E Advanced Competition Models
E Advanced Competition Models
E.1. OLIGOPOLISTIC
MODELS AND THEIR
EXTENSIONS
Number of firms
Concentration
Structural
dimensions
Possibility of product
differentiation
Entry barriers
Urges firms to be
Improves the allocation of Fosters innovation and
efficient resources increases the quality of
products/services
Name a possible disadvantage of competition. Respond at:
https://pollev.com/cristinaross747
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Why is competition important? (2) 7
Game theory is a tool to study oligopolies → It models strategic interactions among firms as
rational economic agents whose actions affect those of other agents
Main assumptions
1. Firms are rational economic agents and aim to maximize their profits
2. Rationality is common knowledge
3. Information is perfect
Key notions
• Dominant strategy: it makes firm A better off regardless of what other firms do
• Nash equilibrium: A’s strategy is the best reply to the strategies of the other firms and vice-
versa → Firms have no incentive to deviate from the equilibrium
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Introduction to (oligopolistic) competition: 9
Oligopoly and game theory (2)
Two Nash
Z strategy is
equilibria
dominated
by the others
3. There are no switching costs, and consumers buy from the firm charging the
lower price
5. Both firms have no capacity constraints and the same linear cost function
• → Total cost: C(q)=cq and thus MC(q)=c
Firm j: max π j ( pi , p j ) = p j D j ( pi , p j ) − cD j ( pi , p j ) = ( p j − c) D j ( pi , p j )
pj
* * π i ( pi * , p j * ) ≥ π i ( pi , p j * ) ∀ pi ≠ pi *
( pi , p j )
π
j i j
( p
*
, p
*
) ≥ π j ( pi
*
, p j ) ∀ p j ≠ p j
*
In the (Nash) equilibrium of a Bertrand duopoly, the two firms charge the same price,
which equals the marginal cost ∗ ∗
𝑝𝑝 𝑖𝑖 = 𝑝𝑝 𝑗𝑗 = 𝑐𝑐
Bertrand paradox: same results as in perfect competition with just two firms
Specifically, one can demonstrate that, for each firm, setting the price
• Lower than the marginal cost determines negative profits → This strategy is strictly
dominated by any other strategy, which brings positive profits or no profits
• Higher than the marginal cost is not an equilibrium
pi > p j > c
• Firm j gets the entire demand and earns positive profit, while firm i earns no profit
• Firm i has the incentive to decrease its price at an intermediate level between pj
and c, thus earning positive profit → This is not an equilibrium
pi = p j > c
• The two firms share the market and earn positive profits
• Each firm has the incentive to decrease its price to serve the entire demand (for
a slight price reduction, profits will be higher) → This is not an equilibrium
pi > p j = c
• Firm j gets the entire demand but earns no profit, while firm i earns no profits as it
sells nothing
• Firm j has the incentive to increase its price, while firm i has the incentive to
decrease it → This is not an equilibrium
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Bertrand model: 15
Extensions
In the Nash equilibrium of the (classical) Bertrand model, for each firm, it holds that
p=c, but this means no profit for both firms
Bertrand paradox: in a Bertrand competition, the price mechanism causes the
same result as in perfect competition
1. Capacity constraints: each firm cannot serve the entire demand by itself; it has a
maximum capacity level of k
• Key notion: residual demand (RD): if pi<pj and D(pi)>ki → qi=ki and RDj = D(pj)-ki
• The equilibrium price is such that both firms produce at their capacity level →
qi=ki, qj=kj, and p=p(ki+kj)
2. Not homogeneous goods: goods are not perfect substitutes; thus, it is not true that the
demand of firm i(j) goes to zero if pi>pj (pj>pi)
3. Diverse cost functions: for instance, because firms use different technologies
4. Repeated games: firms compete on the market repeatedly and thus realize that a price
war hurts them both by driving the profits to zero → Collusion
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Bertrand model - Extensions: 16
Not homogeneous goods
If products are not homogenous, a price reduction does not imply that the rival gets no
demand → p=c is no longer the equilibrium, and firms earn positive profits
• E.g., the same good sold in different locations (→ Hoteling model)
Example → Try to solve it on your own (Prof. Silvestri will revise the exercise)
• Two firms with not homogenous goods competing on prices face the following demand
functions, respectively 1
q1 ( p1 , p2 ) = 300 − p1 + p2
2
1
q2 ( p1 , p2 ) = 300 − p2 + p1
2
• By assuming zero cost of production for both firms, find equilibrium prices, quantities,
and profits
Each firm, given the price of the other firm, chooses the price that maximizes its profit
1
• For firm 1, this means: max 𝜋𝜋1 = 𝑝𝑝1 ∗ 𝑞𝑞1 − 0 = 𝑝𝑝1 (300 − 𝑝𝑝1 + 𝑝𝑝2 )
𝑝𝑝1 2
𝜕𝜕𝜋𝜋1 1
• First-order condition implies: = 300 − 2𝑝𝑝1 + 𝑝𝑝2 = 0.
