Topic 2
Topic 2
Intermediate Microeconomics
Nguyen Thi Hao
[email protected]
0949230527
Textbook,
chapter 5, 6, 10
Topic 2: Optimal choice
2.1. Choice
- Optimal choice (5.1)
- Consumer demand (5.2, 5.3)
- Implication of MRS condition (5.5)
2.2. Demand
- Income offer curve and Engel curve (6.2, 6.3, 6.4)
- Price offer curve and demand curve (6.5, 6.6)
2.3. Intertemporal choice
- Budget constraint (10.1)
- Preferences for consumption (10.2, 10.3)
- Present value (10.6, 10.7)
*) Discussion
1
21/02/2024
2
21/02/2024
what would happen if the MRS were different from the price ratio?
(economic meaning of the condition MRS = slop of budget line at an
interior optimum)
• Suppose, for example, that the MRS is Δx2/Δx1 = −1/2 and the price ratio is 1/1.
• Then this means the consumer is just willing to give up 2 units of good 1 in order to
get 1 unit of good 2—but the market is willing to exchange them on a one-to-one
basis.
• Thus the consumer would certainly be willing to give up some of good 1 in order to
purchase a little more of good 2.
• Whenever the MRS is different from the price ratio, the consumer cannot be at his or
her optimal choice.
3
21/02/2024
4
21/02/2024
• The demand function is the function that relates the optimal choice—the
quantities demanded—to the different values of prices and incomes.
10
5
21/02/2024
11
Perfect substitutes
m/p1 when p1<p2
x1 = any number between 0 and m/p1 when p1=p2
0 when p1>p2
12
6
21/02/2024
13
Perfect complement
• the optimal choice must always lie on the
diagonal, where the consumer is
purchasing equal amounts of both goods,
no matter what the prices are
• p1, p2 price of x1, x2
• x – amount of good 1, good 2
• Budget constraint: p1x + p2x = m
x1=x2=x=
( )
two goods are always consumed together,
it is just as if the consumer were spending
all money on a single good that had a price
of p1 +p2
14
7
21/02/2024
15
16
8
21/02/2024
17
Discrete goods
• Good 1: Discrete goods (integer unit),
• Good 2: money to be spent on everything else
• If consumer chooses 1,2,3 … unit of good 1
• Consumption bundle: (1, m - p1), (2, m - 2p1), (3, m - 3p1), ...
• Compare the utility of each of these bundles to see which has the highest utility.
9
21/02/2024
Concave
convex preference Concave preference
Combination Specialization
Lobster Cheese
(0,2)
(0,10)
(5,5) (1,1)
Concave
10
21/02/2024
Cobb-Douglas preferences
• Cobb-Douglas Utility function: u(x1, x2) =𝑥 𝑥 .
• Appendix (page 93-94), proved to derive the optimal
𝒄 𝒎
𝒙𝟏 =
𝒄 + 𝒅 𝒑𝟏
𝒅 𝒎
𝒙𝟐 =
𝒄 + 𝒅 𝒑𝟐
21
Cobb-Douglas preferences
Fraction spent on x1 x2
11
21/02/2024
• Ex1: Suppose that you have highly nonconvex preferences for ice cream
and olives, like those given in the text, and that you face prices p1, p2
and have m dollars to spend. List the choices for the optimal
consumption bundles.
23
Summary
1. The optimal choice of the consumer is that bundle in the consumer’s budget
set that lies on the highest indifference curve.
2. Typically the optimal bundle will be characterized by the condition that the
slope of the indifference curve (the MRS) will equal the slope of the budget
line.
3. If we observe several consumption choices it may be possible to estimate a
utility function that would generate that sort of choice behavior. Such a utility
function can be used to predict future choices and to estimate the utility to
consumers of new economic policies.
4. If everyone faces the same prices for the two goods, then everyone will have
the same marginal rate of substitution, and will thus be willing to trade off the
two goods in the same way.
24
12
21/02/2024
Review questions
1. If two goods are perfect substitutes, what is the demand function for good 2?
2. Suppose that indifference curves are described by straight lines with a slope of
-b. Given arbitrary prices and money income p1, p2, and m, what will the
consumer’s optimal choices look like?
3. Suppose that a consumer always consumes 2 spoons of sugar with each cup of
coffee. If the price of sugar is p1 per spoonful and the price of coffee is p2 per
cup and the consumer has m dollars to spend on coffee and sugar, how much
will he or she want to purchase?
4. Suppose that you have highly nonconvex preferences for ice cream and olives,
like those given in the text, and that you face prices p1, p2 and have m dollars
to spend. List the choices for the optimal consumption bundles.
5. If a consumer has a utility function u(x1, x2) = x1x4 2, what fraction of her
income will she spend on good 2?
