A handbook for local
government. Washington, DC: International City County Managers Association.
Groves, S. M., M. G. Valente, and M. Shulman. 1981. Financial indicators for government. Pub-
lic Budgeting and Finance 1 (2): 42-60.
Holcombe, R. G., and R. A. Sobel. 1997. Growth and variability in state tax revenue: An anatomy
of state fiscal crises. Westport, CT: Greenwood.
Honadle, B. W., and M. Lloyd-Jones. 1998. Analyzing rural local governments’ financial condi-
tion: An exploratory application of three tools. Public Budgeting & Finance 18 (2): 69-86.
Howell, J. M., and C. F. Stamm. 1979. Urban fiscal stress: A comparative analysis of 66 U.S. cit-
ies. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Kloha, P., C. S. Weissert, and R. Kleine. Forthcoming. Developing and testing a new composite
model to predict local fiscal distress. Public Administration Review.
Ladd, H. F., and J. M. Yinger. 1989. America’s ailing cities: Fiscal health and the design of urban
policy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Univ. Press.
Levine, H. C., I. S. Rubin, and G. Wolohojian. 1981. The politics of retrenchment: How local
governments manage fiscal stress. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Levinthal, D. A.1991. Organizational adaptation and environmental selection: Interrelated pro-
cesses of change. In Organizational learning, edited by M. Cohen and L. Sproul, 195-203.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
MacManus, S. A., and W. J. Pammer Jr. 1990. Cutbacks in the country: Retrenchment in rural vil-
lages, townships, and counties. Public Administration Quarterly 14 (3): 302-23.
Mattson, G. A. 1994. Retrenchment and fiscal policy planning: The political culture of small
towns. Public Productivity and Management Review 17 (3): 265-79.
Morgan, D. R., and R. E. England. 1983. Explaining fiscal stress among large U.S. cities: Toward
an integrative model. Policy Studies Review 3 (1): 73-78.
Nathan, R., and C. Adams. 1976. Understanding central city hardship. Political Science Quar-
terly 91 (1): 47-62.
Orfield, M. 2002. American politics: The new suburban reality. Washington, DC: Brookings
Institute.
Pagano, M. A. 2002. Municipal capital spending during the “boom.” Public Budgeting &
Finance 22 (2): 1-20.
Pagano, M. A., and C. W. Hoene. 2003. Cities confront tough choices as fiscal conditions
decline: Economic recovery threatened. Research Briefs on America’s Cities 2 (May): 1-8.
Pagano, M. A., and J. M. Johnston. 2000. Life at the bottom of the fiscal food chain: Examining
city and county revenue decisions. Publius 30 (1-2): 159-70.
Poterba, J. M. 1994. State responses to fiscal crises: The effects of budgetary institutions and pol-
itics. Journal of Political Economy 102 (4): 799-821.
Rafuse, R. W. Jr, and L. R. Marks. 1991. A comparative analysis of fiscal capacity, tax effort, and
public spending among localities in the Chicago metropolitan region. Washington, DC: U.S.
Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations.
Ross, J. P., and J. Greenfield. 1980. Measuring the health of cities. In Fiscal stress and public pol-
icy, edited by C. Levine and I. Rubin, 89-110. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Ruchelman, L. I. 1996. The finance function in local governments. In Management policies in
local government finance, 4th ed., edited by J. R. Aronson and E. Schwartz, 3-34. Washing-
ton, DC: International City County Managers Association.
Rusk, D. 1995. Cities without suburbs. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press.
Sbragia, A. M. 1996. Debt wish: Entrepreneurial cities, U.S. federalism, and economic develop-
ment. Pittsburgh, PA: Univ. of Pittsburgh Press.
Scott, W. R. 1998. Organizations: Rational, natural, and open systems, 4th ed. Englewood
Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Shannon, J. P. 1987. State revenue diversification: The search for balance. In The quest for bal-
ance in state-local revenue structures, edited by F. Stocker. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Land
Institute.
Sobel, R. S., and R. G. Holcombe. 1996. The impact of state rainy day funds in easing state fiscal
crises during the 1990-91 recession. Public Budgeting and Finance 16 (3): 28-48.
Stonecash, J., and P. McAfee. 1981. Ambiguities and limits of fiscal strain indicators. Policy
Studies Journal 10 (4): 379-95.
Suyderhoud, J. P. 1994. State-local revenue diversification, balance, and fiscal performance.
Public Finance Quarterly 22 (2): 168-94.
Thompson, J. 1967. Organizations in action. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Tiebout, C. M. 1956. A pure theory of local expenditure. Journal of Political Economy 64 (5):
416-24.
Touche, Ross & Co. 1979. Urban fiscal crisis: Comparative analysis of 66 U.S. cities. New York:
Touche, Ross & Co.
U.S. Census Bureau. 1999. Family households/1, by type, age of own children, age of family
members, and age, race and Hispanic origin/2 of householder. Table F1. http://www.
census.gov/population/socdemo/hh-fam/p20-537/1999/tabF1.pdf.
U.S. Department of the Treasury, Office of State and Local Finance. 1978. Report on the fiscal
impact of the economic stimulus package on 48 large urban governments. Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.