𝜕𝜕𝑝𝑝1 2
𝜕𝜕𝜋𝜋2 1
Given the symmetry of the problem, for firm 2 it is: = 300 − 2𝑝𝑝2 + 𝑝𝑝1 = 0
𝜕𝜕𝑝𝑝2 2
The optimal prices by solving the system with the two first-order conditions: 𝑝𝑝1∗ = 𝑝𝑝2∗ = 200.
Thus, the two firms produce 𝑞𝑞1∗ = 𝑞𝑞2∗ = 200 and gain profits 𝜋𝜋1∗ = 𝜋𝜋2∗ = 40,000
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Bertrand model - Extensions: 17
Diverse cost functions (1)
If firms have diverse cost functions, they produce the same good at
different costs
Let us assume that both firms have linear cost functions, with c1 < c2
• Firm 1 has a cost advantage
• The lowest price that firm 2 can set is c2
The optimal price for firm 1 depends on its monopoly price and on c2.
If
• 𝑝𝑝1𝑀𝑀 < 𝑐𝑐2 → 𝑝𝑝1∗ = 𝑝𝑝1𝑀𝑀 firm 1 can set its monopoly price as firm 2
cannot capture the entire demand by setting a price lower than 𝑝𝑝1𝑀𝑀
• 𝑝𝑝1𝑀𝑀 > 𝑐𝑐2 → 𝑝𝑝1∗ = 𝑐𝑐2 − 𝜀𝜀 firm 1 cannot set its monopoly price as firm 2
can capture the entire demand by setting a price lower than 𝑝𝑝1𝑀𝑀
• Firm 1 sets a price just a little lower than c2, the lowest price that
firm 2 can set
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Bertrand model - Extensions: 18
Diverse cost functions (2)
Example → Try to solve it on your own (Prof. Silvestri will revise the exercise)
Two firms compete on prices and face this demand function: q(p)=6,000–60p
• What is the equilibrium when c1=10 and c2=12?
• How does the equilibrium change if c2=60?
• Firm 1 has a cost advantage over firm 2, as c1<c2
• Let us compute the monopoly price for firm 1, pM. It results from MR = MC1
• The inverse demand curve is p=(6,000 - q)/60=100-1/60*q
• MR=100-1/30*q. Hence, 100-1/30*q = 10 → qM = 2,700 and pM= 55
As the monopoly price is pM=55
• When c2=12, in equilibrium, firm 1 cannot set the monopoly price and it sets p1=c2-
ε=12–ε
Considering p1 ≈ 12, firm 1 produces q1 = 5,280 and gets a profit of π1=10,560
Firm 2 sets p2=c2=12, does not produce (no demand), and gets zero profits
• When c2=60, in equilibrium, firm 1 can sets the monopoly price p1=pM=55
Considering the demand function, firm 1 produces q1=2,700 and gets a profit of
π1=121,500
Firm 2 sets the price p2=c2=60, does not produce (no demand), and gets zero
profits
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
19
3. There are no switching costs, and consumers buy from the firm charging the lower price
4. Quantity is the strategic variable that firms set independently and simultaneously
• This is a mild form of competition as changes in quantities
• (Indirectly) cause changes in prices
• Are time-consuming (e.g., setting up new production plants)
• When deciding its quantity, each firm has not yet observed the other firm’s quantity →
No information advantage
5. Price results from total quantity offered on the market Y = y1 + y2. Specifically,
considering a linear demand function: p(Y) = 1-Y (with a=b=1)
6. Both firms have the same linear cost function and no capacity constraints
• Marginal cost is constant: MC(yi)=c (c<1)
The Nash equilibrium is at the intersection of the two best reply functions
• Equilibrium quantities 1− c
y1* = y2* =
3
1 + 2c
• Equilibrium price p* =
3 π =π
* *
=
(1 − c)
2
1 2
• Both firms earn positive profits 9
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Basic Cournot model: 22
Graphical representation
1 − y2 − c 1 − y1 − c
y1 = y2 =
2 2
1−𝑐𝑐
If 𝑦𝑦𝟏𝟏 = 𝟎𝟎 →𝑦𝑦𝟐𝟐 =
2
1−𝑐𝑐
If 𝑦𝑦𝟐𝟐 = 𝟎𝟎 →𝑦𝑦𝟏𝟏 =
2
• The firm with the lower cost produces more and earns higher profits
∂π 2 ( y1 , y2 ) 1 − 𝑦𝑦1 − 𝑐𝑐
= 1 − 2 y2 − y1 − c = 0 𝑦𝑦∗2 =
2
∂y2
• We insert the follower’s best reply in the leader’s profit function and compute the
optimal quantity y1*
1 1− c 1 1− c
2 2
π 1* = π 2* =
• Profits 2 2 4 2
In equilibrium, the leader produces more and earns higher profits than the
follower
• First-mover advantage