25
26
13
21/02/2024
2.2. Demand
Remind last lectures
- Optimal choice: We present the basic model of consumer choice: How maximizing
utility subject to a budget constraint to get optimal choice
- Demand function: give optimal amount of each good as the function of price, income
x1=x1(p1,p2,m), x2 = x2(p1,p2,m)
27
2.2. Demand
- Income offer curve and Engel curve (6.2, 6.3, 6.4)
- Price offer curve and demand curve (6.5, 6.6)
28
14
21/02/2024
29
15
21/02/2024
prices fixed
31
32
16
21/02/2024
33
Cobb Douglas: 𝑢 𝑥 , 𝑥 =𝑥 𝑥
• Demand x1 =
If p1: fixed a linear function of m
Eg: Double m demand double
( )
• Demand x2 = linear
( )
The income offer curve is a straight line: x2= 𝑥
Engel curve is a straight line: m = ; slop =
34
17
21/02/2024
• Income rises, the impact on demand can be less or more rapid than income increases.
• Luxury Good: Increase in demand by greater proportion than income rise
• Necessary good: increase demand by lesser proportion than income
• Suppose that the consumer’s preferences only depend on the ratio of good 1 to good 2
• If the consumer prefers (x1, x2) to (y1, y2), automatically prefers (2x1, 2x2) to (2y1, 2y2), (3x1, 3x2)
to (3y1, 3y2),…, since the ratio of good 1 to good 2 is the same for all of these bundles.
• the consumer prefers (tx1, tx2) to (ty1, ty2) for any positive value of t. Preferences that have this
property are known as homothetic preferences.
• If the consumer has homothetic preferences, the income offer curves and Engel curves are straight
lines. Thus perfect substitutes, perfect complements and Cobb-Douglas are homothetic preferences.
35
Engel curves are straight lines if the consumer’s preferences are homothetic.
36
18
21/02/2024
37
2.2.2. The price offer curve and Demand curve: price changes
Ordinary goods and Giffen goods
• Changes in price lead to a tilts or pivots of the budget line.
• Ordinary good: decrease in price increases demand: <0
• Giffen good: decrease in price decreases demand: >0
38
19
21/02/2024
39
2.2.2. The price offer curve and Demand curve: price changes
• As price changes the optimal choice moves along the price offer curve.
• The relationship between the optimal choice and a price, with income and the other
price fixed, is called the demand curve
𝒑𝟏 - change; m, 𝒑𝟐 fixed
20
21/02/2024
p1=p2
x1=
p2>p1
41
42
21
21/02/2024
43
44
22
21/02/2024
Review question
1. If the consumer is consuming exactly two goods, and she is always spending
all of her money, can both of them be inferior goods?
2. Show that perfect substitutes are an example of homothetic preferences.
3. Show that Cobb-Douglas preferences are homothetic preferences.
4. The income offer curve is to the Engel curve as the price offer curve is to . . .?
5. If the preferences are concave will the consumer ever consume both of the
goods together?
6. Are hamburgers and buns complements or substitutes?
7. What is the form of the inverse demand function for good 1 in the case of
perfect complements?
8. True or false? If the demand func on is x1 = −p1, then the inverse demand
func on is x = −1/p1. 45
46
23
21/02/2024
47
24
21/02/2024
(1) = (2) Both constraints are same for saving and borrowing
• If m1 − c1 is posi ve, then the consumer earns interest on this savings = r(m - c )
• if m1 − c1 is nega ve, then the consumer pays interest on his borrowings. = r(c - m )
• If c1 = m1, then necessarily c2 = m2, and the consumer is neither a borrower nor a
lender. We might say that this consumption position is the “Polonius point.”
49
We say: equation (3) expresses the budget constraint in terms of future value,
equation (4) expresses the budget constraint in terms of present value.
50
25
21/02/2024
C1
C1
Budget constraint when the rate of interest is zero Present and future values: The vertical intercept
and no borrowing is allowed. The less the of the budget line measures future value. The
individual consumes in period 1, the more he can horizontal intercept measures the present value
51
consume in period 2.
• Slope = -(1+r)
Every dollar saved in period 1 increase the amount of composite good that can be purchased in
period 2 by (1+r) 52
26
21/02/2024
54
27
21/02/2024
C1 C1
55
56
28
21/02/2024
57
𝑐 + + =𝑚 + +
( ) ( )
58
29
21/02/2024
Example
• The present value of $1 t years in the future at different interest rates.
• The notable fact about this table is how quickly the present value goes
down for “reasonable” interest rates.
• For example, at an interest rate of 10 percent, the value of $1 20 years
from now is only 15 cents
59
Review questions
1. How much is $1 million to be delivered 20 years in the future worth today
if the interest rate is 20 percent?
2. As the interest rate rises, does the intertemporal budget constraint become
steeper or flatter?
3. Would the assumption that goods are perfect substitutes be valid in a study
of intertemporal food purchases?
4. A consumer, who is initially a lender, remains a lender even after a decline
in interest rates. Is this consumer better off or worse off after the change in
interest rates? If the consumer becomes a borrower after the change is he
better off or worse off?
5. What is the present value of $100 one year from now if the interest rate is
10%? What is the present value if the interest rate is 5%?
60
30