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
27
Concentration deals with the number and size (i.e., the dimensional distribution)
of firms in an industry
The firm’s size is computed based on the number of employees, output volumes,
revenues, added value…
Market share (sij) of firm i in industry j, in which N firms operate, is the ratio of
the output of firm i in industry j (qij) over the total output of j (Qj , sum of
outputs of all firms in industry j)
𝐐𝐐𝐣𝐣 = � 𝐪𝐪𝐤𝐤𝐤𝐤
𝐤𝐤=𝟏𝟏
0,5
N Firms
Concentration indexes synthesize all the information contained in the
concentration vector
• They allow comparing concentration
𝑁𝑁 across periods and industries
• General formula 𝐼𝐼 = � ℎ𝑖𝑖 (𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑖 )𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑖
𝑖𝑖=1
• A concentration index is the weighted sum of market shares
• Depending on the weights, hi(si), we define diverse concentration indexes
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
32
The sum of the market shares of the first k firms in the industry
• Firms are ordered in decreasing order according to their market shares
• Weight of the first k firms → hi(si) = 1 k
• Weight of the other N-k firms → hi(si) = 0 Ck = ∑ si
i =1
• Conventionally, k = 3, 4, 8, 20
• Given k, industry A is more concentrated than industry B if Ck(A) > Ck(B)
• 0 < Ck ≤ 1, equal to 1 when the first k firms cover the whole market, equal to
0 in perfect competition
Problems
1. Which k to choose?
2. Ck provides the same results for industries with different concentration
vectors
• Industry A: IA = (0.1, 0.1, 0.1, 0.1, …), C4A=0.4
• Industry B: IB = (0.37, 0.01, 0.01, 0.01, …), C4B=0.4
• C4 disregards that, in industry B, there is a firm totaling nearly 40% of the
industry output
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
34
Herfindahl index
N
The weighted sum of the market shares of all firms in the industry HI = ∑ si
2
i =1
• The weight of each share is equal to the share itself; thus, HI is the sum of the
squared market shares of all firms in the industry
• Small firms contribute to the value of the index LESS than large firms
The weighted sum of the market shares of all firms in the industry N
1
EI = ∑ si ⋅ ln
i =1 si
• The weight of each share is equal to the (natural) logarithm of the inverse of
the market share itself
• Small firms contribute to the value of the index MORE than large firms (as
the index is based on the inverse of the market share)
E.2.3. Collusion
Collusion allows firms to limit competition, increase prices, reduce quantities, and
exert market power
• Ultimately, it reduces social welfare as firms jointly behave as a monopolist
Firm 1
Definition
• πiC current profit of firm i if it colludes and all the other firms collude
• ViC future profits of firm i if it colludes and all the other firms collude
• πiD current profit of firm i if it deviates and all the other firms collude
• δ discount factor (from 0 to 1) for future profits, which is the same for all
the firms and expresses their “degree of patience”
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Conditions for collusion: 40
Critical discount factor
Collusion arises only if each firm prefers collusion to deviation; for each firm,
it should hold (→ incentive constraint)
π iC + δVi C ≥ π iD + δVi P i = 1, , n
• Rearranging the terms of the incentive constraint, it holds that
[1] tells that collusion arises only if the discount factor is higher than the
“critical discount factor” 𝛿𝛿𝑖𝑖 , namely if firms are patient and attach importance
to future profits
Collusion is more likely if 𝛿𝛿𝑖𝑖 is low; this happens, for instance, when
• The deviation profit (πiD) is low
• The future profits in the punishment phase (ViP) are low
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Collusion with price competition: 41
Main assumptions
There are n firms
• Interacting repeatedly over an infinite time horizon
• Producing homogeneous goods
• Facing a linear demand function
• Having the same constant marginal cost, c
• Having no capacity constraints
• Having the same discount factor, δ
• Aiming to maximize their total discounted profits
The equilibrium if they compete (Bertrand game with homogeneous goods) would be
pi = pj = … = pn= c
With n firms, collusion arises if no firm has the incentive to deviate → If, for each firm, profits
of collusion are higher than profits of deviation
𝜋𝜋𝑀𝑀 𝜋𝜋𝑀𝑀 𝜋𝜋𝑀𝑀
+ 𝛿𝛿 + 𝛿𝛿 2 +. . . ≥ 𝜋𝜋 𝑀𝑀 𝑝𝑝𝑀𝑀 − 𝜀𝜀 = 𝜋𝜋 𝑀𝑀 𝑝𝑝𝑀𝑀 = 𝝅𝝅𝑴𝑴
𝑛𝑛 𝑛𝑛 𝑛𝑛
• This is equivalent to
1 πM 1
≥ 1− δ ⇔ δ ≥ 1−
1
=δ*
≥πM
1− δ n n n
Collusion is sustainable if the discount factor is higher than the critical discount factor δ*
• If δ* is high, even patient firms (i.e., δ high) choose not to collude
• δ* threshold increases with the number of firms → Collusion is less sustainable in
competitive/poorly concentrated industry
• In the duopoly case (n = 2), the threshold is ½ (if δ ≥ ½ collusion arises, if δ < ½, it does
not)
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Factors enabling collusion: 43
A taxonomy
Identifying factors enabling collusion to support anti-trust authorities in deciding
whether and how to intervene
Name a factor making collusion more likely (one short sentence). Respond at:
https://pollev.com/cristinaross747
B. Information availability
B1. Transparency
B2. Information sharing
C. Contract clauses
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Factors enabling collusion: 44
Structural elements (1)
A.1. Number of firms, concentration, symmetry: collusion is more likely
• The fewer firms in the industry
• The higher the concentration
• The higher the symmetry, which means there is a limited power imbalance
C. Contractual clauses
• Some clauses in (long-term) contracts may favor collusion as they disclose relevant
price information
• The “meeting competition”: if the customer receives a better offer from another firm,
the focal firm commits to match the price → This discloses information about the price
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
47
Firms enter (and exit) industries, and this affects the competition
(Potential) entrants: firms intending to enter an industry to commercialize goods that are
substitutes for those commercialized by firms already in the industry (→ Incumbents)
• De novo entrants → Newly created firms (→ startups), which suffer from liability of
newness and smallness but benefit from flexibility
• De alio entrants → Incumbents entering the industry through diversification
De alio entrants are usually more dangerous for incumbents than de novo ones,
as they have more resources to compete
New firms enter an industry as profits, which incumbents earn, attract them. In general
• In deciding if to enter the industry, entrants compare expected profits and entry
costs
• Following entries, the industry supply increases and, thus, the price decreases
• The entry process ends when p=MC → No firm makes a profit
When institutional and structural entry barriers are low, incumbents may engage in
actions to deter entry → Strategic entry barriers
ACe
t = 0: the incumbent chooses the monopoly t = 1: the (potential) entrant evaluates its
residual demand and costs and decides to
quantity and price, which maximize its profits,
enter the industry
given the demand curve As the average cost is lower than the price,
its post-entry profit is positive
The incumbent should deter entry by choosing a different combination of quantity and price
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Limit pricing: 56
Not blockaded entry (2)
Q: Which is the maximum price – limit price - which m can set, by choosing a
limit quantity, to deter entry?
A: Limit price (pL) and limit quantity (qL) are such that they make e indifferent
between entering and not entering the industry
• qL, pL are such that the residual demand of e is tangent to its AC → In this
case, e’s post-entry profit goes to zero
• Any price higher than pL causes positive profits for e and triggers its entry
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Critics to the Bain, Modigliani, Sylos-Labini 57
Model
i threats e to charge pL by choosing qL, but if e decides to enter despite the threat,
enacting this threat might not be optimal for i
• In case of entry, the best reply may be to choose the Cournot quantity, which
maximizes i’s profit in a duopoly → The incumbent’s commitment to the limit
quantity is not credible An exemple: Kodak
vs. Polaroid
• K has 2
strategies: stay
Out or going In
• Then P has 2
strategies:
Fighting or
Accomodate
In the one shot
game, two Nash
equilibria exist
(Out, F) is eliminated
by backward
induction
Typically, firms resort to bundling to reduce costs or for marketing reasons, but
bundling also allows to deter entry
• This happens when an incumbent, operating in industries i and j, is the
market leader in industry i and faces entry threats in industry j
• Bundling good i and good j induces consumers to buy the bundle from the
incumbent rather than buying good i from the incumbent and good j from the
(potential) entrant
The incumbent can charge a lower price for the bundle
Product proliferation occurs when the incumbent enlarges the scope of its
offering to meet all customers’ preferences
• No room for profitable entry exists → A potential entrant should bear very
high costs for differentiating its goods from the incumbent’s ones
• Example: the case of ready-to-eat breakfast cereals in the US
3. Usually, predation is easier (and thus more common) in the presence of information
asymmetries and uncertainty
• The incumbent can leverage these drawbacks to convince (potential) entrants that
there is no room for gaining (high) profits
E.4. COMPETITION IN
NETWORK AND PLATFORM
INDUSTRIES
Network goods are subject to network externalities → Every user increases the value of
the good, thus causing a positive externality on the others
1. Direct network externalities: the value of the network good increases automatically as
the number of users increases
•E.g.: the email has no value per se: being the only one to have an email is useless; its
value increases with the number of email users
2. Indirect network externalities: when the number of users increases, the value of the
network good increases as the offering of complementary goods increases
•The hardware-software paradigm, e.g., the value of a game console increases with the
number of compatible games
1. The more the consoles’ users
2. The more the developers who want to produce compatible games
3. The more those who prefer to buy that console →The more the console’s users
Six guys want to buy video game consoles, and three firms (A, B, C) produce three
console models. The choices of the six guys depend on
1. The characteristics of the console (intrinsic value)
2. How many other guys own the same console (synchronization value) so they can play
with friends, exchange videogames, and so on
•During the weekend, the six guys browse the catalog, reporting consoles’
characteristics and, based on them, decide which console they prefer
•On Sunday evening, their preferences depend only on the intrinsic value of each model;
there is no synchronization value (and no network externality) as none has yet bought
the first console
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
A telling example: 69
A dog and a garbage bin (2)
Suppose that the intrinsic values, which define preferences, are in table 1
Table 1 A B C Preferred With no network
console externalities,
Alan 0.4 0.6 0.5 B firms producing
Bud 0.6 0.5 0.4 A videogame
consoles share
Charlie 0.5 0.4 0.6 C
the market
David 0.4 0.6 0.5 B
Eliah 0.6 0.5 0.4 A
Frank 0.2 0.3 0.4 C
•On Monday at 6 a.m., Charlie’s dog was starving and turned the garbage bin
upside down
•Charlie wakes up suddenly, while the other guys are still sleeping, and thinks,
“Since I am awake, I will go early to the videogame shop and buy my console”
•At 8 a.m., he goes to the shop and buys console C, according to his
preferences
•As Charlie makes his choice, network externalities emerge, and the
preferences of other guys, whom the shop assistant informs, change
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
A telling example: 70
A dog and a garbage bin (3)
After Charlie’s choice, other guys’ preferences change as the value of console C for
them is now Uc=Xc+ 0.2 (w*1). The preferences are those in table 2
Table 2 A B C Preferred consoles Alan, David, and Frank
after Charlie’s choice
now prefer C and will buy
Alan 0.4 0.6 0.5+0.2*1=0.7 C it
Bud 0.6 0.5 0.4+02*1=0.6 A/C
Charlie C
David 0.4 0.6 0.5+0.2*1=0.7 C
Eliah 0.6 0.5 0.4+0.2*1=0.6 A/C
Table 3 reports the
Frank 0.5 0.4 0.4+0.2*1=0.6 C preferences of the other
Table 3 A B C Preferred consoles guys after the choices by
after choice by Alan, David, Alan, David, and Frank
and Frank Console C has won the
Alan C market
Bud 0.6 0.5 0.4+0.2*4=1.2 C
Charlie C
David C
Eliah 0.6 0.5 0.4+0.2*4=1.2 C
Franl C
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Competition in network industries: 71
What the story of the dog and a garbage bin tells us
This short story tells us that in the case of network industries
1. Small initial events, which happen by chance, can determine the fate of the
competition
2. The first who benefits from network externalities can win the market
3. Competition can assume the form of “the-winner-takes-it-all”
• Once the number of users of a network good has reached the critical
mass, any new user wants to buy that good
• The good conquers the market
Critical mass
• In nuclear engineering: the minimum amount of uranium needed to cause
a self-sustaining nuclear reaction
• In the case of network goods, for any price, the number of users (N) such
that
• Number of users > N: the network succeeds as each user attracts
further users
• Number of users < N: the network fails as users progressively leave
the network
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Competition in network industries: 72
How critical mass works
Suppose that a potential user U is willing to pay 1€ for a network good only if
there are other 100 users in the network
•If, when the price is 1€, there are other 100 users, U buys the network good: the
network now consists of 101 users
•A potential user willing to pay 1€ only if there are other 101 users will join the
network, followed by a user willing to pay 1€ only if there are other 102 users,
followed by a user willing to pay 1€ only if there are other 103 users, and so on
The network grows larger and larger, and the good wins the market
•If,
when the price is 1€, there are 99 users, U does not buy the network good, and
the network still consists of 99 users
•If (for whatever reason) a user leaves the network, users become 98
•One of these users may be willing to pay 1€ only if there are other 99 users, this
user leaves the network, users will be 97, and so on
The network becomes smaller and smaller, and the good fails
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Competition in network industries: 73
Growth of the number of users
U = number of users
Maximum number of users
UN
Uh
Critical mass
Ul
Time
tl th tN
•Phase 1: start-up phase, before the critical mass is reached (0 → Ul)
•Phase 2: rapid growth after the critical mass is reached (Ul → Uh)
•Phase 3: maturity, growth slows down (Uh → UN)
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
Competition in network industries: 74
The critical mass and the start-up problem
When Facebook and Twitter, which are network goods, reached the critical mass
2. Charging meager prices to attract users from the very start; a firm can even set the
price to zero
•E.g., free access to social networks (e.g., Facebook)
•Why do software firms (e.g., Microsoft) sometimes tolerate piracy (one short sentence)?
Respond at: https://pollev.com/cristinaross747
Once a network good A has reached the critical mass, the costs of choosing
another network good B and joining its network (i.e., switching costs)
become very high
• The market is locked in A irrespectively of its intrinsic value
OSS advocates
claim that Linux
has better
performances
Platforms shift value creation from the transformation of inputs into outputs to the
coordination of participants from diverse groups
1. Platforms’ value for (prospective) users depends on the size of these groups
• Cross-side network externalities: the value of a platform for a participant of one group
increases as participants of the other group increase
• E.g., Airbnb’s value for renters rises as tenants increase
• Same-side network externalities: the value of the platform for a participant of one
group increases as participants of the same group increase
• E.g., Airbnb’s value for renters increases as renters increase due to an increase in
feedback
• They may also be harmful, e.g., competition between buyers and sellers on eBay
Provide an example of negative same-side network externalities (one short sentence).
Respond at: https://pollev.com/cristinaross747
Cristina Rossi Lamastra
The challenges of platform businesses: 80
Balanced growth and the chicken-egg problem
2. Platforms are “asset-light”: they need few assets to create value → They
benefit from economies of scale
• What is crucial for platform businesses is the interface, which allows
connecting participants from diverse groups
• Fixed costs are mainly related to the design of the interface
• Marginal costs per transaction are (very) low
PRICING STRATEGIES
Platform businesses usually charge a price menu, which consists of
1. Access (or subscription or entry) fees: the price paid for accessing the
platform
• Usually, EU crowdfunding platforms (CFPs) charge a subscription fee to
entrepreneurs who want to post their entrepreneurial projects on the platform
• Access fees for project funders are 0 in the large majority of the cases
2. Transaction (or usage) fees: the price paid for each transaction on the
platform
• Usually, CFPs retain a % of the capital raised by project proponents
• In the case of CFPs, usage fees for project proponents are positive, while
usage fees for project funders are zero in the large majority of the cases
• In the case of CFPs adopting the all-or-nothing approach, transaction fees
assume the form of success fees
2. Specialization. It deals with the span of the offering of the platform, e.g.,
• Hosting just music projects or any project in case of CFPs
• Focusing just on wealthy people or any people in the case of dating platform